Exiting Quantitative Easing: which expectations matter? Lorenzo Rigon1 September 2014 1 Il presente documento è di esclusiva pertinenza del relativo autore ed è esclusivamente riservato per l’uso espressamente consentito dall’autore medesimo, senza il cui preventivo espresso consenso scritto non può essere ulteriormente distribuito, adattato, memorizzato ovvero riprodotto, in tutto o in parte e in qualsiasi forma e tecnica. 1 Table of Contents 1. Abstract................................................................................................................................................. 3 2. Introduction .......................................................................................................................................... 4 3. Theorical Framework: A Different prospective on Expectations........................................................ 5 4. Independent Variable representing QE: Stock or Flow? Spot looking or Forward looking? ............. 8 a. Stock dimension vs Flow dimension. ............................................................................................... 9 b. OMO Expectation Revision… ........................................................................................................... 9 c. …which in practice translates into Spot looking analysis: ............................................................ 10 d. Program Expectation Revision: a Forward looking Analysis ........................................................ 11 5. Dependent Variable: Capturing the effects of QE Expectation Revision, all channels considered. 13 6. Average Maturity, Control Variables and Caveats ............................................................................ 15 a. Average Maturity ........................................................................................................................... 15 b. Business Cycle Controls .................................................................................................................. 16 c. Omission of Other UMP tools ........................................................................................................ 16 d. Major Assumptions used to project Expectations ........................................................................ 17 7. Empirical Evidence. ............................................................................................................................ 19 8. Conclusions ......................................................................................................................................... 27 9. References .......................................................................................................................................... 28 2 1. Abstract When will the US Quantitative Easing actually be over? This work intends to contribute to this question by investigating two related questions: Is QE a stock variable or a flow one? Is QE relevant in its present or future expected size? We first formulate these two questions rigorously in terms of relevant expectation revisions. The four possible answers lead us to define four forms of the independent variable representing QE. Then, thanks to a reasonable assumption on the data, we translate two of such variables into more practical and meaningful ones, and build the remaining two through a series of projections of expected path of the size of QE. Finally, including some relevant controls, we will look at which form of the independent variable provides us with the best explanation for the effects of QE on Yield Curves, and draw our conclusions. 3 2. Introduction Many of the most important central banks embarked in quantitative easing (QE) programs during the Great Recession. Now, some of those economies are moving out of recession and the central banks are pondering the exit from previous extraordinary measures. In order to understand the impact of the end of QE, it is important to firm the understanding of the impact of the QE programs, when they were firstly introduced. However, there is not a consensus on the origin of the effect of the QE on the yields curves; some (BoE) tend to emphasize more a stock effect while others (Fed) tend to put more weight on a flow effect. Moreover, it is yet not clear if the relevant measure of QE is its current size, or its expected future size. This work, starting from these two questions, tries to shed light on that debate in order to get better reading on the implications of a future exit from the QE programs. Section 3 traces a general theorical framework for Unconventional Monetary Policy according to recent Literature. This will provide us with some orientation, since our two questions arise from a change of prospective on a part of this framework. Section 4 formulates our two questions in rigorous theorical terms of expectation revisions, and from the four possible answers draws four different “measures” QE expectation revisions. Then, an assumption on the data will allow us to redefine two of these variables in terms of actual size of Fed Permanent holdings. We end up with four forms of the independent variable, each representing an interpretation of QE. Section 5 defines and justifies the choice of the dependent variable. Section 6 will integrate our analysis with a measure of actual and expected Average Maturity, and with some Control Variables that are necessary to compare QE effects in different moments of the business cycle. Then some caveats and limitations of our analysis are highlighted. In particular, assumptions used to project expectations are shown. Section 7 presents the results of the regression analysis, and considers some robustness checks. Section 8 draws the conclusions. Section 9 includes the reference that was fundamental in shaping this research and some more essential reference on the topic. 4 3. Theorical Framework: A Different prospective on Expectations Quantitative Easing (QE) is an unconventional monetary policy (UMP) tool. Unconventional Monetary Policy aims at stabilising financial markets and lowering effective interest rates charged on funding to real economy, when the short-term rates on central bank reserves have reached their effective lower bound1. Quantitative Easing serves this purpose through assets purchases that are larger in scale and include a broader range of assets than conventional purchases of treasury securities. QE is usually implemented when conventional purchases have already pushed the short-term rates on reserves at their lower floor2, set at the effective lower bound. Just a small part of the effects of QE happens when the purchases are settled. These small, intraday “Local Supply Effects” are mostly due to imperfect arbitrage and market frictions3. The bulk of the effects come instead from Expectation Revisions, happening on Announcements4. Literature5 has so far focused on disaggregating the effects of Quantitative Easing Expectation Revisions on Yield Curves into different “channels”, as the diagram below summarises. By contrast, our focus will shift the prospective on the nature of expectations that are the most relevant. This new focus is explained in the second diagram below, and will be used in the next section to formulate four different measures of QE expectation revisions. 1. From Harrison, 2012: “In principle, ELB may be higher than zero if there are transactional costs associated with holding money (see Yates, 2003). But in practice, it may be positive for a number of reasons. For example, low levels of policy rates may cause difficulties for the functioning of financial intermediaries that maintain a spread between deposit and lending rates to cover the costs of providing banking services and to make a return on capital (see Bank of England, 2009)”. 2. The lower floor in the US is currently set by the Reverse Repo facility interest rate, since not all the holders of reserves, namely the GSEs, have access to the Interest Rate on Excess Reserves. 3. On the relevance and nature of Local Supply effects, I refer to D’Amico and King, 2012, “Flow and Stock Effects of LSAP: Evidence on the importance of Local Supply”, FEDS, and to Daines, Joyce and Tong, 2012, “QE and the gilt market, a disaggregated analysis”, BoE Working Paper 466. Please notice that D’Amico and King define Stock and Flow Effects what we define respectively Expectation Revision Effects and Local Supply Effects. 4. This statement will be discussed in depth in Section 5, with regard to the observations of Foerster and Cao, 2013, “Expectations of Large Scale Asset Purchases”, Economic Review Second Quarter 2013, Kansas City FRB. 5. Reviewed Literature is fully listed in the reference appendix. For the channel analysis, I mainly refer to Krishnamurhy and Vissing-Jorgestern, “The Effects of QE on Interest Rates, Channels and Implications for Policy”, 2011 NBER; Wu, 2013, “Unconventional Monetary Policy and Long Term Interest Rates, IMF; IMF Report 2013a and the 5two papers at point 4. Literature Analysis: Focus on Channels for Expectation Revisions UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY TOOLS Tools to stabilise markets and/or lower interest rates when effective lower bound on short-term reserve rates is reached QUANTITATIVE EASING (Larger-scale asset purchases) LIQUIDITY PROVISION (Longer term, cheaper, and/or emergency lending) EXPECTATION REVISION EFFECTS (Major effects on announcements due to expectation revision) LOCAL SUPPLY EFFECTS (Minor effects on settlements due to imperfect arbitrage) FORWARD GUIDANCE (Announcements on long-term future policy rates) SIGNALING CHANNEL (Announced purchases lower expected future policy rates) PORTFOLIO BALANCE CHANNELS (Announced purchases alter expected future relative supply of assets, altering term premia) INFLATION CHANNEL (Announced purchases higher expected future inflation rate) DURATION PREMIA CHANNEL (Announced purchases of longer duration assets lower expected future relative supply of longer-duration assets, lowering the duration premia) LIQUIDITY PREMIA CHANNEL (Announced purchases of treasury securities lower expected future relative supply of liquid securities, rising the liquidity premia, lowering treasury rates and rising non-treasury rates) SAFETY PREMIA CHANNEL (Announced purchases of government securities lower expected relative future supply of “super-safe” securities, rising the safety premia, lowering government security rates, rising non–government rates) DEFAULT RISK PREMIA CHANNEL (Announced purchases of higher default risk assets lower expected future relative supply of default-risky assets, lowering the default risk premia) PREPAYMENT RISK PREMIA CHANNEL (Announced purchases of prepayable assets (in general MBS) lower expected future relative supply of prepayment-risky securities, lowering the prepayment risk premia) 6 Our Analysis: focus on nature of Expectation Revisions UNCONVENTIONAL MONETARY POLICY TOOLS Tools to stabilise markets and/or lower interest rates when effective lower bound on short-term reserve rates is reached FORWARD GUIDANCE QUANTITATIVE EASING (Announcements on long-term future policy rates) (Larger-scale asset purchases) EXPECTATION REVISIONS EFFECTS (Major effects on announcements due to expectation revision) LIQUIDITY PROVISION (Longer term, cheaper, and/or emergency lending) LOCAL SUPPLY EFFECTS (Minor effects on settlements due to imperfect arbitrage) OMO ANNOUNCEMENT EXPECTATION REVISIONS Revisions of one-day expectations due to single Open Market Operations announcements STOCK DIMENSION OF EXPECTATION REVISIONS Difference with Pre-QE Expectation FLOW DIMENSION OF EXPECTATION REVISIONS Difference with previous Expectation Revision PROGRAM ANNOUNCEMENT EXPECTATION REVISIONS Revisions of longer –term expectations due to announcements on the longerterm path of QE Program EXPECTATION REVISIONS DUE TO OMO ANNOUNCEMENTS IN THEIR STOCK DIMENSION EXPECTATION REVISIONS DUE TO PROGRAM ANNOUNCEMENTS IN THEIR STOCK DIMENSION EXPECTATION REVISIONS DUE TO OMO ANNOUNCEMENTS IN THEIR FLOW DIMENSION EXPECTATION REVISIONS DUE TO PROGRAM ANNOUNCEMENTS IN THEIR FLOW DIMENSION 7 4. Independent Variable representing QE: Stock or Flow? Spot looking or Forward looking? As represented in the diagram above, we think that there are two relevant questions to answer in order to understand the effects of QE arising from expectation revisions: 1. Whether expectation revisions are relevant in their Stock or Flow dimension 2. Whether relevant expectation revisions are the revisions of one-day expectations, arising from OMO announcements on single purchases, or the revisions of longer- term expectations, arising from Program announcements on the future path of the purchases. The possible answers questions will lead us to formulate four different theorical measures of revision of expectations on the “Level of QE”, or “QE Level”. Let us first define “FED Size” at time tο(-∞,T), in days1 , the total amounts of assets purchased by the FED in settled Permanent Open Market Operations, net of principal and coupon repayments. πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ (π‘) ≡ ππΈπ ππ΄πΏππΈ ππΉ π΄πππΈππ πΉπ ππ ππΈπππΏπΈπ· ππΈπ ππ΄ππΈππ ππππ (π‘) Now, we will define “QE Level” as the difference between the current FED Size, and the FED size just before the first QE Program Announcement. ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘) ≡ πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) Then, the four theorical measures of revision of expectations on the level of QE will be: Theorical Specifications Indipendent Variable expressing Expectation Revisions on QE Level. Expectation Revision due to Announcements on Single Purchases Expectation Revision due to Announcements on Program Path Stock Dimension of Expectation Revision How much OMO Announcement changes the previous 1-day expectation on Level of QE How much Program Announcement changes the previous longer-term expectation on Level of QE Flow Dimension Of Expectation Revision How much OMO Announcement changes the previous change of 1-day expectation on Level of QE How much Program Announcement changes the previous change of longer-term expectation on Level of QE 1. t=0 is the start of QE, and will be set at the first QE Program. The time framing actually used for our analysis of the 8 data may and shall not be daily. In fact, we will use weekly data. a. Stock dimension vs Flow dimension. Analysing the Stock Dimension of Expectation Revisions means to consider how much announcements change expected QE Level, which is, look at first order differences. If this dimension is the relevant one, effects on interest rates must be expected to unwind as soon as expectations on QE Level become zero. Analysing the flow dimension of Expectation Revisions means considering how much announcements change variations of expected QE Level, which is, look at second order differences. If this dimension is the relevant one, effects on interest rates must be expected to unwind as soon as changes of expectations on QE Level become zero. b. OMO Expectation Revision… The most intuitive way to analyse QE is to consider the effects on expected QE Level of single permanent purchases at their announcement, when each single Permanent OMO result is announced and the total amounts allotted into the specific securities that are to be purchased the following day. We shall call these one-day expectations “OMO Expectations” and their change “OMO Expectation Revision”. The graph in terms of QE Level described by OMO Expectations will track exactly the graph drawn by the actual QE Level, but one day in advance. 1. The OMO EXPECTATION at time t is the QE Level expected in t for t+1,resulting from Permanent OMO net purchases announced in t with certain settlement in t+1: ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘) ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1)] = πΈπ‘ [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + 1) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] = πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + 1) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1) I. The Stock Dimension of OMO Expectation Revision in day t shall be the difference of OMO Expectations in t for the day t+1 and the OMO Expectations in t=-1 for the day of start of QE, t=0: πππ ππππΆπΎ(π‘) ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1)] − πΈ−1 [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (0)] = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘) − ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (−1) 9 = [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + 1) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] − [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] = πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + 1) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘) = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1) II. The Flow dimension of OMO Expectation Revision shall be the difference of OMO Expectations in t for the day t+1 and the OMO Expectations for day t: πππ πΉπΏππ (π‘) ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1)] − πΈπ‘−1 [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘)] = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘) − ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘ − 1) = οππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏππππ (π‘) = πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + 1) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘) = βππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1) c. …which in practice translates into Spot looking analysis: Evidently, if we consider weekly data, the data on one-day expectations on Fed Size are almost4 equal to the data on the actual FED Size. Therefore, the weekly data on OMO Expectation are almost equal to the actual weekly QE Level data, and the analysis of OMO Expectation Revisions can more practically be done with an analysis of current QE Level, with no loss for the conceptual relevance of this variable. Daily Data: time tο(-∞,T) is in days in weeks πππ ππππΆπΎ(π‘) = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1) πππ πΉπΏππ(π‘) = βππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + 1) Weekly Data: time tο(-∞,T) is πππ ππππΆπΎ(π‘) = ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘) πππ πΉπΏππ(π‘) = βππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘) We will call this analysis “Spot Looking”, since it focuses on the current QE Levels, and rename the above variables as “Spot Stock” and “Spot Flow”. Notice that the stock variable reaches zero when the Balance Sheet returns to Pre-QE size. This 1. Differences for any week X arise only from a) The difference of the amount of Permanent purchases announced the last day of the week X-1, but settled in the first day of week X, and amount of Permanent purchases announced the last day of week X, but settled in the first day of week X+1. b) The difference in amounts of coupons and principal repayments received from Permanent Purchases in the first day of week X and their amounts for the first day of week X+1. We assume these differences to be zero. 10 is the extremisation of the Stock interpretation of Exit Strategy of the BoE. By contrast, the flow variable reaches zero when no new purchases are made. This is the Flow interpretation of Exit Strategy of the Fed. d. Program Expectation Revision: a Forward looking Analysis Market reactions to more general announcements on the future of QE programs suggest that the approach above may not yield a satisfactory explanation. To capture the effects of such program announcements the idea is to infer how much these announcements change the expected path of future permanent purchases, and utilise this change in longer-term QE expectations as independent variable. We shall call these longer-term expectations “Program Expectations” and their change “Program Expectation Revision”. We shall consider as Program Expectation the expected QE Level S month in the future, as inferable from the latest Program Announcement. 1. The PROGRAM EXPECTATION at time t is the QE Level expected for t+S, resulting from Permanent OMO net purchases announced in t with settlement up to t+S. We set S as time to longer-term Program Expectation: ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘) ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] = πΈπ‘ [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + π) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] = πΈπ‘ [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + π)] − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) I. The Stock Dimension of Program Expectation Revision shall be the difference of Program Expectations for the day t+S and the Program Expectations for the day of start of QE ππ ππΊπ π΄π ππππΆπΎ ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] − πΈ−π [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (0)] = ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘)−ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (−π) = 11 = πΈπ‘ [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(π‘ + π) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] − πΈ−π [πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0) − πΉπΈπ·ππΌππΈ(0)] = ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘) = πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] Strictly speaking, the above Expectation ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (−π) makes sense only if the first QE Program Announcement was announced in t≤-S, which is not true if we set this announcement at t=0. To settle the formality, we impose that if the First QE announcement is after –S, then ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (−π) = 0 II. The Flow dimension of Program Expectation Revision shall be the difference of Program Expectations in t for the day t+S and the Program Expectations in t-1 for day t-1+S: ππ ππΊπ π΄π πΉπΏππ ≡ πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] − πΈπ‘−1 [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ − 1 + π)] = ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘)−ππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘ − 1) = βππΈ πππ ππΊπ π΄π (π‘) Since these variables focus on the future, we will call their analysis “Forward Looking” and will refer to PROGRAM STOCK and to PROGRAM FLOW calling them FORWARD STOCK and FORWARD FLOW. Practical Specifications of the Independent Variables expressing Expectation Revisions on QE Level Spot Looking Analysis Forward Looking Analysis Stock Dimension ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘) πΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] Flow Dimension βππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘) βπΈπ‘ [ππΈπΏπΈππΈπΏ (π‘ + π)] 12 a. .How to compare the explanations? To compare the plausibility of our four different interpretations, we will consider which of the previous forms of the independent variable is more relevant in accounting for the change in the shape and form of the yield Curve. We will focus on USA BB+ Bonds Yield curves, comparing the adjusted R2 coefficients in significant regressions. 5. Dependent Variable: Capturing the effects of QE Expectation Revision, all channels considered. Coherently with the prospective of our research, explained in Section 1, we need to capture the effects of expectation revisions conveyed through all the channels that Literature has instead disaggregated. The logical Yield Curves to observe then are the ones for medium quality corporate bonds. We shall use the USA BB+ Bonds Yield Curves published by Standard&Poors Global Fixed Income Research, since they provide us with a nice weekly time series of effective rates on Wednesdays, for 5, 10, 15, 20 and 25 years maturities of industrial Corporate Bonds1. We will consider the average level of Yield Curves in its stock dimension, intended as the difference between initial (pre-QE) and current levels, since this is the most relevant dimension to understand the consequences of the Exit Strategy. An interesting integration of our analysis would have been to consider also shape features of the Yield Curves, such as their Slope and Convexity, or to focus on specific Maturities. This, however, is beyond the scope and resources of the present analysis, and is a possible extension of it. 1. AGGREGATE EFFECT ON YIELD CURVE Let us define i(t,s) as BB+ spot curve at time tο(0,T) for s months of maturities, sο(0,S). π Its average vertical value is πΌ(π‘) = {[∫π =0 π(π‘, π ) ππ ] /π} Its slope is ππΏπππΈ (π‘) = {[π(π‘, π) − π(π‘, 0)]/π} 13 Its convexity shall be πΆπππ (π‘) = π (π‘, π/2) − {[π(π‘, π) − π(π‘, 0)]/2} I. Then the variation in average Level can be computed as: π [π(π‘, π ) − π(0, π )]ππ ∫ βπΌ(π‘) = π =0 π Since in practice Yield Curves will be described by discrete points, the integral will be approximated as a discrete sum: ∑ππ =0 π(π‘, π ) − π(0, π ) βπ(π‘) = π II. The Convexity Variation Shall be defined as βπΆπππ(π‘) = πΆπππ(π‘) − πΆπππ(0) III. The Slope Variation shall be βππΏπππΈ(π‘) = ππΏπππΈ(π‘) − ππΏπππΈ(0) 2. EFFECT ON SPECIFIC MATURITIES For some relevant Maturities π ∈ { 0, 3, 6, 12, 24, 36, 60, 120 } we may compute the change βπ(π‘) = π( π‘, π) − π(0, π) 1 We choose S&P data over Dow Jones Investment Grade Corporate Bonds because a) S&P yields are effective, which is already corrected by volatility, whereas Dow Jones most suitable data would be Yield to worse, which is the Yield for a particular holding period. b) S&P Bond data is disaggregated for a wide range of ratings: BBB, A, AA and AAA data will be used for some robustness checks. c) Dow Jones Data are a mix of Investment Grade Bonds, including AAA. Safe Bonds are differently affected by the default risk channel. The total effect of Expectation Revision would be distorted by such a mix, since some channels (like the duration channel) would be considered always whereas some others (like the default risk) would be underrepresented. d) S&P Yield curve points are regularly spaced at 5y, 10y 15y, 20y and 25y maturities, therefore we may improperly consider arithmetical averages as some loose sort of 15-years equivalent. 14 6. Average Maturity, Control Variables and Caveats a. Average Maturity Up to now, in the definition of our four Independent Variables, we have overseen the “quality” of QE purchases, and only focused on their size. Evidently, we need to control for the average maturity (AM) of the purchases, since ceteris paribus a different the AM of the purchased assets will bring about different impact on the Yield Curves. For the spot Analysis, we will include the stock and flow dimension of the Average Maturity of non MBS SOMA Assets. The data here has been built1 using numerous “screenshots” of CUSIPlevel composition of SOMA balance sheet, completing the gaps with a linear evolution where the changes were small enough. MBS information is dropped, since it depends on complex expectations on prepayments. With regard to the Forward looking analysis, we will include the same variables with S weeks perfect foresight if a clear announcement on the future AM path is in place (like operation TWIST announcement). In absence of such an announcement, and if the NY Fed Operational Releases signals that the AM of purchases or reinvestments differs substantially from current AM, we will infer a reasonable path for future AM based on said releases. AM in years Three Models for SOMA nonMBS Average Maturity Model1: Correct AM using Weekly BS Data on remaining Face Values, ignores Coupons" 10 years 9 years Operation Twist Model 2: Approximative AM modelling H41 release on Maturity Breakdown" 8 years 7 years 6 years Date Model 3: AM using Daily OMO Data since 25/08/2005, computing expected coupons and repayments. Initially imprecise due to dynamic of holdiongs already held at 25/08/2005 " 1. The resulting time series (Model1) has been compared with the result of a much more extensive analysis based on CUSIP level Permanent OMO Purchases since 2005 (Model2), and a model of H.4.1 FED Release. The result is accurate enough for the period when the comparison was possible. 15 2. The main reference for macro control variables is Wu, 2013. b. Business Cycle Controls We consider the inclusion of some standard2 coincident controls for the business cycle and other economic and market conditions that may influence Yield Curves: 1. Output Gap: US Output gap as a percentage of Nominal Potential GDP published by the CBO. 2. Unemployment Gap: Seasonally Adjusted Civilian Unemployment- Natural Rate of Unemployment by the CBO 3. Inflation: Trimmed-Mean 1-month PCE Inflation, Annual Rate (%), by FRB Dallas 4. Consumer Confidence on Present Situation: Seasonally adjusted, by the Conference Board, indexed 1985. 5. Financial Market Volatility: Bank of America Merrill Lynch Option Volatility 1 month (MOVE 1m) 6. Industrial Production: Seasonally adjusted, by Haver Analytics, indexed 2007. Selection among these Control Variables will be Justified in Section 6 Clearly, we will not control for Expected Inflation, Expected Volatility, or Consumer Confidence for the Future, etc., since these controls on expectations would interfere with our analysis of the Independent Variable. We will only control for the differences in present economic conditions. c. Omission of Other UMP tools First and foremost, our analysis has the limit of not considering the effects of Forward Guidance, which is deeply intermingled with the QE tool1. It would have been useful to control for Forward Guidance Announcements, but it is beyond our scope and resources. Secondly, we are not going to consider the Local Supply effects on the tern structure and on the aggregate Yield Curve. Especially considering the period that we are going to analyse, at the height of the crisis, intraday effects can be relevant, if minor compared to Expectation Revision effects2. However, since BAA Corporate Bonds were not directly purchased in QE operations, 1. The issue of interrelation between Forward Guidance and QE Effects is central in Wu, 2013. 2. See Daines, Joyce and Tong, 2012, “QE and the Gilt Market, a Disaggregated Analysis”, BOE Working Paper 466 and D’Amico and King, 2012, “Flow and Stock Effects of LSAP: Evidence on the importance of Local Supply”, FEDS Working Papers. 16 and since we are taking weekly data, our concerns greatly diminish. Finally, the same applies for the effects of the Emergency Liquidity facilities that the Fed created at the height of the Crisis. Controlling for their effects would be useful, but it is not possible here. d. Major Assumptions used to project Expectations In the process of projection of the future expected paths of the Fed Size, some assumptions had to be made. In particular, 1. Expectations paths and revisions are designed after the details officially announced by the Fed1. In reality, market participants have sometimes2 anticipated, overestimated or underestimated these announcements. Therefore, Yield Curve reactions on announcements may at times reflect the effect of a partial correction of expectations, as some revision has already taken place3. This limitation is almost inevitable, and common to all Literature studying the Effects of QE by channels3. Controlling for the amount and quality of QE action already priced in by the markets is well beyond the scope and resources of our work, and probably impossible. Even limiting our attention to the expectations of the Primary Dealers, the Primary Dealer Survey published by the NY Fed is only available after 2011, and its detail is insufficient3 to design expected paths for expected Fed size. Moreover, even assuming that it was possible to build such paths, we are interested in reconstructing the effects of QE, not of its perception. As a consequence, we would need to distinguish to what extent the changes of these curves are an anticipation of a determined future announcement, how much they overestimate or underestimate it, or to what extent, for instance, they are a correction for the reaction to a previous announcement …Such distinctions would be largely arbitrary. These considerations however do not prevent us from using consensus information to firm the interpretation of some parts of QE announcements. 2. The weekly decays of Treasuries, Agency Debt and MBS that are expected to take place in case of no new purchases or no reinvestment of principal and coupon repayments have been assumed to be equal to a 12 months moving average of the reductions of the above listed balance sheet items unjustified by net purchases. The resulting decays are approximatively consistent with the (scarce) information provided by the NY Fed releases on reinvestments. Decays are assumed linear, and not exponential: this implies 1. Some general inspiration and guidance on this point came from Wu, 2013. 2. See Foerster and Cao, 2013, “Expectations of Large Scale Asset Purchases”, Economic Review Second Quarter 2013, Kansas City FRB, where the problem is discussed in depth. 3. For instance, consider the case of the market reactions to Jackson Hole Speech of Bernanke in 27/08/2010, anticipating QE2 official Announcement on 03/11/2010. Even more interesting is the 100Bp jump of 10 years treasury Yields in the weeks following mid May 2013, as ex-post misleading news of imminent tapering started to spread. 17 3. 4. 5. 6. 7. that our projections of expectations become inaccurate for distant times in the future. Finally, if a reinvestment policy is in place, we derive that holdings are expected to never decay, coherently with the assumption at point 1 above. Purchases of any given asset are assumed to be distributed smoothly between the date of start of purchases of that asset and the date of ending of purchases for that asset, where not differently announced. The starting dates of purchases are set for the week after announcement where not differently announced, and then possibly modified according to a reality check on the actual start of purchases. For QE1, the 2008 announcements do not specify how much time it would have taken to complete the purchases of Agency Debt and MBS. We assume that “Several Quarters” on 25/11/08 and then “Few Quarters” on 30/12/08 mean “by 15 September 2009” consistently with subsequent announcement of slowdown and available surveys. For QE2, the announced program was due to purchase 600Bn of treasuries by June 2010. However, these purchases were completed by early May, and by the end of June additional 175Bn were purchased. I assume that the program expected ending date was kept on June 30 until 11/05/2010, when it is suddenly revised since the total amount of scheduled purchases is reached. When tapering is announced, I assume that the expectation path includes a 10Bn taper for all following meetings, in line with consensus at that date and reality so far. This is justified as an interpretation of the FOMC Statements formula “ If incoming information supports… (etc.), the committee will likely reduce the pace of assets purchases in further measured steps at future meetings” Expected Fed Size ($Mil) Projected Expectations: QE1 1200000 1000000 800000 600000 400000 200000 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 Horizon of Expectation: Months ahead 05 November 2008 12 November 2008 19 November 2008 26 November 2008 03 December 2008 10 December 2008 17 December 2008 24 December 2008 31 December 2008 07 January 2009 14 January 2009 21 January 2009 28 January 2009 04 February 2009 11 February 2009 18 February 2009 25 February 2009 04 March 2009 11 March 2009 18 7. Empirical Evidence. a. The Data Set We will consider 300 Weekly Observations, from 19/11/2008 to 13/08/2014. The Dependent Variable, as explained in Section 4, is the difference between current BB+ Average Yield and Pre QE BB+ Average Yield. All the coefficients represent the impact in Basis Points on the dependent variable of a unit variation in the Independent or Control Variable, and the unit for all QE Variables is $100 Billion. Even if their values are not reported, all regressions include a constant. Coefficients whose significance is weak are underlined. The Forward Looking analysis includes Program Expectation Variables with expectation projected for horizons S of 1 month, 2 months, 3 months, 6 months and 12 months. b. A first comparison without control variables A first comparison is possible among the explanatory power of the four different forms of the Independent Variable before control variables are included. Tables 1 and 2 below show the results for independent Variables in their Stock and Flow dimension: Table1 Stock of Independent Variable (100Billion$) QE Level Expected QE Level 1m Expected QE Level 2m Expected QE Level 3m Expected QE Level 6m Expected QE Level 12m Coefficient (Bp/100Bil$) t-Statistic (P-Value) Adjusted R2 -17,3181 -17,4984 -17,5191 -17,3796 -16,2159 -13,4351867084359 -32,6347 (0,0000%) -31,3802 (0,0000%) -29,7432 (0,0000%) -27,8339 (0,0000%) -23,0163 (0,0000%) -21,7261 (0,0000%) 78,0635% 76,6902% 74,7180% 72,1270% 63,8780% 61,1700% 19 Table2 Flow of Independent Variable (100Billion$) ΔQE Level Δ Expected QE Level 1m Δ Expected QE Level 2m Δ Expected QE Level 3m Δ Expected QE Level 6m Δ Expected QE Level 12m Coefficient (Bp/100Bil$) t-Statistic (P-Value) Adjusted R2 96,3804553774222 85,9803825412457 77,1580712385115 63,6975640299625 3,36548010422004 12,9896522642099 2,1025 (3,6341%) 2,4463 (1,5010%) 2,6666 (0,8080%) 2,6881 (0,7589%) 2,5159 (1,2397%) 1,2831 (20,0450%) 1,1274% 1,6397% 2,0029% 2,0398% 1,7514% 0,2157% We can see that even if all forms are significant, 1. Independent Variables in their Stock Dimension are far more significant and explicative to the Dependent Variable than in their Flow Dimension. 2. Both significance and explanatory power fade away as Expectation Horizon stretches further in the future. An interesting detail to notice is how Flow Explanatory Power initially increases with time Horizon. Robustness check: The regressions in the tables above have been replicated for BBB Average Yields. For BBB data, we witness a generalised reduction in explanatory power (Adjusted R2 ranging from 39% to 34% for Stocks and from -0,003% to -0,001% for Flows) and significance (Tstatistic ranging from 19 to 12,5 for Stocks and from -0,69 to -0,19 for Flows). In particular, flows are not significant at any conventional level. However, aside from this generalised loss, the two trends underlined above for BB+ Yield Curves remain perfectly confirmed. c. Explanatory power, significance and selection of Control Variables. Now, let us turn to the Macroeconomic Controls. We will first check how much explanatory power and significance these controls provide on their own, before including the independent variables. The results are included in table 3 below. 20 Table3 Consumer Confidence MOVE (Index) Unemployment Gap Output Gap PCE 12m Industrial Production Adjusted R2 F Statistic Selected Controls -7,3101460522772 29,409081778305 -132,6226738880630 -78,3014214411354 90,6167% 722,8761 (0,0000%) T Stat -7,91317 -12,3581 19,75933 -13,5184 All Controls -4,59956361264181 1,38672195835272 -152,83974381166600 26,11446395301120 15,63967035468080 -37,80446337363200 T Stat -9,3149 9,3198 -19,0411 3,0752 2,6846 -15,5255 94,8347% 915,9452 (0,0000%) We notice that the set including all controls have high significance and explanatory Power. However, in our complete regressions we will drop PCE Inflation and Industrial Production, retaining only the “Selected Controls”. Here is why: 1. Industrial Production. Industrial Production generates a major problem of multicollinearity with Output gap: this is evident from the massive reshuffle in T Statistics between the two whose sum, however, is stable. In fact, a quick check shows that their correlation in our data is 94%. After some further checks, we decided to exclude IP rather than Output Gap. 2. Inflation. We can notice from the table above that PCE Inflation shows already a weaker significance than the other variables. Secondly, its inclusion generated a discrete drop in significance of the QE Independent Variables when they are included. This is probably due to the particular relevance that inflation data has had on QE decisions. Moreover, since we focus on expectations, considering expected inflation is likely to pose a dangerous problem. Final and decisive remark: Inflation generates a serious problem of multicollinearity with all other control Variables (Linear Correlation with MOVE: - 76%, with Consumer Confidence:-79%, with Unemployment Gap: -72%, and with Output Gap: 81%) Robustness Check: The above regression including the set of Selected Control Variables has been replicated on Average Yields for BBB, A, AA and AAA bonds. The explanatory power drops, but not beyond reasonable levels (BBB, 66%; A: 78%, AA: 70%, AAA: 68%) and even though some variables lose significance at times, overall regression significance remains very high. 21 d. Controlling for Average Maturity As previously anticipated in Section 5, we will include a control for Fed’s Average Maturity, both current and Expected. This will give traction to Twist Program Announcements, even if they did not announce a change in the future size of the Fed, but just a change in its future Balance Sheet composition. We will only consider Average Maturity of Non-MBS Holdings, since the data on MBS maturity is scarcely informative due to the complexity of MBS prepayment expectations. The outcomes of Average Maturity inclusion are shown in table 4 below. Table4 Consumer Confidence MOVE Unemployment Gap Output Gap AM (Days) Adjusted R2 F Statistic Selected Controls+ AM T Stat AM T Stat -6,7611 2,8539 -139,0428 -80,6626 -0,000319220272 90,7820% 589,931 (0,0000%) -10,8037 18,8325 -13,8283 -11,7413 -2,5082 -0,00175647894963713 -14,076 39,7339% Robustness Check: We considered the impact on significance and explanatory power of AM inclusion in regressions for BB+ and BBB Average Yields. The results in terms of T Statistics and Adjusted R2 are shown below in table 5: Table5 T Statistics Consumer Confidence MOVE Unemployment Gap Output Gap AM (Days) Adjusted R2 BB+ including AM BB+ excluding AM -10,80 18,83 -13,83 -11,74 -2,51 90,78% BBB including AM -12,3581 19,76 -13,52 -11,40 90,62% BBB excluding AM 3,73 -9,40 8,58 8,44 1,29 65,99% 4,46 -9,95 8,52 8,33 65,91% Clearly, the impact on significance is limited, and positive for certain variables. Similar checks have been done on regressions including QE Independent Variables. 22 e. The complete regression comparison We will now include both Independent and Control Variables in complete regressions. Tables 6 and 7 below include Independent Variables in their Stock dimension, whereas tables 8 and 9 include their Flow dimension. Table6 Stock QE Level T Stat QE Level Expected QE Level 1m Expected QE Level 2m Expected QE Level 3m Consumer Confidence MOVE Unemployme nt Gap Output Gap -13,1 -12,32 AM (Days) Adjusted R2 F Statistic 0,3984 1,6571 0,52 10,56 1 Month T Stat -8,5949 -8,63 2 Month T Stat -10,3351 -9,65 -0,98 13,13 10,40 10,15 -7,01 -3,3688 2,1263 -4,83 13,76 -0,8027 2,0445 -95,6082 -10,74 -106,7836 -10,85 -100,8789 -45,2343 -7,20 -0,1147 -9,29 93,91% 768,81 -49,0812 -0,0468 92,86% 648,98 -7,32 -6,13 -62,9949 -0,0836 93,03% 665,70 For Stock Variables we can see that: 1. All QE Variables, for both current and expected QE Levels, are highly significant. 2. Significance of both overall regressions (F-Statistics) and of QE variables (T-Statistics) diminish as expectation horizon increases. However, the dynamic near 2-3 months horizon seems a partial exception to this trend. 3. Explanatory Power (Adjusted R2) slightly diminishes as expectation horizon increases. Once more, the dynamic near 2-3 months horizon seems a partial exception to this trend. 4. The coefficients are negative, just as we would expect. In particular, their magnitude is consistent with the magnitude of Yield reactions that literature1 associates with QE Programs. 23 5. The magnitude of QE coefficients diminishes as expectation horizon increases. Again, the dynamic near 2-3 months horizon seems a partial exception to this trend. Table7 Stock Expected QE Level 3m Expected QE Level 6m Expected QE Level 12m Consumer Confidence MOVE Unemployment Gap Output Gap AM(Days) Adjusted R2 F Statistic 3 Month T Stat -9,2071 -8,85 - 1,6172 2,1727 6 Month T Stat -6,2030 -6,20 12 Month T Stat -3,6775 -4,27 -2,03 14,24 -3,3795 2,5510 -4,12 17,22 -5,0621 2,6910 -6,44 18,21 -105,7872 -10,67 -65,3578 -10,59 -0,0727 -6,69 92,84% 647,28 -115,6254 -70,3961 -0,0477 92,02% 575,63 -11,05 -10,95 -4,93 -125,1953 -64,9754 -0,0353 91,57% 542,26 -11,87 -9,43 -4,34 1. Compare, for instance, our coefficients with the table at page 8of Foerster and Cao, 2013, “Expectations of Large Scale Asset Purchases”, Economic Review Second Quarter 2013, Kansas City FRB. Consider, for instance, QE2, which announced 600Bn purchases to be completed in approximatively six months. Our QE Level coefficient suggests an 84 Bp Drop, a reasonable 20% above the upper estimate that Literature gives for the 10 years Treasury Yields drop. In a separate regression, for better comparability, I considered only 10 years BB+ Yields, instead of Yield Curve Averages, and the coefficients were almost unchanged (-13.95 Bp/100Bn$) still giving an 84 Bp drop for QE2. 24 Table8 Flow Δ QE Level ΔQE Level 48,3641 Δ Expected QE Level 1m Δ Expected QE Level 2m Δ Expected QE Level 3m Consumer Confidence -7,0435 MOVE 2,8088 Unemployment Gap -141,5315 Output Gap -74,9964 AM (Days) -0,0368 2 Adjusted R 91,08% F Statistic 509,8574 For Flow Variables we can see that: T Stat 3,29 Δ 1 Month T Stat 23,0263 2,13 Δ 2 Month T Stat 25,2479 2,82 -11,33 18,76 - 7,4782 -13,01 2,773 18,53 -6,7722 -11,19 2,7932 18,50 -14,27 -10,75 -2,92 -142,0844 -14,37 -69,988 -10,12 -0,0328 -3,94 -139,7197 -14,03 -77,6951 -11,44 -0,0392 -3,18 91,05% 508,0607 91,18% 516,2049 1. Not all QE Variables are highly significant. 2. Significance of QE variables (T-Statistics) diminishes as expectation horizon increases. However, the dynamic near 2-3 months horizon seems a partial exception to this trend. 3. Explanatory Power (Adjusted R2) remains almost constant as expectation horizon increases. This is a consequence of the scarce impact of Expectation Variables. 4. The coefficients are positive, differently from what we would expect. A possible explanation for this may be that the positivity of the “Second derivative” of QE is associated with the worsening of market conditions. Still, the explanation that is more likely to be sensible is that the flow dimension of our QE variables is simply not reliable. 5. The magnitude of QE coefficients diminishes as expectation horizon increases. The dynamic near 2-3 months horizon seems a partial exception to this trend. 25 Table9 Flow Δ Expected QE Level 3m Δ Expected QE Level 6m Δ Expected QE Level 12m Consumer Confidence MOVE Unemployment Gap Output Gap AM(Days) Adjusted R2 F Statistic Δ 3 Month T Stat 19,9334 2,76 -6,9052 -11,82 2,7499 18,13 Δ 6 Month T Stat 13,472 2,79 T Stat 5,8477 1,93 -7,3104 2,7913 -12,67 18,62 -1,4189 -14,22 -1,4083 -14,13 -1,417 -76,5711 -11,44 -74,7132 -11,15 -72,7178 -0,0422 -3,71 -0,0377 -3,77 -0,0333 91,16% 91,21% 91,16% -14,28 -10,68 -4,00 514,7078 -7,0528 -12,26 2,7624 18,31 Δ 12 Month 517,9684 514,707 Robustness Check: All the regressions shown in the four tables above have been replicated using BBB Yield Curves Averages as dependent variable. Significance and Explanatory Power of overall regressions diminish, but remain at acceptable levels. However, regressions in which one or more variables turn out to be not significant are more frequent. In any case, the analysis BBB Yields does not contradict the ten points highlighted above. 26 8. Conclusions Our empirical analysis suggests that a Flow interpretation of QE seems less reliable than a Stock one, and that information on the current levels of the size of QE retain more explanatory power than our projections of expectations for the longer term. In particular, our results for the Stock dimension confirm the relationship between QE and Yield Curves that is presented in the Literature, both in its sign and, for QE current levels, in its magnitude. In general, we have observed that the further in time we project expectations, the lower their relevance becomes. This conclusion seems to support a stronger relevance of current levels of asset purchases than future expected ones. However, this result may depend on two other factors. First, the models that we have used to project expectations becomes less accurate for longer horizons. Second, as discussed in the “Caveats” section, real expectations for the longer term are created in a more complex process than the one that can be modelled after official announcements. Actually, this process includes a variable degree of anticipation of official announcements, and continuous adjustments of these anticipations. Our model, centred on official FOMC announcements, inevitably approximates the real process of expectation formation. Moreover, the fact that current levels seem more significant and explanatory should not shade another result of our analysis, possibly more relevant: Expectations for the longer term in their Stock dimension retain high significance and explanatory power on the Average level of Medium-Quality Yield Curves. Therefore, even if caution is needed in emphasising current size of the FED’s Balance Sheet over its future expected one, as far as implications for the exit strategy are concerned, this enquiry suggests that a normalisation of the effects of QE will take some time, coherently with a stock interpretation of it. 27 9. References Fundamental reference for this analysis: ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· Daines, Martin, Michael A.S Joyce and Matthew Tong, 2012. “QE and the gilt market, a disaggregated analysis”, Bank of England Working Paper No 466. D’Amico, Stefania and Thomas B.King, 2012. “Flow and Stock Effects of Large Scale Asset Purchases: Evidence on the importance of Local Supply”, Finance and Economic Discussion Series, No 2010-52, Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September. Foerster, Andrew and Guangjye Cao, 2013. “Expectations of Large Scale Asset Purchases”, Economic Review Second Quarter 2013, Kansas City Federal Reserve Bank. IMF Report 2013a “Unconventional Monetary Policy- Recent Experience and Prospects” Krishnamurhy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgestern, 2010 “The Aggregate Demand for Treasury Debt”, Northwestern University. Krishnamurhy, Arvind and Annette Vissing-Jorgestern, 2011. “The Effects of Quantitative Easing on Interest Rates, Channels and Implications for Policy”, NBER. Wu, Tao, 2013. “Unconventional Monetary Policy and Long Term Interest Rates”, IMF. Other essential reference on topic: ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· Bernanke, Ben S., Vincent R. Reinhart and Brian P. Sack, 2004. “Monetary Policy Alternatives at the Zero Lower Bound: an Empirical Assessment”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol.1, pp. 1341-93. Chen, Han, Vasco Curdia and Andrea Ferrero, 2012. “The Macroeconomic Effects of LargeScale Asset Purchases Programs: Rationale and Effects”, Federal Reserve Board, Working Paper. Eggertson, Gauti, and Michael Woodford, 2003. “The Zero Bound on Interest Rates and Optimal Monetary Policy”, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol.1, pp. 139-211. Gagnon, Joseph, Matthew Raskin, Julie Remache and Brian Sack, 2011. “The Financial Market Effects of the Federal Reserve’s Large-Scale Asset Purchases”, International Journal of Central Banking in a Zero Lower Bound Environment, Vol.7, No 1, pp. 3-43. Hamilton, James D. and Jing Cynthia Wu, 2012. “The Effectiveness of Alternative Monetary Policy Tools in a Zero Lower Bound Environment”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol.44, pp. 3-46. 28 ο· ο· ο· ο· ο· Harrison, Richard, 2011. “Asset Purchase Policies and Portfolio Balance Effects: a DSGE Analysis”, in Chadha, J., and Holly, S., (eds), Interest Rates, Prices and Liquidity, Cambridge University Press, Chapter 5. Harrison, Richard, 2012. “Asset Purchase Policy at the Effective Lower Bound for Interest Rates” Bank of England Working Paper No 444. Neely, Christopher, 2011. “The Large –Scale Asset Purchases Had Large International Effects”, Federal Reserve Bank of Saint Louis, Working Paper. Swanson, Eric T., 2011. “Let’s Twist Again: a High-Frequency Event-Study Analysis of Operation Twist and Its Implications for QE2”, Federal Reserve Bank on San Francisco, Working Paper No 2011-08. Vajanos, Dimitri and Jean-Luc Vila, 2009. “A Preferred Habitat Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates”, NBER Working Paper No 15487. 29