Offering Broadband services via the Telephone system in a Volatile Economic Environment Alberto Fernandes first name.last name@cl.cam.ac.uk University of Cambridge Abstract nomic result. This exploitation, though, occurs in a deflationary and volatile environment, with the cost of bandwidth in constant fall and competing technologies in development. Spectrum management in DSL protects lines of potential customers from spectrum pollution. A spectrum management decision is equivalent to estimating a price for the future revenue from these potential customers. Making explicit this pricing decision would allow mixing economic and technical knowledge into a single estimator. Keeping them separate may be leading to double conservatism where the engineers produce a conservative estimate and the economists start from there to add their own pessimism to arrive at an investment decision. We propose a model where varying economic parameters would be included in the estimator used to compute the data rate offered to each customer. This would allow to maximise expected revenue and implement a version of a financial “hedge”, where the risk is minimised by mixing optimistic and pessimistic assumptions. 1 1 The physical make up of the system determines how it can be exploited. Telephone lines serving different customers are collected together in binders, and can be modelled as an interference channel, ie, a Multiple Input Multiple Output (MIMO) system where users are not centrally coordinated. 2 . Although the number of lines in a binder is fixed, the number of active lines running a DSL service varies with time. As users gradually adopt DSL, is not known how many users will end up sharing a binder. Every time a new customer decides to buy a DSL service, the telco is faced with the problem of offering the highest bit rate possible while avoiding damage to older and to future systems. There is an inherent trade-off between present and future users data rates. The data rate made available to the new customer is limited by the necessity of protecting the other lines in the same binder from interference. Introduction Digital Subscriber Line (DSL) technologies owe their existence to an economic motivation: the exploitation of the existing telephony system as a medium for “broadband”, or high speed data connections. Telephone wires are far from ideal for the job, but this technical hurdle is compensated by its cost advantage, as the lines are already installed. This protection is called spectrum management. It can be done by setting fixed limitations on power and spectrum of new entrants, or by directly aiming for some feasible set of data rates to be distributed between users. The former method is the current practice today, and is detailed by standards agreed by the committee T1.E1.4 in the United States and by the European Telecommunications Standard Institute in Europe ([1], [2]) . The latter is the state of current research in the area and is actively being Thus, DSL is about exploring a finite, nonrenewable resource to the best possible eco1 The author thanks the helpful comments and support of Dr David Greaves, Dr Jon Crowcroft and Prof. John M. Cioffi. Thanks to Dr Ken Kerpez of Telcordia for providing measurements and New Visual Inc for funding this research. 2 As of today there are few or no exceptions to this, but there will probably be some centrally coordinated systems in the future. 1 discussed in T1.E1.4.([3],[7]) 2 Any spectrum management policy has very direct economic implications. Using the basic axiom that in general telephony companies (telcos) will be able to charge more for higher data rate, a spectrum management problem is one of trade-off between revenue from current customers and revenue from potential future customers. This can be expressed as a pricing exercise. The “co-existence” in DSL of current and potential future customers invalidates the paradigm used in most of MIMO literature, that the goal is to maximise the bit rate sum. Bit rate sum implies that data rate is worth the same, whatever line it is in. We argue that bit rate in current customers lines is better than bit rate for potential customers, for the following reasons: 1. Bit rate in a new customer line can certainly be exchanged by revenue. The expected revenue from future customers has to be weighted by the estimated probability that these customers will take up the service eventually. The price in question here is the expected revenue to be achieved from future customers. For example, suppose that telco X receives an order from a new DSL customer whose line has potential to support 2 Mbps 3 , but only offers 1 Mbps in order to cut on “spectrum pollution”. 2. The estimate in item(1) has to take into account the fierce competition in provision of broadband services by other means rather than the telephone line. In particular, cable has a bigger share of the market in many OECD countries [5]. This decision is equivalent of that of a wellinformed telco that computed the expected extra revenue from that binder if the “pollution” is kept low, and decided that the price that the current customer is willing to pay for data rate above 1Mbit/s is not enough to compensate for the potential loss of revenue. From the point of view of an external observer, the behaviour of telco X and the well-informed telco is indistinguishable; in this sense we view the decisions motivated by the spectrum management policies as equivalent to pricing decisions. 3. Future deflation of prices charged per data rate unit is generally expected. 4. Revenue comes in the form of a stream of monthly payments by the customer. Future customers will initiate their stream of payments later on. If everything else is equal, their streams of payments will last for a shorter period than the stream that is starting now. The analysis in this paper is focused on the case where a single operator controls the physical layer of a telephone binder. This applies for instance in VDSL scenarios in the US. VDSL is designed to support high data rates over short distances, as a “last-mile” solution, in conjunction with fibre. For those “hybrid” networks, that mix fibre and copper, a recent FCC ruling decided that the incumbent telephony companies are not forced to unbundle, i.e., to allow other companies to provide DSL using the incumbent’s telephone lines [6]. This decision allows telcos to adopt new strategies such as those explained here. 5. Interest rates or capital return rates mean that money received now is more valuable in actuarial terms (has a higher present value) than the same amount in the future. A second source of uncertainty comes from technical limitations. A practical assumption is that the MIMO system itself is not completely known, but is gradually “discovered” as new users take up the service. In the typical case, a telephone exchange or cabinet will serve several customers for instance, different homes. To measure the direct channel would involve a visit to each user’s home, including to those who haven’t express interest in DSL yet. Some technology for measuring a DSL channel from a single end has recently been presented [4], but is still challenging from a theoretical point of view, so it is not reasonable to expect it to be in widespread use soon with sufficient accuracy This paper is organised as follows. In section 2, we examine why careful pricing is necessary; in section 3, we show how it is possible to change practices by incorporating the most recent research results from DSL; and in section 4 we propose new practices and discuss benefits. 3 While Motivation not interfering with current customers 2 for this task. allow better terms of trade to be achieved. Dynamic Spectrum Management techniques (see for example [7], [3]) moved the spectrum management discussion from simply considering whether technologies are “compatible” into identifying the “rate-region”, i.e., the set of all feasible sets of data rates for the MIMO system users.To be efficient, any MIMO system would have to operate in the convex hull of the rate region. Both economic and technical sources of uncertainty must be taken into account for an unbiased estimate of the value of data rate for a future customer. There is nothing new about mixing different components such as these into price. Computing price estimates that incorporate all available knowledge about a certain asset, while recognising the implicit underlying uncertainty, is the basis on which financial markets operate, for instance. Even though it is not always possible to know the complete MIMO system, the downstream (i.e., from the telephone company to the user) Near End (NEXT)4 crosstalk functions may all be measured on the telephone companies’ side. These happens to be the most important crosstalk functions, as the downstream rates are often higher, as in ADSL or in applications like video on demand. In most cases, NEXT is far higher than FEXT. As mentioned before, spectrum management decisions being made today can be seen as implicit pricing decisions. Because they ignore most of the factors listed above that should have been in the model, there is a high risk that these are bad decisions. For instance, companies may be “paying” too much for the potential of data rate in future DSL customer lines if the rate of deflation is not being taken into account. This measurement is assumed in many new technologies and there are now less technical impediments for it to be performed. This would allow a much greater insight into which rates are achievable. Spectrum management techniques in current use a very pessimistic scenario, designed to be worse than 99% of practical crosstalk functions. The amount of conservatism used is illustrated by figure 1. The economic uncertainty factors are likely not to be ignored by companies. The problem is that they are kept in a separate forum. This may lead to duplication of the conservatism, where different people in the same company build their own margins of safety. For instance, data rate capacities may be conservatively estimated by the engineers and passed on to the economists, who include their own conservatism to decide on investment policies. 4 The result is underinvestment in DSL, and eventually the industry missing some of the window of opportunity represented by the existing telephone infrastructure. The evidence is that, despite their initial advantage, telephone companies lost the first move advantage in providing broadband Internet services in practically all of the richest countries ([5] ). 3 Recommendations The main conclusion is that new engineering models are needed that take take economic parameters into account. The practice today, when a new customer requests DSL, is to make a decision on the data rate offered based on loop measurements. We propose a new practice where loop measurements and economic parameters serve as input on which individual data rate decisions should be based. Thus these new models would provide a function that takes this data and returns a recommended data rate for each individual case. Potential for Implementation Such a function would provide the means for a company to react to changes in the economic A price estimator depends on knowledge about the terms of trade, i.e., how much extra data rate is gained in one line when a unit of data rate is lost in another. 4 Near End crosstalk means a transmitter on the telephone company exchange interfering with a receiver in the same exchange; Far End crosstalk (FEXT) would be a transmitter in a customer’s home interfering with a receiver on the telco exchange. Fortunately, recent advances in DSL technology much increased our knowledge about this and 3 In short, the data rate offered in some lines would be based a pessimistic view of the future, following a greedy strategy, taking close to the maximum revenue possible from the current customer. In some lines, the data rate offered would reflect an optimistic view of the future, following a parsimonious strategy, keeping spectrum pollution to a minimum in order to achieve future profits from the other lines in the binder. Therefore, whatever scenario materialises would not drive the actual revenue too far from the initial expectation. Attenuation (dB) x Frequency (MHz) −40 −50 −60 −70 −80 −90 −100 −110 −120 −130 −140 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 Investors in telecommunications are notoriously more risk-averse following the crisis in the sector in 2000. Such a tool for reducing the implicit risk in their returns could be essential for bringing back more investment in DSL. Figure 1: The thick line is the conservative estimate of a crosstalk NEXT transfer function currently in use (Unger model). The other lines are real measurements by Telcordia, for pairs close together. References and technological environment by simply adjusting parameters. This capacity of rapid reaction is very important in a sector where changes are occurring fast. [1] Spectral management: Definitions and signal library tr 101 830-1. Technical report, ETSI. The model can be expressed as finding the rate [2] Spectral management t1.417-2001. Technifor the incremental new customer that maxcal report, T1.E1.4. imises total revenue : [3] R. Cendrillon, M.Moonen, W.Yu, , where is the revenue expected from J.Verlinden, and T. Bostoen. On the the new customer, from future customers optimality of iterative waterfilling. T1.E1.4 and and are vectors including all the other contribution 2003-325, December 2003. parameters mentioned. As a function of random variables, is itself a random variable and [4] Stefano Galli and David Waring. Loop the expectation of R is computed via computmakeup identification via single ended testing the integral over its probability distribution ing: Beyond mere loop qualification. IEEE function (pdf). Protection of older systems is Journal on Selected Areas in Communicaconsidered a hard constraint and thus not intions, June 2002. cluded in this trade-off. [5] Irene Wu Sherille Ismail. Broadband internet access in oecd countries: A comparative This pdf would incorporate data and beliefs analysis. Technical report, Federal Commuabout all the economic and technical paramenications Commision (USA), October 2003. ters, including whatever inferences are possible about the shape of the rate region based on the [6] Federal Communications Commission measurements available. Even a simple model (USA). Fcc adopts new rules for network here would be better than the current situation unbundling obligations of incumbent local where no explicit model is used. phone exchange carriers. Press Release, 2003. A second possible application of the model is to maximise revenue subject to keeping the vari- [7] W. Yu, W. Rhee, S. Boyd, and J. Cioffi. Iterance of revenue small; i.e., reduce the risk for ative water-filling for gaussian vector multhe company that the expected revenue won’t tiple access channels. In 2001 International be achieved. This maximisation would be done Symposium on Information Theory, Washover many rate decisions and would be similar ington, DC, June 2001. to the concept of “hedge” in finance. 4