Ragnar Arnason Comments on Environmentally harmful subsidies: - Developing a checklist OECD Workshop on Environmentally harmful subsidies 7-8 November 2002 Basic considerations 1. There is a good (but not an unqualified) economic case for removing (or reducing) subsidies 2. There is an even better economic case for removing economically harmful subsidies (…if by “harmful” we mean deviation from the “optimal harm”) …..but 1. Not all subsidies are equally harmful 2. There are lot of counterexamples (i.e. where subsidy is economically beneficial and its removal a mistake) $ MC0 MC1 p1 p0 q0 q1 q* quantity Therefore we need more information • Basically, an empirical economic/environmental general equilibrium model • But, this is not available (…and not in sight) • And environmental concerns are pressing • Therefore we need some guidelines – a checklist perhaps. • But with almost no theory and little data this is very difficult! An illustration Following Jan Pieters, assume: • Government wants to reduce environmentally harmful subsidies by a given amount • Which subsidies should it reduce and by how much? Two environmental goods: y and x Social indifference curves y Budget constraint y* x* x But this is too simplistic • Environmental goods cannot really be generated (or bought) at a constant rate. • Subsidy reduction (may) produce environmental goods • That production is the output of the economic and environmental GE-system • If that production is well behaved (..not particularly likely), it will look like: Production of environmental goods y Production possibility frontier x A possible case y y* x* x Another possible case y y* x* x Yet another possible case y y* x* x Back to the checklist • A checklist is supposed to reflect this – Not the optimal solution – But the ranking of of alternatives for allocating subsidy reductions. – So, we can • Do things in the right order • Avoid drastic mistakes Note: The ranking depends on the situation! It cannot be invariant (over space, time, extent of subsidies, output, cultures etc)! Therefore, to compile the checklist, we need to know 1. The transformation frontier 2. The social preference (utility) map 3. In a dynamic context The transformation frontier (How do subsidy reductions translate into environmental benefits) • • • For all environmental variables! Requires intricate economic knowledge (dynamic GE model) Requires intricate environmental knowledge (how does economic activity really affect the environment) We don’t have this knowledge! The social utility map • Basically environmental valuation • This is a function of environmental quality • This is a function of the state of the economy (all economic variables) We don’t have this knowledge! We are like a man sent to the supermarket to buy groceries • He has a certain amount to spend • But doesn´t know the price of the goods (I.e. how much he gets for a given expenditure) • He doesn’t know the utility generated by the goods. What can he do? The problem is one of choice under uncertainty • Only if all outcomes are equally likely will it be optimal to do nothing. • Assuming constant risk over choices, the best choice is to pick the most likely options. • This is precisely what a good checklist is supposed to do • It increases the likelihood of a good choice Jan Pieters checklist • Not solidly founded in theory • But impressively intuitive (and practical) • Misses two important aspects: – Corresponding to every subsidy is a tax – The environmental gains must be valued • Apart from this I found myself in general agreement Flow chart behind the checklist Description of the subsidy Policy filter effective yes no Benign alternatives available no yes Conditionality leads to higher volumes no yes Concentration of market power yes Subsidy removal not likely to be environmentally beneficial Effects are indeterminate no Environmental variables valuable no yes Subsidy financing “problematic” no Subsidy removal likely to be environmentally beneficial End