All above board all above board great governance for the government sector – second edition Julie Garland McLellan Julie Garland McLellan Government sector organisations are important. They provide many of the essential goods and services that underpin society, and allow industry and commerce to function efficiently. They are diverse and span almost every sector of industry from agriculture to zoo-keeping. The directors who serve on government sector boards play a vital role in the success of the nation. Until the publication of All Above Board there was no comprehensive guide to assist in developing and applying governance skills specifically for the government sector. Now in its second edition, All Above Board will help directors, and those who work with them, to develop the skills required for great governance and great outcomes. Second Edition Second Edition all above board great governance for the government sector 1 2 3 4 AICD-AAB_COVS-16mm_PRINT.indd 1 4/10/11 2:27 PM 2 Logo To cate applica brandi selecti To hel artwor for you 1 All Above Board Great governance for the government sector 2 Second Edition Our lo To mai use an Artwo 1 Maste Our log of colo applica and wh on the 2 Second When our sec appear consist 3 Mono For bla as fax s the log solid b 4 Julie Garland McLellan With foreword by the Hon Nick Greiner AC FAICD (Life) 3 4 Mono This ve the log third p as a sp logo re solid b All Above Board The Australian Institute of Company Directors is a member institute for directors dedicated to having a positive influence on the economy and society by promoting professional directorship and good governance. Company Directors delivers director development programs, information and advocacy to enrich the capabilities of directors, influence the corporate governance environment in Australia and promote understanding of and respect for the role of directors. With offices in each state of Australia and more than 27,000 members, Company Directors represents a diverse range of organisations from the top ASX 200 publicly listed companies to not-for-profits, public sector entities and private companies. Disclaimer The material in this publication does not constitute legal, accounting or other professional advice. While reasonable care has been taken in its preparation, Company Directors does not make any express or implied representations or warranties as to the completeness, reliability or accuracy of the material in this publication. This publication should not be used or relied upon as a substitute for professional advice or as a basis for formulating business decisions. To the extent permitted by law, Company Directors excludes all liability for any loss or damage arising out of the use of the material in the publication. Any links to third party websites are provided for convenience only and do not represent endorsement, sponsorship or approval of those third parties, any products and services offered by third parties, or as to the accuracy or currency, of the information included in third party websites. Copyright Copyright strictly reserved. The text, graphics and layout of this guide are protected by Australian copyright law and the comparable law of other countries. The copyright of this material is vested in Company Directors. No part of this material can be reproduced or transmitted in any form, or by any means electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording or by any information storage and retrieval systems without the written permission of the Australian Institute of Company Directors. Published in October 2011 by: The Australian Institute of Company Directors Level 2, 255 George Street Sydney NSW 2000 T: 61 2 8248 6600 F: 61 2 8248 6633 E:publications@companydirectors.com.au W:www.companydirectors.com.au © 2011 Australian Institute of Company Directors. Design by Kirk Palmer Design Printed by Ligare Pty Ltd National Library of Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication entry Title: All Above Board: Great governance for the government sector ISBN 978-0-9871901-4-7 Subjects:Corporate governance Government boards Public sector governance Contents Acknowledgmentsix xi Foreword to the second edition Introductionxiii Chapter 1 Corporate Governance in Context What is governance? Governance structures and definitions What constitutes good governance? The value of good corporate governance A brief history of governance The development of corporate governance in the government-owned sector The current governance status quo The difference between boards and committees Chapter 2 Government Operations The Australian government framework Federal government The federal government law-making process The Australian Constitution Council of Australian Governments State and federal governments Local governments Government departments State and federal treasuries Portfolio departments Liabilities and rights of elected officials and staff Importance of the public sector iii 1 1 3 4 6 6 9 13 15 17 17 18 19 21 22 22 26 27 29 31 33 35 iv All Above Board Classification of public sector organisations Legislation and regulation 37 40 Chapter 3 Key Governance Roles in Government 45 45 46 47 49 50 51 53 54 57 58 The role of elected representatives Fiduciary duties Profitable organisations or community benefits Community service obligations The role of parliament The role of the government as shareholder Key ministerial roles The portfolio minister The shareholder minister Local government shareholder roles Chapter 4 Board Operations General governance functions Reporting and accountability functions The integrity and value of reports The annual general meeting Performance audits and reporting Board meeting agendas Board papers Board meetings Technology in the boardroom Minutes and recording decisions Workshops and seminars Board tours and site visits 61 61 62 63 64 65 66 69 72 74 75 76 77 Contents Board performance reviews Board composition and recruitment Composition Recruitment Board committees Audit committee Remuneration committee Other board committees Chapter 5 Key Governance Roles in Corporations The chairman Individual board members Nominee directors Moving from government to boards Right to information Confidentiality Conflicts of interest Directors’ skills Personal risks of directorships Gaining financial and legal knowledge Indemnity Deeds of access Insurance The chief executive The difference between chief executive and managing director Key governance roles of senior executives The company secretary The chief financial officer 78 81 82 85 86 88 90 91 93 93 97 98 99 100 101 101 102 105 106 107 108 109 109 111 112 112 113 v vi All Above Board The general or corporate counsel The risk manager The prosecuting officer External advisers The difference between consultants and contractors How to manage consultants Developing selection criteria Conflicts of interest when appointing consultants 113 114 115 115 117 118 118 119 Chapter 6 Policy, Strategy and Planning 121 121 122 124 126 127 132 140 140 141 144 147 148 148 149 150 153 155 156 The role of public policy Who develops public policy? The effects of policy changes The role of the government in policy How policy is developed The role of the board in strategy Strategy retreats Key planning documents Statement of corporate intent Corporate plan Business plan Succession plans Gaining familiarity with the plans Practical tools for planning SWOT analysis Scenario planning Industry competitive forces Core competence agenda Contents The firm value chain The balanced business scorecard and strategy maps The regulatory diamond Chapter 7 Risk Management, Finance and Reporting The role of the board in risk management Risk processes and structures The Australian and New Zealand standard on risk management Establishing a context Identifying risks Analysing risks Evaluating risks Treating risks Reporting risk Financial requirements and disclosure Continuous disclosure Government observers The annual general meeting Triple bottom line reporting Diverse stakeholders National tax equivalent regime Dividends and other payments to the shareholder Ring-fencing requirements Public monies Purchasing and tendering Grants Private-sector funding 157 158 160 161 161 164 167 167 168 170 171 172 173 175 178 179 181 181 182 184 185 187 188 189 190 191 vii viii All Above Board Chapter 8 Ethics and its Place in Business Life 195 What is ethics? The business case for ethics The role of the board in creating an ethical organisation The effect of changes in the environment Common ethical issues in government-owned organisations Remuneration levels Dedicating resources to training Downsizing and related issues Conflict between taxpayers and public interest Receiving gifts and entertainment Displays of religious, political or cultural significance Conflicts between personal agendas and current policy The legislative context The current Public Service Act The current values Criminal acts Bribery Manslaughter Statutory duties 195 196 197 201 203 203 204 205 205 206 207 207 208 209 211 212 212 213 214 Likely Future Developments 215 Appendices 1 List of acronyms and abbreviations 2 Governance codes 3 Bibliography 217 219 225 Acknowledgments I would like to pay tribute to everyone who helped with this book, especially the staff in the various government departments I have interacted with, and the board members who have so graciously shared their knowledge. Heartfelt thanks are due to my current and former boardroom colleagues: they have taught me practically everything that is in these pages. Particular recognition is due to my family, David and Andrew McLellan, for their patience, tolerance, love and support while I have been busy completing the text. Finally, I would like to thank the team at the Australian Institute of Company Directors for their role in bringing this book to publication. Julie Garland McLellan FAICD About the author: Julie Garland McLellan is a professional non-executive director with experience on a range of boards and committees including Federal, State and Local government-owned organisations. Her experience on listed and not-for-profit boards allows her to identify and communicate the differences that make government sector boards uniquely challenging and ultimately rewarding. Julie understands how different communities, external stakeholders, customers, suppliers, staff, investors, regulators, policy makers, management and boards influence a company. She is a former Australian Institute of Company Directors Councillor and has developed and facilitated Australian Institute of Company Directors’ courses. She is the author of The Director’s Dilemma, a newsletter with subscribers in 36 countries, and also of two internationally acclaimed books Dilemmas, Dilemmas: Practical Case Studies for Company Directors and Presenting to Boards. ix x All Above Board Foreword “A board is not a board is not a board.” W hen I introduced the State Owned Corporations Act in 1989 in New South Wales, indeed when I first joined the boards of QBE and Stockland in 1992, the expression “corporate governance” was barely known, much less studied and the focus of massive political, regulatory and media attention. These days, to paraphrase Paul Keating, every galah in every pet shop is talking about corporate governance. Clearly, the origin of this focus in the last two decades lies in the many listed company failures and scandals that occurred in most western economies, and to which Australia was certainly not immune. Governments and communities moved to develop and enforce new standards, structural and behavioural, to help protect the interests of shareholders and all stakeholders. Groups representing investors and directors, among others, developed their own views and interpretations of best practice to go with a range of legislative and regulatory initiatives. Naturally this has led to attention on governance practices at private companies, not-for-profit non-government organisations (NGOs), and of course, the public sector with its huge variety of institutional forms that often have boards. This second edition of All Above Board provides a readable and accessible approach to understanding the governance of single shareholder entities – large and small, corporate and advisory – operating at the complex interface of politics, public service and the community. With the use of many practical examples, it clarifies both for new directors starting their careers in this sector, a common and successful route for many, and for experienced private sector directors, the similarities and differences, formal and informal, between government boards and others. xi xii All Above Board The temptation to simply take the private listed company template and slavishly apply it is resisted but the many applicable aspects are articulated. This book will help public sector directors answer simple but crucial questions. Why are we here? How do we reconcile our role with expectations of shareholder, ministers, portfolio ministers and myriad stakeholder groups? What are our legal powers and responsibilities? To whom are we accountable? How do notions of best practice apply to the particular board on which I am invited to serve? The backgrounds of government directors reflect far greater diversity in every sense than in, say, the ASX 200. As such, All Above Board provides an effective means of creating a common understanding of governance as it is now. It is of course a living, breathing practice which changes with changing community standards and expectations. Dare I say, it should also be compulsory reading for politicians who find themselves responsible for appointing and dealing with boards, often with little or no relevant experience of their own. At the end, however, no matter how comprehensive and useful a guide this book is, directors will understand that it can only be an aid to their individual application of values, views and common sense, which led to their selection. Hon Nick Greiner AC FAICD (Life) Sydney, Australia September, 2011 Introduction The role of a company director is complex and multifaceted. At times it provides a control function; at other times, a motivating one. At all times it is a vigilant and prudent risk-taking role. Experts around the world agree that directorship is a blend of art and skill and that it requires people of good judgment, high integrity, deep experience, ability to work in a team, and advanced leadership skills. In the government sector the aims of the organisation can be far more complex than those of commercial-sector corporations, and the range of experiences, qualifications and personalities that govern the sector make it an exciting and unpredictable place to be. This book highlights the practical issues for anyone embarking on a career as a director in the government-owned sector. No single issue takes precedence except, perhaps, the duty to act in good faith and for a proper purpose. All events are important at the time they affect the organisation. The hallmark of a good board is to help keep the organisation ahead of the game, so that issues are managed before they trigger an adverse event and correct priorities are maintained as the organisation progresses towards its strategic objectives. The government sector is diverse: it contains many different sizes and types of organisations governed by company directors whose only similarity is their duty towards, and frequent passion for, the organisation and its mission. The challenges are as varied as the directors who successfully guide these organisations. Sections of this book will be important for different organisations at different times. Selecting the time to tackle each issue and bring it all together to create a high-performance organisation is a balancing act that each director will address in his or her own way. This book has been written as a practical guide for people who are serving on, aspiring to serve on boards, or working in an organisation that has an interface with a government sector board. It is not a basic guide to directorship but will provide a useful reference for people who are familiar with directorship and governance in the commercial or not-for-profit sectors, so they may effectively transfer their skills to the government sector. xiii xiv All Above Board Although the book is written from an Australian perspective, the information it contains is not jurisdiction-specific and, with a little effort, can help directors in other countries. Indeed feedback about the first edition from international readers has been used to enhance the rationale for the development of government sector governance practices in Australia. The book contains a short guide to some of the international governance codes and explains the principles, which will allow the reader to apply these in their own context and understand how international influences affect governance at National, State and Local levels. Many different organisations operate under government ownership. These organisations generally have two things in common: 1.They are owned by a single shareholder, which paves the way for the board and management to develop a close relationship. 2.They have a specific objective to achieve. This is frequently, but not always, more important than generating a high financial return on the shareholder’s funds. This book aims to help the reader develop a good relationship with the shareholder and achieve the organisation’s strategic objectives. A range of names is used for incorporated bodies within the government sector – entities, enterprises, companies, corporations, authorities, commissions, and probably a few that even the author has not yet encountered. What they have in common is a separate incorporation. To avoid confusion, this book refers to all of the different classes of incorporated bodies as “organisations”. The government sector uses many acronyms to abbreviate the names and functions of organisations, processes and institutions. Where possible, this book has avoided acronyms in favour of the complete word. Some are unavoidable, and where an acronym is in current and frequent widespread use it has been used in the text. Australia has a three-level government structure with a federation, or commonwealth, uniting and serving the State and Territory governments as well as providing assistance to the Local government sector within each State. This gives rise to a complex matrix of rules, laws, guidelines and regulations that affect organisations in the sector. This book has not attempted to reproduce, or even reference, all the applicable legal instruments. Instead, it has selected legislative introduction instruments from all three levels and from different States and Territories to illustrate the points. The reader is advised to find comparable instruments in their own jurisdiction and to compare and contrast them with the examples in this book. Understanding your own legal environment and how it differs from others is one of the hallmarks of an experienced director. To assist in understanding the law, this book makes use of practical examples of organisations that demonstrate legal principles. Australian government sector organisations operate under a combination of precedent and statute law. Legal precedent operates in a specific way: the older cases establish the rules that are applied to newer cases. In Australian law courts it is quite usual for cases to refer back to cases that happened many years before. As a result, where a case has established an important precedent that is still relevant to boards today, the book will refer to that case and not to more recent examples that demonstrate the precedent. The original judgments tend to contain more exposition of reasoning than cases where precedent is applied, even if those cases are more recent. Understanding how government sector organisations have evolved and the theory of how they may best be governed, requires a grounding in general governance, as well as an understanding of how the government sector is different from other sectors of the economy. Although most corporate governance and boardroom theory has been developed in regards to the commercial sector, the government sector is different. Government sector organisations often operate in very sensitive environments, and concern for stakeholders and the environment is an appropriate preoccupation for a board member. Board members are often recruited because they have strong ties to stakeholder groups or a passion for a local region, industry or environment that will provide insight for the board when developing a strategy that is sensitive to stakeholder concerns. As a board member, there is a difference between ensuring that the activities are undertaken, with correct regard to the potential side effects, and being there to thwart the aims of the organisation. Board members have an over-riding duty to the organisation they govern. Government organisations typically exist in areas of the economy or society where free-market mechanisms would fail. Often there is an inability to translate the value of the product or service into a price that can be borne by the consumers. xv xvi All Above Board At other times there is a monopoly that requires removal of the profit motive or redistribution of the dividend stream back into the general government sector budget to make the price of the products and services socially or politically acceptable. There are also cases where the government operates sound commercial businesses and derives from that activity a profit stream that funds other areas of government endeavour and boosts government resources. As a result of this complex array of organisation types, precedent and rationale for government ownership, a plethora of regulations are developed to keep pace with society, technology and economic developments. The changing regulatory environment is a stimulus that draws many directors to choose government-owned boards over public listed and private company boards. The satisfaction of influencing, or of precipitating regulatory change, can be a potent motivator for serving on government-owned boards. Effective directors need to understand the policy framework and how to influence it. They also need the confidence and skills to develop organisational strategy within the government context and within the constraints provided by the policy framework of the government of the day. There are some risks, however, that counterbalance the thrill of doing a necessary and fulfilling job in a stimulating and changing environment. Examples are the State Bank of South Australia and the National Safety Council where a nonexecutive, and unpaid, chairman was found personally liable for over $97 million when the company was found to have been trading whilst insolvent.1 It is important to note that while fulfilling your dream of helping build a better tomorrow, you are running some risks that could, if not properly managed, cost you your house, your life savings and your reputation. In cases of extreme misconduct courts may impose a banning order that can effectively end a director’s career. Some of these risks are the same as those facing the directors of listed and privately owned companies; others are far greater because of the nature of the sector in which the organisation operates, the complexity of the regulations or the higher expectations that the government, as shareholder, has of its directors. 1 Insolvent trading is defined as trading when debts or obligations are taken on that cannot be discharged as and when they fall due. Under these circumstances the directors may be held responsible for the debts and obligations incurred by the company. introduction In general, a government-owned company is governed in a similar way to one in the private or listed sector. In a few areas there are some very different practices. Probably the most notable difference are in: • strategic and operational planning • the recruitment and resignation of directors, and • the appointment of the auditor. In these areas the government-owned organisation lacks the ambiguity of the “corporations law company”, as the shareholder is identifiable, is approachable and is usually willing and able to take up its responsibilities and have meaningful input into the processes and their outcomes. As with any other directorship, governance in the government sector is about making decisions and managing the outcomes. The board and directors are responsible and have to decide on a case-by-case basis how to treat each item that comes their way. This book should provide a wider set of factors to consider in board and individual directors’ decision-making Ethics and values drive much of the observable behaviour in government sector boardrooms. An understanding of the ethical framework is imperative for success in governing in the sector, and many directors, even those with many years of experience on commercial boards, are unfamiliar with the public sector ethics acts and legislation, and how these can subtly alter boardroom processes. Most directors have a positive motive for the decision to stand for board membership, whether a general desire to serve the community or an affinity with the sector or objectives of the organisation. There is nothing wrong with having a personal stance on issues as long as it is managed in an appropriate fashion and in accordance with achieving the shareholder’s aspirations for the organisation. The government sector has complex stakeholder relationships and it is quite common for board members to have personal interests in the matter on which their boards must decide. Appropriate management of these potential (and often actual) conflicts is an important task for government sector directors. Serving on a government-sector board is a life-enriching experience and will have a positive effect on the lives of others in the community. xvii xviii All Above Board Chapter One Corporate Governance in Context This chapter gives a brief history of governance and discusses the reasons governments have boards that govern the organisations that they own. It provides an introduction to the government-owned organisation and its benefits to the Australian economy. What is governance? The Australian Securities Exchange (ASX)2 defines corporate governance as “the framework of rules, relationships, systems and processes within and by which authority is exercised and controlled in corporations”. Although this book is concerned with governance in the government sector, many organisations in the sector aspire to the highest and most recent standards, typically those of the listed sector where shareholder activism and regulatory pressure demand continuous improvement. It is not uncommon to find companies in the government sector 2 ASX Corporate Governance Council, Principles of Good Corporate Governance and Best Practice Recommendations, June 2007. Available at www.asx.ice4.interactiveinvestor.com.au. 1 2 All Above Board aspiring to and reporting against private-sector standards as well as their own guidelines. Governance is the way things get done, rather than the things that are done. Main Roads Western Australia defines governance in its 2010 annual report as: “how we direct and manage business activities to optimise performance, achieve regulatory compliance and deliver value”.3 Like many of its peers, Main Roads Western Australia uses modified ASX guidelines as well as guidelines specific to the public sector when designing and evaluating its governance processes and structures, explaining that: To further underpin the strength of our governance practices we have assessed our performance against the Guidelines established by the Western Australian Office of Public Sector Standards Commissioner. This checklist is based on the nine Corporate Governance principles developed by the Australian Stock Exchange and modified for the State public sector. In his 2002 Review of the Corporate Governance of Statutory Authorities and Office Holders, John Uhrig, AC, defined governance as: … the arrangements, by which the power of those who implement the strategy and direction of an organisation is both delegated and limited to ensure the organisation’s success, taking into account the environment in which the organisation is operating.4 In the Commonwealth sector the Uhrig definitions and principles are applied to a range of organisations using governance structures of both board and direct administrative control. The process involves ongoing review and refinement and updates are published so that stakeholders may view the progress.5 Brendan Butler, SC, defined governance very succinctly: “If management is about running a business, governance is about seeing it is run properly”.6 The concept of a “proper” adherence to an acceptable and independently 3 4 5 6 Available at www.mainroads.wa.gov.au. Review of the Corporate Governance of Statutory Authorities and Office Holders, John Uhrig, AC, June 2003. Available at www.finance.gov.au. Available at www.finance.gov.au. B. Butler, “Corporate Governance in the Public Sector”, Fourth Annual Public Sector Symposium, Brisbane, June 1999. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT established standard is pervasive in government sector governance. The elegance of Butler’s definition is that “run properly” is a concept that will evolve with circumstances and differing societal expectations. Generally, whenever people are discussing governance they are discussing how the organisation is controlled and the processes, systems and procedures that ensure control is effective and is exercised in an appropriate manner. Governance structures and definitions Before starting to examine how corporate governance is delivered in the government sector, it is worth establishing the basic concepts of board governance that apply across all structures. A corporation is governed by three groups of people: • shareholders, who own the corporation and provide the capital, • management and staff, who do the day-to-day work, and • directors, who are elected by the shareholders to govern the company on their behalf. These groups are not always rigidly separate. It is possible for a shareholder to be a director and also a staff member. Directors who are also managers or staff members are known as “executive directors”. They are more familiar with the business than directors who are not involved in running it. In small businesses with few shareholders it is possible for the shareholders to come together and take the big decisions about the business. As businesses get bigger and bigger, shareholders become more numerous and less connected with the business; it becomes more and more difficult for shareholders to get together often enough to make the decisions that are required. To prevent the management from operating unsupervised, shareholders will elect non-executive directors, who are not part of management, to independently review management’s performance and make the necessary decisions to guide sustainable development of the organisation. Agency theory suggests that management, if left unsupervised, will eventually tend to run the business to suit themselves rather than to meet the legitimate 3 4 All Above Board needs of shareholders. Symptoms of this include paying excessive salaries, granting themselves perks and perquisites that are unjustified, taking excessive or insufficient risks, etc. Shareholders elect representatives to oversee the actions of management to ensure that the interests of the shareholders are adequately safeguarded. Non-executive directors have no part in the day-to-day running of the organisation. However, they are expected to be familiar enough with the business to be able to spot any tendencies towards subverting the shareholders’ interests and prevent them from occurring. It is important that the non-executive directors have the skill and that they invest sufficient time and effort to do this. It is also important that they do not become too closely aligned with management so that they can be independent in their supervisory role. Sometimes independence is sacrificed to gain better familiarity or vice versa. Some non-executive directors who have not recently worked for the corporation, are not associated with any large suppliers or customers and have no significant emotional or pecuniary relationships with management are considered to be “independent” of management. In Australia every organisation has a constitution. This document sets out the company’s name, its aims (or objectives) and the rules for how it will operate. Companies may write their own constitution, adopt the standard constitution contained in the Corporations Act or use a combination of both. Shareholders can enforce the constitution the same way they would enforce a contract. It can be difficult and time consuming both for the shareholders to enforce and for management to implement changes to the constitution that shareholders require of them. Companies can amend (or update) their constitution by passing a special resolution of their shareholders. Ideas about what is a “good” constitution change, and it is a good policy for companies to keep their constitutions up to date and aligned to current ideas of good practice. What constitutes good governance? Just as there is no agreed standard definition of corporate governance, there is also no single “right” set of procedures, structures or measures that would ensure good CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT governance. Boards and shareholders work out what is most appropriate for their organisation at that particular time. Some general principles exist. These are often contained in mandatory codes of practice. However, over time, codes evolve or are redesigned to suit the current circumstances. In the government sector there are many codes, guidelines and statements of principle that may be applied to the governance of organisations. Some are legislated; others are options that organisations may choose to adopt. Different jurisdictions have decided to highlight different principles in their governance codes, a reflection of their different cultures, histories, social structures and aspirations. Although the codes are different they are not inconsistent with each other. Some of the better-known governance codes are discussed in Appendix 2. EXAMPLE 1: QUEENSLAND CORPORATE GOVERNANCE GUIDELINES FOR GOVERNMENT-OWNED CORPORATIONS The Treasury of the State of Queensland has drafted a set of corporate governance guidelines for State-owned companies. These guidelines set out the expectations of shareholding ministers in relation to the corporate governance of all Queensland government-owned corporations established under the Government Owned Corporations Act 1993 (GOC Act). They are intended to provide a framework for government-owned corporations to develop, implement, review and report on their corporate governance arrangements. The guidelines have been drafted with regard to: –ASX Corporate Governance Council Principles of Good Corporate Governance and Best Practice Recommendations (ASX principles) –Auditor-General’s Report No.2 2002-2003 – Review of Corporate Governance and Risk Management at Government-Owned Corporations –Auditor-General’s Report No.10 2002-2003 – Review of Management’s Assessment of Fraud Control Risks and Associated Plans and Procedures –OECD Principles of Corporate Governance. Opportunity for reflection What guidelines apply in the jurisdiction of your organisation that would influence your corporate governance practices? What processes does your organisation use to ensure that any changes are brought to the attention of the board and acted on in a timely manner? 5 6 All Above Board The value of good corporate governance Christopher Søren Shann Turnbull defined good governance as the ability of corporations to efficaciously achieve their purpose while minimising the involvement of the law or regulators in protecting and furthering the interests of corporate stakeholders and society in general.7 This definition is particularly relevant to the government sector, where the need for regulatory attention to be focused on a government-owned organisation is often accompanied by political sensitivity. Many experienced directors in the sector will use phrases such as “remain under the radar” or “keep your head below the parapet” in describing how their governance attempts to minimise the level and frequency of intervention required. Good governance is positively correlated with value creation. A McKinsey study found that investors were willing to pay a premium of up to 30 per cent for shares in companies with good corporate governance.8 While there is no share price premium for government-owned organisations to aspire to, the creation of value is still a key consideration for the board. Value for money is embodied in the Australian Public Service Values9 and in most of the State and Territory values or ethics legislation. Value for money may be embedded in intangibles, such as reputation, performance levels, community satisfaction or the ease of attracting good staff, or may be measured in financial terms. A brief history of governance Corporate governance became an issue when the modern corporation was invented. Modern corporations are characterised by a separation between owners and other capital providers on the one hand and business operators or managers on the other. There are records of Phoenician sailing and trading businesses dating back 4000 years and records of mining businesses in India that date back more than 7000 years. Somehow these businesses needed to develop systems and processes that 7 8 9 C S S Turnbull, “What’s Wrong With Corporate Governance Best Practices?”, in Corporate Governance, A synthesis of theory, research and practice, edited by H Kent Baker and Ronald Anderson, 2010, John Wiley and Sons, Hoboken. Roberto Newell and Gregory Wilson, “A Premium for Good Governance”, The McKinsey Quarterly, No.3, 2002. The APS Values are discussed in Chapter 8 Ethics and its Place in Business Life. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT would engender trust, so that the needed capital could be provided and the returns shared with the providers of capital. In short, they needed corporate governance. These early enterprises did not have the concept of limited liability, and if the business failed the owners were held personally responsible for all debts incurred. In some instances they could be held to more than just financial responsibility and penalties. The code of laws of Hammurabi established that: If a builder build a house for someone and does not construct it properly, and the house which he built fall in and kill its owner, then that builder shall be put to death. If it kill the son of the owner, the son of that builder shall be put to death.10 Under those circumstances, owners and providers of capital in early enterprises were closely involved in monitoring how the business was conducted. This was the only way they could manage the high personal risks attached to being in business. As a result, those businesses were generally small. Owners of capital would only invest in businesses that they personally understood and could devote their time and attention to managing. This need for close involvement and personal knowledge limited the available supply of capital to businesses and inhibited their rate of growth. Modern corporations have adopted the principle of separate identity, whereby the business is considered to be a being separate and distinct from its owners. The first documented systems of modern corporate governance sprang from medieval Europe when businesses, mainly trading corporations, local service providers and monasteries, were granted licences, or royal charters, to undertake activities. These licences recognised the business as a legal entity in its own right, in some instances, and limited the liability of the owners and/or operators for the potential losses of the corporation. Businesses became “synthetic persons” or “incorporated” as entities apart from their managers or their capital investors. Thus the inhibition on growth was removed (or loosened) and those businesses could develop at a faster rate and to a greater ultimate size than businesses where the liability was absolute. At about that time in Britain, some local government boroughs were among the first businesses to be awarded this status so that they could apply pooled community resources for the common good. The elected (or hereditary) 10 Hammurabi’s Code of Laws, estimated first published circa 1780 BCE, translated by L W King. 7 8 All Above Board community representatives became the equivalent of modern local councils and governments. The competitive economy was not, at that time, believed to be an efficient model and many of the early organisations were granted monopoly status to guarantee that they would be efficient generators of wealth for their owners. Those monopolies were often granted with a limit on the activities that could be undertaken. The concept of the articles of association and of acting ultra vires by exceeding these limits had been invented. At about the same time other corporate forms were being tried; mostly partnerships and sole traders, which still exist today, and unlimited liability companies often operating under trust or guarantee. In many of these corporate forms the liability of the owners was absolute, so they were not as popular as the limited liability companies. Standard forms of enterprise emerged and had the benefit of allowing investors to learn the basic corporate structure and powers once and then apply that knowledge to several businesses in which they might invest, rather than having to become familiar with the intricacies of myriad forms of enterprise. Enterprises that conformed to a standard type were preferred as investment vehicles over those that were specific (or special-purpose vehicles). Eventually, the exercise of these preferences created disparate growth rates, and pressure from investors and the business community led to the development of ever increasing numbers of limited liability companies. International trading organisations in the 18th century took full advantage of their monopolies and developed into enormous international businesses that generated significant shareholder wealth and national prestige. This development accelerated as the industrial revolution brought the need for ever greater sums to be invested in new and, frequently, capital-intensive industries. As businesses grew more complex, control became more and more difficult and codes, standards and laws were developed to regulate the activities of the companies and the claims they could make when raising money from shareholders. The numbers of shareholders in certain companies also grew, so that it became cumbersome for management to report to each shareholder individually. Standardformat reports, reporting time frames, report content and a secondary share market developed. Shareholders elected boards to represent their interests and to provide CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT a trusted intermediary between themselves and the professional managers of the business. There were cases of fraud where funds were raised for business ventures that did not exist, or where businesses were allowed to spend sums on items that benefited the management rather than generating a return for the owners of the business. In addition, some businesses, such as railways and other infrastructure companies and large associations of commodity producers, extracted high returns from their monopoly status and this led, in some instances, to cases of price collusion and anticompetitive behaviour. Legislation was drafted to counteract those two trends. Perhaps the most far-reaching of these was in 1890, when the Sherman Antitrust Act in the US declared that it was illegal to restrain trade or to attain or to preserve monopoly power through anticompetitive acts. A raft of legislation in many countries limited the powers of boards and management and set out basic requirements for provision of information to shareholders and for using funds for the purposes for which they had been obtained. This was the beginning of the corporate governance movement. The development of corporate governance in the government-owned sector According to current economic theory, there is no rationale for governments to own businesses unless they provide “public goods” or are regulatory bodies that serve to prevent abuse of power by other organisations. A public good could be defined as something that, once available, cannot be withheld from any who need it, regardless of their ability to pay. This inability to withhold is as often based on technical considerations as it is on any basic moral or ethical right.11 Clean air, water supply and sewerage, street lighting and national defence are common examples of public goods in the developed world. Another definition of public good is provided by the concept of “non-rivalry”. Under this definition, any good that is available equally to all, regardless of use by some, is a public good. For example, if I enjoy the use of the street lights when 11 A full discussion of ethics is contained in Chapter 8 Ethics in its Place in Business Life. 9 10 All Above Board driving at night on my suburban road, it does not make the lights any less bright or any less available for my neighbours. The lack of access to telecommunications infrastructure for some regional areas is an example of a service that has become considered as a public good but that is not equally available to all and from which it is very simple to exclude users that are not economically viable for the company. For example, businesses may wish not to extend mobile phone coverage or reticulated gas networks to remote areas with few inhabitants. EXAMPLE 2: The State Bank of New South Wales When the State government of New South Wales proposed to privatise the State Bank, Stan Neilly, member of parliament for Cessnock, had the following comments: I oppose the bill, but not for any of the reasons enunciated by opposition members. To me, philosophically, the sale of the State Bank goes against the grain. The government has a fiscal responsibility to the electorate as well as a social responsibility. I believe that a well-managed State Bank would avert many of the difficulties with which some people in our community become confronted. I recall an occasion in the mid-1980s, when the State Bank of New South Wales tried to influence home lending rates. It did so only for limited time, but at least it took the lead. I recall also when the State Bank was a friend to the farmer—the man on the land. During the past two years, the State Bank has been primed the sale [sic] and, in conjunction with that priming, there has been a review of the loan portfolio. Some hard decisions have been made, and those decisions have had sorry ramifications the [sic] property owners. Opportunity for reflection Is there a role for State governments to own banks, or are banking services best provided by the private sector? If the government is going to own banks, should these banks play a social, or a purely commercial role in society? Traditional market mechanisms are not always effective or efficient in providing public goods to an acceptable service standard. Frequently, “natural monopolies”, systems that would be too costly for a rival to build, are used to provide the service. A good example of this is the electricity supply network. Rival electricity vendors would not want to supply a second wire connection to every customer: it would be a waste of resources and would be unprofitable. Also, in many cases, the good or service is not sold at a price that would enable a privately owned company to make a commercial return on its investment, especially given the risks associated with the supply of the service to certain customers. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT Modern technology enables the provision of services via infrastructure to be separated from the ownership and maintenance of that infrastructure. This has resulted in the creation of separate businesses that can compete in a normal commercial manner, using infrastructure provided by a “natural” monopoly supplier. As this phenomenon has developed, industry boundaries have changed and governments have retreated from businesses that used to be seen as key areas for government activity but are now seen as commercial markets. The process is referred to as “privatisation” because businesses are removed from government, or public, ownership and placed into the ownership of privately owned commercial businesses.12 The population holds government responsible for providing an acceptable level of service at an acceptable price to a majority of the electorate. Failure to do so would result, usually, in the government being voted out of office in favour of a new government that promised a service more closely aligned with the needs of the population. What is defined as acceptable levels of service and the acceptable price can change over time, and governments need to pay strict attention to this process. As the demand for services changes, so do perceptions of how large a role the government should play in their provision. As the level of service and the number of services demanded by society have increased, so has the complexity and variety of methods used to provide them. Government involvement in industry and the economy has varied, depending on myriad circumstances, including commercial markets, external impacts such as war and changing political climates. Its involvement has included developing regulatory bodies or authorities that establish terms and conditions for trade and, supported by the union movements, employment in many industries. Today many governments around the world use corporations to provide goods and services for their populations. Many of these are governed by boards. In freemarket economies the focus of governance thinking is currently on board 12 The reverse of this process, “nationalisation”, occurs when the government decides an industry (or a service in an industry) is too important to the nation to be allowed to stay in private-sector ownership. The government then enters the market to take the activity into government ownership. This happened with many services, such as health care, rail and electricity supply, in the years after World War II. Some of those industries are still in government ownership, while others have been privatised and are once again in the private sector. 11 12 All Above Board independence and diversity. The government sector is following this debate and increasingly composing boards of independent and diverse directors. The desired level of government intervention in markets and ownership of businesses differs around the world. In some countries, such as France, government is required to play a comparatively large role; in others, such as the US, government plays a comparatively small role. The role of government in industry will change according to the prevailing social, economic and political environment. This is a natural process but can be very unsettling for directors of businesses in the sector as governments change their ideas about what activities they will, or will not, undertake. As the extent of government involvement changes so, too, does the structure of the organisations under government ownership. Government, unlike commercial shareholders, is a single entity and does not need elected board members to manage the flow of information between the government body and the organisations that it owns. Straightforward executive control is possible. Also, government can employ specialist managers to manage each business and professional accountants to check up on the management and ensure that all is being done effectively and efficiently. In spite of these two factors, governments all around the world continue to place boards between themselves and many of their organisations. They have good reasons for doing this: 1.Corporate structures are too complex and the number of organisations is too high for politicians to manage by direct personal involvement. 2.There is a need for services to continue to be provided immediately before, during and immediately after elections: an independent board with sufficient tenure can ensure that business continues to deliver while the political landscape is changing. Executives who report directly to the politicians on a daily basis are often considered less likely to continue to operate independently, regardless of the political agendas, and in many countries it is common for a change in the governing political party to involve a large change in the leadership of government-owned businesses. 3.Boards typically include experienced people from the private sector who may bring the latest ideas and efficiencies into the government businesses. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT 4.Legislation has evolved to enable risk to be transferred to the board, rather than to remain with the elected government. Although the extent of government involvement in commercial areas has changed over the years and will continue to change in the future, these reasons remain relatively constant and explain much of the government sector board governance that we currently take for granted. The current governance status quo Australia has a wide range of government-owned businesses comprising every type of organisation, from large government departments to small quasi-independent entities. Within the Commonwealth sector13 as at 1 October 200914 there were 932 separately identified government bodies. This does not include bodies associated with and/or belonging to state and local governments. The following criteria determine whether an organisation should be classified as “government sector”: • whether the organisation is established or given statutory recognition in a Commonwealth act, regulation or other legislative instrument • if a minister, secretary (of a department of state) or agency chief executive is involved in governing the organisation, either as a member (such as a shareholder) or a director, or has the capacity to direct the organisation • if the board or executive are appointed by a minister, secretary (of a department of state) or agency chief executive • if a minister, secretary (of a department of state) or agency chief executive has some influence or authority over board appointments or a right to make a proportion of board appointments, 13 See Chapter 2 Government Operations for an explanation of Commonwealth, State and Local governments. 14 The date of the most recent list of Australian government bodies available at the time of publication. More up-to-date lists will be published from time to time and details can be accessed at www.finance.gov.au The list of 932 public sector organisations includes bodies where the government is involved in their governance, but does not include bodies where the government’s involvement is for investment purposes: that is, to achieve a profit, is purely in the form of providing finance through loans or grants, or through other contractual arrangements that do not impose a governance responsibility on the government. 13 14 All Above Board • if the Commonwealth or one of its bodies acts as a trustee • if the Commonwealth or one of its bodies has a proportion (or all) of the shares • if the Commonwealth, through any minister, secretary, agency chief executive or their delegate, agency or authority or statutory body or Commonwealth company is a member of a company (whether as a shareholder or guarantor), partnership, association, joint venture or trust. Directors need to understand the governance arrangements applying to their organisation and also understand how their organisation is expected to coexist with other government- and non-government sector organisations. Before accepting an appointment to a government-owned board it is important to check the exact nature of the appointment and the status of the organisation. The differences between one organisation and another can be indicative of differences in the legal environment that create risks which, if not understood and managed, can be career or organisation threatening. For most government sector boards, directors are appointed by the shareholder and serve for a predefined term of office. Unlike public-listed companies, where the directors elect a chairman15 from among their number, the government, as shareholder, usually directly appoints the chairman. The chair is also appointed for a predefined term of office. Independence and skill are particularly valued in directors, as they allow the board to provide the organisation with a wider variety of qualifications, experience and knowledge than it would be possible to find in a single executive manager. This aids decision making and effective oversight of large and complex organisations. The size of the board is designed to ensure access to an appropriate range of skills and experiences without overstretching the budget of some of the smaller organisations. Boards range in size from 3 to 21 members with most boards having between five and seven members. 15 The term chairman has meaning associated with service, serving and presiding. It is not indicative of the gender of the person in the role. CORPORATE GOVERNANCE IN CONTEXT There is a trade-off between giving boards time to develop a team to work effectively together and preventing the team from falling prey to “group think”. Governments select a length of tenure carefully so that an effective team can achieve a reasonable amount of progress, but so an ineffective team does not have time to damage the entire organisation. Within the sector, board members’ terms of office range from very brief appointments to oversee specific projects or activities to seven-year terms. Most directors are appointed to serve between three and five years and the current practice16 is that appointments are renewed only once, or twice if the director is promoted to chairman. More information on appointments and board operations is contained in the Section on Board Composition and Recruitment. The difference between boards and committees There are important differences between boards and committees: • A board acts as a team; the key aim is to maximise performance. A good board will be willing to upset certain stakeholders if the long-term value created by a course of action is greater than that of other potential courses. A board has a statutory duty to further only the interests of the shareholders as a whole and no such duty to further the interests of any other stakeholder. Where a board member has been nominated by a shareholder or stakeholder, that board member still owes his or her duty to the shareholders as a whole and never to their nominator(s). When the interests of a shareholder conflict with those of other shareholders, the directors must do their best to impartially assess the best course of action for the company as a whole and not for any one group. • A committee is a decision-making body that looks and, to some extent acts, like a board but it is made up of representatives. The key aim of a committee is to ensure that no outcomes will be unacceptable for any one of the stakeholder groups represented. This is very different from the aim of a board, which is to maximise performance. A committee is more 16 The preference is observable as a pattern emerging from the drafting of terms of reference and tenure for many boards over recent years. It is rarely expressed as a preference with proponents often preferring to call it “best practice” rather than just the prevailing notion of good practice. 15 16 All Above Board focused on minimising the chance of an unacceptable outcome. For the public sector the use of committees made up of representative members is crucial for good governance in difficult areas where free markets would not provide good governance outcomes. Another important difference is that board members carry a personal liability for the actions of the organisation that the board governs. This liability extends beyond the decisions made by the board members in board meetings to myriad events including, but not limited to, workplace health and safety, trade practices, solvency, bullying and harassment. Committee members are usually held to account by their nominators but rarely have responsibility for actions outside their sphere of direct control. It is, perhaps, this liability that underlies the general practices of remunerating committee members using sitting fees and remunerating board members using an annual fee similar to a salary.