Fundamentals of Banking Crises Causes of Banking Crises • Banking crises can be caused by inadequate governmental oversight, bank runs, positive feedback loops in the market and contagion Key Points • • • • • • • • A bank occurs when many people try to withdraw their deposits at the same time. As much of the capital in a bank is tied up in investments, the bank’s liquidity will sometimes fail to meet the consumer demand. Due to the mass interdependence of economies across the globe, a banking crisis in one nation is likely to dramatically affect other international economies. The Great Depression in 1929 resulted from a variety of complex inputs, but the turning point came in the form of a mass stock market crash (Black Tuesday) and subsequent bank runs. Irresponsible and unethical leveraging in these assets by the banks, and mass governmental failure to listen to economists predicting this over the past decade, caused the 2008 stock market crash and subsequent depression. Irresponsible and unethical leveraging in these assets by the banks, and mass governmental failure to listen to economists predicting this over the past decade, caused the 2008 stock market crash and subsequent depression. Key Terms Bank Run: A large number of customers withdraw their deposits from a financial institution at the same time due to a loss of confidence in the banks. leverage: The use of borrowed funds with a contractually determined return to increase the ability of a business to invest and earn an expected higher return, but usually at high risk. • In light of recent market and banking failures, the economic analysis of banking crises both historically and presently is a constant source of interest and speculation. Banking crises are when there are widespread bank runs: an abnormal number depositors try to withdraw their deposits because they don’t trust that the bank will have the deposits for withdrawal in the future. • Banking crises are not a new economic phenomenon, and similarly are not the only source of financial crises. Over the course of the past two centuries there have been a surprisingly large number of financial crises, as demonstrated in the attached figure. In understanding banking crises over time, it is useful to identify the causes in context with historic examples of banking collapses. Causes of Banking Crises • • • • • Banks can fail for several different reasons: Bank Run: A bank occurs when many people try to withdraw their deposits at the same time. As much of the capital in a bank is tied up in investments, the bank’s liquidity will sometimes fail to meet the consumer demand. This can quickly induce panic in the public, driving up withdrawals as everyone tries to get their money back from a system that they are increasingly skeptical of. This leads to a bank panic which can result in a systemic banking crisis, which simply means that all of the free capital in the banking system is withdrawn. Stock Market Positive Feedback Loops: One particularly interesting cause of banking disasters is a similar positive feedback loop effect in the stock markets, which was a much more dynamic factor in more recent banking crises (i.e. 2007-2009 sub-prime mortgage disaster). John Maynard Keynes once compared financial markets to a beauty contest, where investors are merely trying to pick what is attractive to other investors. There is a profound truth to this, creating an interdependent and potentially self-fulfilling investment thought process. This can create dramatic rises and falls (bubbles and crashes), which in turn can throw banks with poorly designed leverage into huge losses. Regulatory Failure: One of the simplest ways in which bank crises can occur is a lack of governmental oversight. As noted above, banks often leverage themselves to capture gains despite extremely high risks (such as over-dependence on derivatives). Contagion: Due to globalization and international interdependence, the failure of one economy can create something of a domino effect. In 2008, when the U.S. economy collapses, the reduced buying power and economic output from that economy dramatically damaged all economies dependent upon it (which includes most of the world). This is called contagion. The Great Depression • The Great Depression highlights how bank runs caused a banking crisis, which ultimately became a global economic crisis. The Great Depression in 1929 resulted from a variety of complex inputs, but the turning point came in the form of a mass stock market crash (Black Tuesday) and subsequent bank runs. As fear began to grip consumers across the United States, people became protective of their assets (including their cash). This caused a large number of people to the banks to withdraw, which in turn motivated others to go to the banks and get their capital out also. Since banks lend out some of their deposits, they did not have enough cash on hand to meet the immediate withdrawal requests (they became illiquid) and therefore went bankrupt. Within a few weeks this resulted in a systemic banking crisis Consequences of Banking Crises • Banking crises have a range of short-term and long-term repercussions, domestically and globally, that reduce economic output and growth • • • • • • • • Key Points Banks play a critical role in economic growth, primarily through investment and lending. After a banking crisis, investment suffers. When banks lack liquidity to invest, growing business depending upon loans struggle to raise the capital required to execute upon their operations. The fall in liquidity and investment, in turn, drives up unemployment, drives down governmental tax revenues and reduces investor and consumer confidence. Imports and exports play an increasingly large role in the health of most developed economies, and as a result, the relative well-being of trade partners plays an increasingly critical role in the success of domestic economies. Key Terms Economic crisis: A period of economic slowdown characterised by declining productivity and devaluing of financial institutions often due to reckless and unsustainable money lending. liquidity: The degree to which an asset can be easily converted into cash • Banking crises have a dramatic negative effect on the overall economy, often resulting in an eventual financial and economic crisis in a given economic system. Banking crises have a range of short-term and long-term repercussions, domestically and globally, that underline the severe repercussions of irresponsible banking practices, poor governmental regulation, and bank runs. The most useful way to frame the consequences of bank crises is by observing the critical role banks play in economic growth, primarily through investment and lending Domestic Consequences • • • Within a given system, banking failures create a range of negative repercussions from an economic perspective. Banks coordinate and economy’s savings and investment: the act of pooling money to capture higher returns for everyone while simultaneously funding business dependent upon leveraging debt and equity. With this in mind, a banking crises can have a variety of averse individual and economic consequences within the system. First and foremost, investment suffers. When banks lack liquidity to invest, businesses that depend upon loans struggle to raise the capital required to execute upon their operations. When these businesses cannot produce the capital required to operate optimally, sales decline and prices rise. The overall economic performance of any debt-dependent industries becomes less dependable, driving down consumer and investor confidence while reduce overall economic output. Banks also perform more poorly, due to the fact that they have less capital to invest and returns to acquire. This drives down the overall economic system, both in the short term and the long term, as companies struggle to succeed. The fall in liquidity and investment drives up unemployment, drives down governmental tax revenues and reduces investor and consumer confidence (damaging equity markets, which in turn limits businesses access to capital). There is a distinctive cyclical nature to these adverse effects, as each are interconnected in a way that creates a domino effect across the domestic economic system Global Consequences • • While these domestic consequences are expected and, in many ways, intuitive, the global dependency upon foreign trade in modern markets has exacerbated these effects. Imports and exports play an increasingly large role in the health of most developed economies, and as a result the relative well-being of trade partners plays an increasingly critical role in the success of domestic economies. A good example of this is to look at the way in which the U.S. (and to some extent, European) banking disasters in 2008 and 2009 led to a complete global financial meltdown, destroying economies not involved in the irresponsible investing practices executed by banks in these specific regions. identifies the critical importance of economic well-being in trading partners, as the U.S. banking and financial crises spread rapidly (within the course of just one year) across a substantial portion of the globe (though there are certainly other factors that contributed to the financial crisis and its consequences). The domestic reduction of capital for businesses, income for consumers and tax revenue for governments ultimately results in a reduction of trade and economic activity for other economies International Banking Operations Banking Crisis from an International Perspective I. The Causes of Banking Crises -Each banking crisis has its own dynamics, most of the main ingredients are always present. -Based on their most common causes, Banking crises can be classified into one of two categories: 1-Microeconomic (or bad banking), 2- Macroeconomic (or bad operating environment). 1-Bad banking • Banking crises often have their roots in poor bank operations: poor lending practices, excessive risk taking, poor governance, lack of internal controls, focus on market share rather than profitability, and currency and maturity mismatches in the banks themselves or among their borrowers. These conditions are aggravated if bank owners have little at stake in the banks—that is, do not have enough capital invested in the banks—and if bank managers carry little personal responsibility for the risks they take. • In some emerging countries these conditions may be worsened when bank ownership is very narrow and when banks are run as personal "piggy banks" or pyramid schemes of industrial groups or families. • In these conditions, connected lending, insider operations, and outright fraud may go on with impunity. • Similarly, state banks may be run as quasi-fiscal agencies based on political criteria with disregard for commercial principles, which undermines their solvency and the soundness of other better-run banks. • • Bad banking can only persist in the absence of proper regulation and supervision, and of adequate market discipline. Weak supervisory frameworks may include allowing for concentrated lending, portfolio mismatches, inadequate loan valuation that overstate bank profits and capital, incompetent management, etc. Supervision may also lack authority, and have an insufficient number of skilled staff who may be poorly motivated and compensated. • Poor transparency, limited financial disclosure, and poor accounting and auditing practices mean that the market—that is, bank creditors—will not have sufficient information to exert discipline on bank owners. • Market forces are further impeded by weak frameworks for dealing with problem banks, including weak legal, judicial and institutional frameworks for dealing with failing banks and companies. Expectations of depositor and creditor bailouts may overpower any policy to the contrary. 2-Bad operating environment • Crises can arise from macroeconomic causes that are external to the banking system. • Even well-run banking systems operating in a strong legal and regulatory framework can be overwhelmed by the effects of a poor macroeconomic environment or inadequate policies. Macroeconomic difficulties may arise from lending booms, possibly stoked by excessive capital inflows or changes in tax rules; real estate and/or equity price bubbles that inflate and burst; slowdown in growth and/or exports, or the loss of export markets; growing excess capacity/falling profitability in real sector; lower overall investment; rising fiscal and/or current account deficits; weakened public debt sustainability; sharp changes in exchange rates and real interest rates; and so on. Not all these developments are under authorities' control—but governments must be ready to adapt macro policies that take the conditions of a systemically distressed banking system into account. Crisis triggers • • As long as the banks remain liquid, banking distress can persist for a prolonged period—until some trigger leads depositors and creditors to lose confidence in the banking system. These can be market, policy, or political shocks that become the "wakeup call" for dealing with problems so far ignored, causing dramatic shifts in expectations and systemic bank runs. The emergence of illiquidity in one bank can quickly spread to others through contagion, as bank or payment system weaknesses destroy credibility of all banks, and lead to creditor and depositor runs regardless of the soundness of individual banks. Contagion is in this case local, but can also be international, when it is caused by the emergence of a systemic crisis in a country related through financial and trade channels. • Premature financial liberalization, together with inadequate preparation among bankers and supervisors, has also in the past triggered banking crises. Bankers may not have the needed skills to manage and price risk, and supervisors may lack adequate resources and competencies to monitor the more complex new risks. This can easily create a situation where liberalization unleashes the effects of pure ignorance about the risks involved among relevant parties. • A loss of confidence in the government and its ability to implement its macroeconomic framework can trigger a systemic crisis. Such concerns erode confidence in the banking sector as well as, often, the currency. • In addition, if the medium-term sustainability of a country's macroeconomic policies, including its external debt, comes under question, are in doubt, private confidence in the economic outlook can erode, resulting in the emergence of banking pressures and, in unaddressed, banking distress. • But maybe the most important issue is not the specific causes of a banking crisis, but the ability of the political authorities to come together to develop a strategy and then implement it. • Political decision makers must recognize that there is a problem and make quick and resolute actions. Developing a political consensus on the path forward is a critical step. Most importantly, the process must be seen as fair and transparent. Bank owners and borrowers must be prevented from exerting inappropriate interference Framework for crisis resolution • • • By the late 1990s, the Fund had significant experience in addressing banking sector crises in a variety of economic environments. The experiences of the Nordic countries were among the first, intensive areas of involvement and, in the late 1990s, the Fund, and MAE in particular, was intensively involved in resolving the financial crises in Asia. These crises emerged in an environment quite different from the crises in Latin America today. The roots of the crises lay, in large part, with the weak financial sector and were only triggered by macroeconomic difficulties. Our response was to address those root causes, implementing important legal and regulatory reforms and strengthening bank supervision. These efforts were supported by reforms to address the deep insolvencies in the banks and institutional steps to manage the system's nonperforming assets. The results of the Nordic and Asian crises have been quite good. The countries involved have largely emerged from the crises with vibrant financial systems. However, the lessons learned so well in those countries are now being modified in light of the new challenges faced in the more recent financial crises in Latin America. II. Recent Challenges • If these issues where not sufficiently difficult and challenging, recent banking crises have dealt with a combination of high dollarization and high levels of government debt that have imposed particularly hard constraints on crisis management 1-Dollarization • Crises have emerged recently in highly dollarized economies such as Argentina and Uruguay. This aspect raises issues not previously encountered and special factors must be considered. • A high degree of dollarization particularly makes banking systems more prone to runs and makes runs more difficult to stop. Dollarized economies face liquidity constraints early in the crisis, as bank runs must be addressed using limited international reserves. Furthermore, as depositors know that the supply of dollars is limited, they may be more prone to leave the banking system. • These conditions—the constraints on liquidity support and on depositor protection—may make the use of administrative measures—such as restrictions on deposit withdrawals or securitization of bank liabilities—more likely. As we all know, both Argentina and Uruguay were forced to design administrative measures to contain a run on their banks that could not otherwise be contained 2-Sovereign debt restructuring • • • Another factor that has recently become evident is the constraints on banking crisis management when this is combined with sovereign debt restructuring. Although we have limited experience, available evidence suggests that the impact of sovereign debt restructuring on bank soundness will depend on a large number of issues, including the size of banks' exposure to the government, the currency of denomination of the debt, and the terms and modalities of the debt restructuring. Large-scale restructuring can result in immediate undercapitalization or even systemic insolvency when banks have sizeable holdings of government debt. At the same time, policymakers should be aware that the use of fiscal resources to deal with banking problems are inherently limited when the debt is already unsustainable and needs to be restructured— hence the government's role as creditor, guarantor, or owner of last resort is severely limited. For these reasons, any strategy for sovereign debt restructuring must be designed to explicitly consider the impact on the banking system. From a banking system perspective, we have come to believe that, if restructuring is necessary, and if the authorities have a choice, a preferable approach is to avoid nominal reductions (haircuts) in bank assets. Haircuts would result in reduction of bank capital and, likely, the imposition of remaining losses on depositors. Instead, the authorities should try to achieve a restructuring through reductions in interest rates or extension of deposit maturities that may not entail immediate losses III. The Case of Argentina • in 2000, the Argentine banking system was in sound financial condition following the substantial consolidation, privatization, and increased foreign entry in the second half of the 1990s. This strengthening of the system was supported by a tightening of regulation and supervision. • The build up of the crisis began in 2001 and emerged in full in 2002. • During 2002, progress in stabilizing the financial conditions was delayed by the lack of basic information on banks' financial conditions, uncertainties concerning compensation for policy-induced losses, as well as delays in issuing necessary prudential and accounting rules. Banking sector strategy • The policy agenda for 2003 is both clear and urgent. • As I mentioned above, the most important challenge now is for the Argentine authorities—both the Ministry of Economy and the Central Bank of Argentina—to agree on a coherent banking strategy and then implement that strategy as quickly as possible. Further delays will only increase the costs of restructuring and reduce the already limited options available. • Second, as we have seen in numerous other crises, the policies adapted must be transparent and uniformly implemented. Special interests will always try to gain in period of economic distress. The policy challenge is to build a broad domestic consensus for the difficult challenges ahead without giving in to limited, special interest groups. • • • Third, progress must be made in understanding the true condition of the banking system. While banks appear reasonably liquid, their solvency remains unclear. This reflects uncertainties about compensation for policy-related losses as well as concerns about the quality of banks' portfolios. These issues must be quickly addressed. Specifically: The mechanism for compensating banks for policy-related losses should be finalized; The regulatory framework should be updated; • • • • Banks must provide detailed audits, business plans, and monthly cash flow projections. Fourth, the central bank must determine the state of the banking system. Using financial statements and the business plans, viable and nonviable banks should be identified. Viability can be determined by evaluating banks' capital, the strength and commitment of shareholders to recapitalize the bank, the business plans, their client base, the quality of the loan portfolio, and future cash flow. Fifth, nonviable banks must be resolved, either through recapitalization and restructuring by shareholders, or through least cost resolution techniques including merger, sale, or liquidation. Finally, I believe that, regardless of the resolution option chosen, if feasible, additional losses to depositors should be minimized. If depositors lose confidence further, it will be difficult to prevent a resurgence of bank runs Special issues for public banks • A priority task is to accelerate the restructuring of the large public banks, which were weak even before the crisis and have accumulated a substantial debt to the central bank. Uncertainties remain about the true condition of these banks, which must be ascertained through a detailed due diligence process. After that, a difficult restructuring process must begin, leading to a reasonable financial solution to these banks' problems, and a clear definition of the future role for public banks in the Argentine system. Remaining institutional agenda • • • • I would like to highlight two more issues that should have priority in the emerging strategy for the financial sector. We have seen in all countries that progress cannot be made in the restructuring of the banking system without clear protection for supervisors. Dealing with weak or insolvent banks touches at the heart of a country's financial system. Pressures can be put on supervisors to make inappropriate decisions or not to make decisions at all. Without protection, supervisors will have little ability to withstand such pressures. Legal protection is a key element of any successful strategy. Second, the autonomy of the central bank has increasingly become an accepted international standard. In the region, as well as in Europe and Asia, more and more central banks are gaining their autonomy. This allows them to act in the best interest of the country, aiming monetary policy at controlling inflation and ensuring financial stability. I would urge the Argentine authorities to continue their movement towards the full autonomy of the central bank. These are challenging times and I wish the best for Argentina and the Argentine authorities