Another trick that may help prevent entry: Raising the costs of all firms in the industry (pp.488-491) You are a monopolist, earning $10 (million) in profit. If another firm enters, then each of you would earn $3. You can convince the government to require pollutioncontrol devices that would raise everyone’s costs by $4. Let’s represent this as a sequential game, with the government moving first: Firm 1 Lobby for devices Not Firm 2 Enter -1, -1 Firm 2 Do Not Enter 6, 0 Enter 3, 3 Do Not Enter 10, 0 Limit pricing You are the monopolistic incumbent: What quantity is best to produce? - Find MR = MC - Determine quantity, price, and profit MC PINC ATC Demand Q QINC MR Limit pricing You are the incumbent: … then this is the additional quantity that can be sold at any given price. It is called “residual demand” MC ATC P Q If this is the quantity produced by the incumbent… Limit pricing You are the incumbent: Suppose there is a firm with the same cost structure as ours. Can that firm enter “our” market profitably? MC Yes it can! P > ATC ATC Demand Q This is a problem: if another company enters, our profit would decrease substantially. Furthermore, if (in the worst case scenario) the new firm starts a price war, our profit may go all the way down to zero. How can we prevent this from happening? The competitor will not enter if entry is unprofitable! Instead of producing the profit-maximizing quantity, you need to “flood” the market by lowering the price and increasing the quantity produced so that the residual demand is pushed far enough to the left to make entry unprofitable. Limit pricing You are the incumbent: MC ATC P This is where you need the residual demand to be Q Q Therefore these are your safe P, Q, and profits Instead of deviating from the profit-maximizing quantity of output, can’t you simply make a threat to potential entrants that, in case they enter, you increase your output, lower your price and thus make the entrant lose money? Limit pricing as illustrated above Incumbent Profit-max price Lower price (limit pricing) Entrant Entrant enter no 3, 3 20, 0 enter - 1, -1 no 6, 0 First entry is for the player moving first (the incumbent) Lowering price in response to entry Entrant enter no Incumbent Incumbent High P Low P High P 3, 3 - 1, - 1 0, 20 First entry is for the player moving first (the entrant) Low P 0, 6 How can a firm deter entry? – A summary •Pay for exclusive rights; •Make new entry unprofitable: •strategic lobbying for new laws; •limit pricing; •reduce the degree of substitutability between the two products: •advertising; •reputation; •filling all niches; •“burn bridges” (make an irreversible credible commitment): •build a large plant; •invest in a technology. Non-credible threats do not work!!! Infinitely repeated games The concept of present value (see pp.14-18): Profit today is more valuable than profit one year from today. The present value of the future profit is Profit PV = ---------- , (1+i) where i is the discounting factor, usually set equal to the interest rate. A firm that is believed to exist and earn profits infinitely into the future has the present value of PV = π 0 + π1 (1 + i ) + π2 (1 + i ) 2 + π3 (1 + i ) 3 + ⋅⋅⋅ (Such an expression is called an infinite series.) A couple of useful facts about infinite series: If the profits, π, are the same in each period and we start counting with the present period, then π π π π (1 + i )π + + + ⋅⋅⋅ = =π + PV = π + 2 3 (1 + i ) (1 + i ) (1 + i ) i i If the first period in the series is “a year from now”, then PV = π (1 + i ) + π (1 + i ) 2 + π (1 + i ) 3 + ⋅⋅⋅ = π i Airline pricing game, revisited Firm 2 Low price High price Low price 3, 3 8, 1 High price 1, 8 6, 6 Firm 1 What if this game is played repeatedly? Firms use “trigger strategies” – strategies contingent on the past play of a game (a certain action “triggers” a certain response). Suppose both firms are currently keeping their prices high. An example of a trigger strategy: “I will continue to play “HIGH” as long as you are playing “HIGH”. Once you cheat by playing “LOW”, I will play “LOW” in every period thereafter.” If firm 1 continues to cooperate, its present value is PVcoop = π + π (1 + i ) + π (1 + i ) 2 + π (1 + i ) 3 + ⋅⋅⋅ Firms use “trigger strategies” – strategies contingent on the past play of a game (a certain action “triggers” a certain response). Suppose both firms are currently keeping their prices high. An example of a trigger strategy: “I will continue to play “HIGH” as long as you are playing “HIGH”. Once you cheat by playing “LOW”, I will play “LOW” in every period thereafter.” If firm 1 continues to cooperate, its present value is PVcoop = 6 + 6 6 6 6 6 + + + ⋅ ⋅ ⋅ = + (1 + i ) (1 + i ) 2 (1 + i ) 3 i If firm 1 cheats, its present value is PVcheat 3 3 3 3 = 8+ + + + ⋅⋅⋅ = 8 + 2 3 (1 + i ) (1 + i ) (1 + i ) i Firm 1 will prefer to cooperate if PVcoop > PVcheat or 6 3 6+ > 8+ i i or 6i+6>8i+3 3>2i i < 66.7% If the rate of discounting is less than 66.7%, then both firms prefer to cooperate Another example of a trigger strategy: Quality choice by a firm. The good can be purchased repeatedly. Firm Low quality High quality Don’t buy 0; 0 0; - 10 - 10; 10 1; 1 Consumer Buy A trigger strategy by consumers that can support the mutually beneficial outcome: “I will buy your product as long as you produce high quality. Once you produce low quality, I will never buy your product again”