Informality: Exit and Exclusion OECD Development Centre Paris July 2007 LAC not significantly more informal than comparable countries… Self Employment (% of Labor Force) 2/ Lack of Pensions (% Labor Force) 1/ 2 Measures of Informality vs Income per Capita 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 - 10,000 20,000 30,000 40,000 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 - 10,000 Advanced Countries 30,000 40,000 2005 GDP per capita PPP adjusted 2005 GDP per capita PPP adjusted Latin America 20,000 Rest of the world Latin America Advanced Countries Rest of the world …But, a disturbing trend in the nineties % Informal Labor Force (Productive Definition) % Informal Labor Force (Legalistic Definition) 11.9 Argentina 1992-2005 7.7 Venezuela 1995-2003 18.5 Venezuela 1989-2003 Uruguay 1992-2004 7.0 Honduras 1992-2002 6.8 5.4 Panama 1995-2003 Brazil (Met) 1992-2002 6.2 Nicaragua 1993-2001 5.9 Colombia 1996-2004 4.8 Peru 1997-2003 4.6 3.4 Jamaica 1996-2002 4.0 Mexico 1990-2004 * 1.1 Chile 1990-2003 -0.7 Ecuador 1994-1998 Brazil 1990-2003 -0.8 Paraguay 1997-2003 -0.9 -2.4 Colombia 1996-1999 3.1 Dominican Republic 1996-2004 Paraguay 1997-2003 2.6 Mexico 1996-2002 2.4 El Salvador 1991-2003 2.2 Argentina 1995-2005 1.9 Bolivia 1997-2002 1.5 Ecuador 1994-2003 1.1 Costa Rica 1992-2003 -0.4 Nicaragua 1993-2001 -0.9 -3.3 Brazil 1992-2003 El Salvador 1991-2003 -12.0 -5.2 Chile 1990-2003 -15.0 -10.0 -5.0 0.0 5.0 10.0 15.0 -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 Why do we care? Unprotected workers: issue of welfare, equity and efficiency Productivity: firms too small? Barriers to growth? Indicator of regulatory distortions Low and distorted tax collections and poor provision of public services Weak rule of law and Governance: A problem in our social contract? Exit and Exclusion Traditional exclusion view of informality Exit view: agents analyze costs vs. benefits of becoming formal Labor: inferior jobs in a segmented market Firms: denied access to services by high entry costs (de Soto) Labor: informality offers flexibility, avoidance of poorly designed benefits programs, and provides “decent” work Firms: don’t need/want State programs, don’t pay for them Larger firms and individuals: Why pay taxes if can avoid? Both exist to varying degrees across countries but have different implications for policy The Informal Worker Comparative Advantage and Constraints Two Distinct Types of Informal Worker Distribution of informal workers in Latin America % contributing to social security system Peru 2002 Bolivia 2005 Ecuador 1998 Nicaragua 2001 Colombia 2006 Guatemala 2002 Dom. Republic 2006 Mexico 2002 Informal independent Venezuela 2003 El Salvador 2003 Argentina 2005 Brazil 2003 Informal Salaried Uruguay 2004 80.0 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 10.0 0.0 Chile 2003 % employed workers % Not Contributing to Social Security System Two distinct types of informal workers. Role of Each Changes across Life-Cycle Informal Salaried Self employed Cunningham (2007) Formal Informal 67 63 59 55 51 47 43 prevalent among prime or older have capital and skills to open a business 39 35 Self Employment 31 27 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 23 port of entry for youth accumulate experience for Formal Salaried or independent work Most in micro firms 19 Brazil: Employment as share of age cohort 15 Most informal workers found in small firms 75% of Mexican and Argentine in firms of at most 5 workers However, expansion in large firms in Arg, Bra over 1990s % of Informal and Self Employed workers Mexico (Urban Areas) 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1994 2004 1 2-5 6-10 11-15 16-50 Firm Size 51-100 101-250 250 + % of Informal and Self Employed workers The allocation of Informal Workers across firm size Argentina (Gran Buenos Aires) 50 45 1980 40 2003 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1 2 to 5 6 to 25 26 to 100 Firm Size 101 to 500 501 + Workers tell us of both exit and exclusion Self-rated Poverty Relative to Formal Workers Most (~2/3) of independent workers are voluntary not queuing for formal jobs value flexibility, esp. women opting out of Social Protection odds ratio 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Independent Argentina Informal Salaried Dominican Republic Workers tell us of both exit and exclusion Self-rated Poverty Relative to Formal Workers Most Informal Salaried are involuntary would prefer to be FS or SE Brazil: 30% do not want to leave Exceptions Dominican Republic, Mexico youth: difficulty entering workforce odds ratio 1.6 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Independent Argentina Informal Salaried Dominican Republic And their transitions suggest both voluntary entry in Mexico .14 .12 .1 .04 .05 .06 Self-Employed to Formal Formal Salaried to Self Employment .16 .07 .18 Mexico .08 .03 Self Employment to Formal Salaried 1987q1 1991q1 1995q1 Formal to Self-Employment Bosch, Goñi, Maloney (2007) 1999q1 2003q1 Self-Employed to Formal Cyclical Patterns of Labor Informality .8 Mexico: Job Finding Rates: Transitions from U to Work What drives countercyclically? .6 IS .4 FS .2 0 SE 1987q1 1991q1 1995q1 q_unm_for q_unm_se 1999q1 q_unm_inf 2003q1 However, new insights from OECD literature on why Job Finding in FS: volatile and pro-cyclical Job finding in the I Sector Informal sectors constant. Net: I-sector absorbs labor in downturns What Was Behind Trends in 90’s? Boom in capital inflows and non tradable sectors in the early nineties Rise in female participation? (AR, perhaps, CO, BR no) Trade Reform: Ambiguous effects Some in BR, AR; MX Increased real minimum wages and/or more restrictive labor regulations (CO, BR, PE) Social security reform often lowered Benefit/ Cost ratio (except in CH) Temporary contracts and relaxed enforcement (AR) Cyclical Patterns Mexico 1.4 2.6 1.3 2.4 1.2 To Formal/Tradable To Informal/Nontradable 1.2 0.5 Unconditioned Earnings F/SE Real exchange rate 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1.0 1991 0.4 FS rigidities less binding in booms Boom in nontradables: REER appreciation due to boom in capital inflows: opening of Capital account, Exchange Rate Based Stabilization, improved expectations due to reforms Formal/SE Colombia 1.6 2.4 2.2 1.4 2.0 1.2 1.8 1.0 1.6 0.8 1.4 0.6 1.2 Countercyclical/Segmented Unconditioned Earnings F/SE Real exchange rate 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1.0 1985 0.4 Procyclical/Integrated Formal / SE 1.4 0.6 Increase in Informality in early 1990s 1.6 0.7 Formal/SE Formal / SE 0.8 1990 1.8 1989 0.9 1988 Show voluntary entry Depend on positive shocks 2.0 1.0 1987 2.2 1.1 Relative earnings Real exchange rate Informality mostly countercyclical But can be procyclical in some booms Relative earnings Real exchange rate What Was Behind Trends in 90’s? Boom in capital inflows and non tradable sectors in the early nineties Rise in female participation? (AR, perhaps, CO, BR no) Trade Reform: Ambiguous effects Some in BR, AR; MX Increased real minimum wages and/or more restrictive labor regulations (CO, BR, PE) Social security reform often lowered Benefit/ Cost ratio (except in CH) Temporary contracts and relaxed enforcement (AR) The symmetric pattern breaks down in Brazil after 1990 1 4 SE to FS 3 1.2 1.4 1.6 Self-Employment to Formal 1.8 5 Brazil FS to SE 2 .8 Trade & Constitutional Reform 1983m1 1988m1 1993m1 time... Formal to Self-Employment Bosch, Goñi, Maloney (2007) 1998m1 2003m1 Self-Employment to Formal Actual and predicted size of the formal sector in Brazil 90 85 80 75 70 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 65 Actual No trade No Constitution What Was Behind Trends in 90’s? Boom in capital inflows and non tradable sectors in the early nineties Rise in female participation? (AR, perhaps, CO, BR no) Trade Reform: Ambiguous effects Some in BR, AR; MX Increased real minimum wages and/or more restrictive labor regulations (CO, BR, PE) Social security reform often lowered Benefit/ Cost ratio (except in CH) Temporary contracts and relaxed enforcement (AR) The Informal Firm Microfirm Dynamics: Very similar in LAC and the US Example: as in the US, self-employment increases with age United States 60 50 50 Percent Percent Mexico 60 40 40 30 30 20 20 10 10 Age 0 18-20 21-25 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 0 18-20 21-25 26-30 31-35 36-40 41-45 46-50 51-55 56-60 61-65 Entry Rate Exit Rate Self-employment Rate Age Entry Rate Exit Rate Self-employment Rate Other similarities: Entry increases with: Education (firms with some employees) Conditional wages of salaried workers (overachievers) Firm exit and growth: Higher for smaller microfirms (as predicted by Jovanovic) Firm survival and growth increase with owner’s education, firm revenues Why do the Majority of Microfirms Formalize as they Grow? 0% 30% 60% 90% Formality by firm size (Brazil) 0 1 2 3 4 5 Number of Paid Employees Not Registered No workers registered Informal services & institutions may become insufficient: No tax payment Contract enforcement Formal Credit Sales to formal firms (e.g. if VA system) Access to Government programs …or just increased probability of detection Detection does seem to play an important role in driving firms to formalize (IFC surveys) Main advantage of Formality (%) Main motivation seems to be risk of being caught: Comply with the law “comply with the law” (47%) avoid bribes, fines (30%) 47 Avoid paying fines 20 Expand and Gain new clients 14 Avoid paying bribes Access to markets/services less important (<25%) 9 Improve access to credit 8 Improve contract enforcement 2 0 10 20 30 40 50 Source: IFC (Bolivia, Peru, Brazil, Honduras and Nicaragua) And Small Firms often say they do not formalize because “they don’t need to” The DR and Mexico over 60% and 80% resp. say “they’re too small” or “they don’t need to formalize” Why do microfirms not register? 38 Argentina 63 84 Mexico Probably low detection probability, lack of demand for formal services Argentina: somewhat different picture, for 63% main motivation are formality costs 14 63 Dominican Republic 27 0 20 40 60 80 No need to register/business is too small Formality costs 100 But note that informality is not just a small firm phenomenon Medium and Large Firms evade considerable Taxes and Social Security Firm level correlates of evasion: firm size (-) Productivity (-) corruption (+) rigidity of labor regulations (+) linkages to large companies (-) use of third party contract enforcement (-) Tax and Social Security Evasion (%) 20 and under 21 to 99 100 and more Chile 20 and under 21 to 99 100 and more Colombia 20 and under 21 to 99 100 and more Mexico 20 and under 21 to 99 100 and more Brazil 0 5 10 Tax 15 20 25 30 Social Security 35 40 45 Recent Evidence on Policies to reduce Red Tape and Taxes Mexico’s SARE program: Business registration in less than 3 days Positive Impact on formality but effect is of small magnitude Bruhn (2007): 5.6% increase in fraction of registered businesses but mostly increased entry salaried workers Kaplan et al. (2007): increase is of only 0.7% Brazil’s SIMPLES program: Tax burden reduction: 8% of revenues Monteiro & Assunção (2005): 46% increase in registration rate for retail firms…at least in 1st year after SIMPLES Evidence of improved firm performance as a result of formality Impact of informality on Firm Productivity? Lower economies of scale as firms remain small: “Unfair” competition by low productivity informal firms? To avoid detection Because of low access to markets and services Firm Productivity in High Evasion Areas Labor Productivity Total Factor Productivity -12 -10 -8 -6 Unregistered Workers -4 -2 0 Unreported Sales Slows Schumpeterian creative destruction Reduces market/investments of formal firms? Efficiency gains thanks to avoiding regulations? Example: evidence of higher firm productivity associated with lower enforcement of labor regulations (Almeida and Carneiro, 2006) Impact of informality on growth? Difficult to identify formality effects: Regulation, education, etc. affect both informality and growth, but... Impact of Informality on Growth Cross country regressions Controlling for: Informality - % of GDP Self Employment None Initial Education Informality itself has negative but insignificant effects on growth Regulation Financial Depth Investment Corruption Future research: how does the impact of informality on growth vary according to the specific factors that drive informality All -.1 -.05 Estimated Impact 0 .05 -.1 -.05 95% Confidence Interval 0 .05 Social Protection Protecting all LAC’s citizens against risk Andrew D. Mason Senior Economist Informality and Social Protection – Why do we care? Lack of access to social protection has welfare, equity and efficiency implications While individuals/families employ private risk management strategies – informally (prevention, self-insurance) and somewhat through the market (market insurance) … … Lack of access to formal social protection raises important concerns on several fronts From the perspective of household welfare From the societal perspective Inefficient coping, impoverishing shocks (particular concerns in health and old age security) Too much uninsured risk can have external costs, productivity effects On the social protection system Small, inefficient risk pools, foregone savings Social Security Coverage is Low and Stagnant – or Declining – in Many Countries Coverage Rates for the Economically Active Population (% of economically active) 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 BO PY PE NI GU CO EC MX 1990s Source: Rofman and Luccetti (2006) SA 2000s VE AR BR UY CL CR LAC’s “Truncated Welfare State” – The Poor Have Largely Lacked Access Pension Coverage by Income Quintile (% of economically active) Percentage 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Peru Poorest Quintile Colombia Second Quintile Mexico Argentina Middle Quintile Brazil Fourth Quintile Chile Wealthiest Quintile Persistent “Truncation” Helped Spawn the Rise of Social Assistance Programs Over the last decade, LAC countries have launched a variety of programs to better reach the poor, e.g.: CCTs Social assistance pensions Subsidized health insurance Subsidized housing etc. Absolute Incidence of CCTs in Brazil and LAC Absolute Incidence - CCTs in Brazil and LAC (QUINTILES) % of total benefits received by each QUINTILE BR-Bolsa Familia PNAD 2004 CL-SUF/Solidario 2003 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% MX-Oportunidades 2002 AR-Jefes 2003 Q1 Q2 Q3 Q4 Poorest to richest (QUINTILES) Q5 Government Failures are Pervasive and Create Incentives for Informality Government failures exist on at least two levels … Weak design of Social Security programs High costs via payroll contributions; rigid one-size-fits-all approach (young vs. old; paying twice for health insurance) Excessive “bundling” of benefits (health, pensions, disability, … but also housing, childcare, sports & recreation) taxes contributors Weak accounting for labor mobility (too-high vesting periods for pensions, intermittent coverage in health) Low quality of services/benefits Lack of Incentive Compatibility within the “System” Noncontributory assistance for informal workers increasingly “compete” with Social Security reinforcing incentives for informality The Design of Social Security is Inconsistent with Movement In-and-Out of the Formal Sector In Mexico Low wage (affiliated) workers spend less than half their time in the IMSS system, on average Would take over 50 years of qualify for a minimum pension In Uruguay Less than 30 percent of workers are estimated to attain vesting requirements by age 65 Workers’ Years Insured by IMSS, Mexico, 1997-2005 Share of Workers (in percent) 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Years Workers with < 3 MW Workers with > 3 MW 8 9 Re-engineering Social Protection to Protect all Citizens Recommendations grounded in the economics of insurance (Comprehensive Insurance Framework) and in public economics (the appropriate role for public intervention) In the long-term, ensure Universal “essential cover” in health, de-linked from the labor contract, and financed by general taxation By facilitating widest possible risk pool, also enhances efficiency of the insurance model Brazil-Fernandes, Gremaud and Narita (2006): replacing labor tax on first minimum wage with neutrality reduces informality (1.5%) if capital investments are exempt Poverty prevention pensions, targeted to the poor, and incentive compatible with multi-pillar systems Both pooling and savings components are important (complementary) Targeted social assistance pensions for “large gap” countries; incentive compatible, integrated systems (a la Chile) for “smaller gap countries” The Role of Institutions and Social Norms Towards an Inclusive Social Contract Informality Partially Reflects How Citizens Relate to the State Self Employment and Quality of Institutions (correlations controlling for GDP) Government Effectiveness .2 BOL COL PER HON GUA JAM .1 CHI -1 -.5 0 .5 Goverment Effectiveness coef = -.07366668, se = .01583045, t = -4.65 CHI COS PAN SAL -.2 -.2 -1.5 ARG COL PER BOL HON GUA JAM ECU BRA MEX -.1 BRA COS MEX PAN SAL -.1 0 ECU ARG VEN 0 VEN Share of Self-employed .1 .2 Rule of Law Index 1 -1 -.5 0 .5 1 Rule of Law Index coef = -.07296094, se = .01690364, t = -4.32 Poor, untrustworthy institutions increase the costs, decrease benefits of formality High informality limits the action of the state Another vicious circle? Institutional Performance also Shapes Citizens’ Perceptions about Effectiveness and Fairness of the State Share of firms which are confident that the judiciary will enforce contractual and property rights (controlling for GDP) .2 0.9 Correlation of informality and the Perception of impartiality of courts 0.8 0.4 0.3 0.2 PER BOL HON GUA 0 ECU ARG COL BRA MEX PAN SAL JAM CHI COS -.1 0.5 VEN 0.1 0 Middle East & North Africa OECD East Asia & Pacific Sub-Saharan Africa Europe & Central Latin America & Asia Caribbean South Asia -.2 Percentage 0.6 .1 Share of Self-employed 0.7 -4 -2 0 Impartiality of Courts Coef.=-0.0262, coef = -.02625821, t=-4.3 se = .00611322, t = -4.3 2 4 Lead to exit and a “culture of informality” Symptom of a dysfunctional” social contract? PAR .1 BRA NIC HON ARG COL 0 Ex: tax morale is negatively correlated to perceptions of State capture SAL GUA CHI MEX URU -.1 COS VEN PAN ECU BOL PER -.2 Collective perceptions of fairness/efficacy of state Strong reciprocity: I’ll comply if others comply Tax Morale .2 “Social Norms” of Compliance: Perceptions of State, of Each Other -.2 -.1 0 Run By a Few Interest coef = -.80478831, se = .24120409, t = -3.34 .1 .2 Is Inequality Related to a High Informality / Weak Institutions Equilibrium? Informality vs. Inequality 20 40 ECU NIC VEN 0 URU PER PAR ARG BOL MEX GUA DOM HON SAL BRA COL CHI -20 JAM COS High inequality correlated with: PAN -60 -40 -20 -10 0 Gini Coefficient coef = .71532765, se = .20185487, t = 3.54 10 20 Unequal access and exclusion Differences in power, voice and influence State capture by the rich and organized middle classes and low state legitimacy But, Chile: strong institutions, low informality Policies to Reduce Informality Reduce opportunity cost of informality: raise productivity in the formal sector Remove segmenting distortions in labor markets where applicable Tilt the benefit/cost ratio of firms and workers to opt for formality: improved Investment Climate higher human capital accumulation removing distortionary incentives in Social Protection Systems, reducing cost of doing business for all firms improving services associated with formality especially for SME’s, Improve quality and fairness of institutions and policies and even handed enforcement: move social norms towards a culture of compliance. A potential virtuous circle