Optimal Dynamic Taxation 75 It is instructive to concentrate on iso-elastic utility, since then we have two regimes for the after-tax interest rate: ρ = 0 and ρ = fk. We will see later on that the dynamic behaviour of the economy does not fundamentally change for the more general case. Also, for expositional simplicity we keep τl constant in the graphs. We will see later on that when τl is changing over time (according to the optimal policy), the fundamental dynamic patterns do not change. We shall consider the following timing: at t0 Chamley’s policy is implemented, and at t1 the capitalincome tax is set to zero. We may think of three initial values of the capital stock when Chamley’s policy is implemented: lower, equal to, or greater than its steady-state value. That is, either k(t0) < k*, or k(t0) = k*, or k(t0) > k*. Assume first that the initial value of the capital stock is equal to its long-rung value. When ρ = 0 both the slope and the level of the line q̇ = 0 goes to plus infinity, (we may think of this as when the line disappears to the left), and we are left with Figure 3.6, below. We then have three possibilities for the individual’s behaviour. The individual may choose initial consumption and initial labour supply so that initial marginal utility is (I) equal to steady-state marginal utility, i.e. q(t0) = q*, (II) greater than the steady-state level, i.e. q(t0) > q*, (III) smaller than the steady-state level, i.e. q(t0) < q*, and then adjusting according to the first-order differential equation q̇ = θq. Graphically the three possibilities are depicted in Figure 3.7, below. Endogenous Taxation in a Dynamic Economy 76 Figure 3.6 Figure 3.7 It is clear that (I) cannot be optimal, when the regime switches to a zero capital income tax the economy cannot turn back to its steady state. The economy would accumulate capital forever and consumption would go to zero. On the same grounds we Optimal Dynamic Taxation 77 can rule out (II). We are left with (III) as the only possibility. In fact the initial value of q is such that the economy is guaranteed to join the unique converging trajectory X, exactly at the date of the regime switch t1. This path requires capital decumulation.24 See Figure 3.8, below. Figure 3.8 It is clear that the analysis above does not fundamentally change when there is no regime switch but a gradual adjustment of ρ towards fk.25 Still the economy would decumulate capital for a period and join the new converging trajectory associated with the continuous adjustment of ρ towards fk. 24 We could think of a fourth possibility as well: q(t0) is very low. Then the trajectory would not cross the k̇ = 0 line, but continue left upwards toward the q-axis. In this case marginal utility goes to infinity and the economy’s capital stock goes to zero. This would happen if the ρ = 0 regime lasts forever. 25 When form of the utility function is more general than the iso-elastic form. Endogenous Taxation in a Dynamic Economy 78 It is also clear that if the size of economy’s initial capital stock is different from its steady-state value, the same analysis apply. Suppose the initial capital stock is smaller than its steady state value. We have three possibilities analogously to the case when k0=k*: The individual may choose initial marginal utility (I′) on trajectory X, (II′) above trajectory X, (III′) below trajectory X. Case (I′) and (II′) may be ruled out on the same grounds as above. We are left with (III′), which at t1 joins X. See figure 3.9. Figure 3.9 Finally suppose that the economy’s capital stock is greater than its steady state value. Again we have three possibilities. The individual may choose a q on trajectory Y, and then follow the differential equation q̇ = θq. But then the economy cannot follow trajectory Y, since q grows faster when ρ = 0 than when ρ = fk. Since q grows faster, consumption will decrease faster and k will not decumulate as quickly as intended on trajectory Optimal Dynamic Taxation 79 Y. Clearly this implies that the economy will go on a trajectory above, and after some time cross the k̇ = 0 line and behave as in the case (I) above. By the same reason we may rule out any q(t0) above the trajectory and we are left with case (III′′), depicted in Figure 3.10. As above the economy will decumulate capital. Figure 3.10 The length of the confiscatory regime (t1-t0) depends on the economy’s funding requirement. If the funding requirement is large relative to the capital stock k(t0) then the co-state q(t0) would take on a lower value and join X at a later date. So, the greater the distance t1-t0 the smaller the q(t0). Smaller q(t0) is associated with faster capital decumulation. We may think of two paths not covered by the Figures 3.5-3.8. First, if the confiscatory regime is permanent, i.e. t1-t0 → ∞, then q(t0) takes on a value so small that the trajectory never crosses the k̇ = 0 line and therefore continues to infinity and the capital stock goes to zero. Second, if the funding requirement Endogenous Taxation in a Dynamic Economy 80 is small and k(t0) > k*, we have the possibility that q(t0) is large enough for the economy not to decumulate capital below k*. The two cases are depicted below in Figure 3.11, as trajectories IV and V respectively. Figure 3.11 We have drawn the graphs for a constant labour income tax τl. When τl changes over time we have to imagine the k̇ = 0 line "moving" over time (at least between t0 and t1) in Figures 3.7, 3.9-3.11. For example, when τl is increasing over time [as for the utility function in (36)] the k̇ = 0 line will move outwards as time goes on. This is so since an (uncompensated) increase in the labour income tax decreases labour supply and at least not decreases consumption, if consumption and leisure are complements. This would make k̇ < 0. To "restore" k̇ = 0 the level of k has to be higher (or alternatively the level of q has to be greater). If this is the case, trajectory III will as before be below the k̇ = 0 line, and towards t1 "chase" the line and cross it. Clearly, the fundamental pattern of trajectory III does not change, and on the same basis as before we can always rule out Optimal Dynamic Taxation 81 the trajectories I and II. From the graphical analysis we have found a common characteristic of the economy under the confiscatory regime: Remark Regardless the initial value of the capital stock when Chamley’s policy is implemented, the economy always decumulates capital in the beginning of the regime, and at least after some time (if the confiscatory regime is long enough) the pre-tax interest rate becomes greater than the rate of time preference. This characteristic will be useful to bear in mind when we in the next part will study the feedback equilibrium of an optimaltax economy. To conclude, in this section we have reviewed Chamley’s result, and at the same time derived additional results regarding the labour income. We have also studied the dynamic behaviour of the economy under Chamley’s fiscal policy. The solution was derived under the assumption that the government can (credibly) commit to all future taxes. This solution is usually labelled as second best. We have an economy in which no lump-sum instruments are available, and we want to find the optimum combination of distortionary tax instruments so as to fund an exogenously given public expenditure sequence.26 Because capital income is fixed in the short run, capital income taxation is like lump-sum taxation. However, capitalincome taxes distort the intertemporal price between commodities at different dates. So, by the choice of utility function, it is optimal in an economy without capital to tax 26 Or without loss of generality endogenous public expenditure. Endogenous Taxation in a Dynamic Economy 82 consumption at different dates at uniform rate, i.e. a zero capital income tax.27 In the long run the latter effect becomes predominant, and therefore we find the capital income tax zero in the long run.28 It is therefore clear that, if the government is allowed to reoptimise, the government would always find capital inelastic, and therefore find it optimal to tax it at the maximum rate. This is true regardless weather the optimal long-run capital income tax is zero or not.29 The time-inconsistency problem is quite severe, despite this the open-loop solution is useful as a bench mark at which we may evaluate optimal policy under different institutional settings. We shall proceed with the analysis by assuming that the government cannot commit to future taxes, and evaluate the optimal policy resulting from this institutional setting. We may suspect that if commitment is not possible, the government will find it optimal to always confiscate capital income. We will see that this intuition is true in a more formalised treatment of differential games in the next part. 27 Atkinson and Stiglitz (1972) prove that when utility is additively separable in commodities, these commodities should be taxed at a uniform rate. 28 As Lucas (1990, pp. 299-300) argues: "One principle is that factors of production in inelastic supply - factors whose income is a pure rent - should be taxed at confiscatory rates [...] A second principle in Ramsey’s analysis is that goods that appear symmetrically in consumer preferences should be taxed at the same rate [...] In my formulation there is but one tax rate applied to income from old and new capital alike, so these two principles cannot simultaneously be obeyed." 29 That is, regardless weather utility is separable in commodities at different dates. Perhaps the most important question may not be whether the optimal capital-income tax is zero or not, but how different institutional arrangements may cause a deviation from the second-best optimal policy.