Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Fall 2011 Lecture 14 Monday, we ran out of time talking about penalty damages Common law courts often refuse to enforce “penalty damages” written into a contract That is, damages which appear substantially larger than the harm actually done by breach Started to look at how penalty damages could have led to the desired outcome in Peevyhouse v Garland Coal 1 To remind you of the case… Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Peevyhouse v Garland Coal Peevyhouses only wanted farm strip-mined if it would be restored to original condition after Suppose coal extracted worth $70,000 Garland paid $25,000 for rights to mine it Restoration work would cost $30,000 Diminution of value was $300 So liquidated damages would be $300 Suppose Peevyhouses got $40,000 of disutility from land being left in poor condition 2 Liquidated damages Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Peevyhouses Don’t Sign Garland Coal (0, 0) Restore property (25,000, 15,000) Don’t, pay damages (-14,700, 44,700) If courts will only enforce liquidated damages… Peevyhouses shouldn’t believe restorative work will get done So Peevyhouses better off refusing to sign Even though mining and restoring Pareto-dominates 3 Penalty damages Coal worth $70,000 Garland to pay $25,000 Restoration would cost $30,000 Liquidated damages are $300 Peevyhouses value restoration at $40,000 Peevyhouses Don’t Sign Garland Coal (0, 0) Restore property (25,000, 15,000) Don’t, pay penalty (25,000, 5,000) If penalty damages were enforceable… Write contract with $40,000 penalty for leaving land unrestored Now restoration work would get done, so Peevyhouses willing to sign But if courts won’t enforce penalty damages, this won’t work 4 Penalty clauses Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a $50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000 performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem! 5 Penalty clauses Whatever you can accomplish with penalty clause, you could also accomplish with performance bonus I agree to pay $200,000 to get house built, but I want you to pay a $50,000 penalty if it’s late Alternatively: I agree to pay $150,000 for house, plus a $50,000 performance bonus if it’s completed on time Either way, you get $150,000 if house is late, $200,000 if on time Courts generally enforce bonus clauses, so no problem! Similarly, Peevyhouse example Peevyhouses get $25,000 for mining rights, $40,000 penalty if land is not restored Equivalently, get $65,000 for mining rights, pay $40,000 bonus if restoration is completed But, if intent of contract is too transparent, still might not be enforced 6 Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance 7 Plane worth $500,000 to you Price $350,000 Cost: either $250,000 or $1,000,000 Remedies and breach Expectation Damages Specific Performance Costs Low – Perform Costs High – Perform Costs High – Breach I get 100,000 -650,000 -150,000 You get 150,000 150,000 150,000 Total 250,000 -500,000 0 Costs Low – Perform Costs High – Perform Costs High – Renegotiate I get 100,000 -650,000 -400,000 –650,000 + ½ (500,000) You get 150,000 150,000 400,000 150,000 + ½ (500,000) Total 250,000 -500,000 0 Transaction costs low either leads to efficient breach, but seller prefers “weaker” remedy Transaction costs high S.P. leads to ineff. performance 8 Remedies and breach Opportunity cost damages, or reliance damages Inefficient breach when transaction costs are high Renegotiate contract to get efficient performance when transaction costs are low Like nuisance law: any remedy leads to efficient breach with low TC But only expectation damages do when TC are high Unfortunate contingency and fortunate contingency 9 Efficient signing Specific Performance If costs stay low, I get $350,000 - $250,000 = $100,000 profit If costs rise, I take $400,000 loss Am I willing to sign this contract? Even expectation damages face this problem Expectation damages: costs stay low, same $100,000 profit Costs rise, $150,000 loss If probability of high costs is ½, I won’t sign contract Expectation damages lead to efficient breach, but may not lead to efficient signing 10 Reliance – did example a few days ago If reliance investments increase the damages you receive, we expect to get overreliance To get efficient reliance, need to exclude gains from reliance in calculation of expectation damages But then promisor’s liability < promisee’s benefit, leading to inefficient breach With low transaction costs, fix this through renegotiation But what about unobservable actions the promisor needs to take, to make breach less likely? Investment in performance 11 Investment in performance Some investment I can make to reduce likelihood that breach becomes necessary Suppose probability of breach is initially ½… but for every $27,726 I invest, I cut the probability in half Invest nothing probability of breach is 1/2 Invest $27,726 probability is 1/4 Invest $55,452 probability is 1/8 Any investment z probability is .5 * (.5) z / 27,726 Wrote it this way so p = .5 e – z / 40,000 12 Investment in performance (continuing with airplane example) Suppose you’ve built a $90,000 hangar Increases value of performance by $180,000… …so value of performance is $150,000 + $180,000 = $330,000 Probability of breach = .5 e – z/40,000 Let D = damages I owe if I breach Same questions as before: What is efficient level of investment in performance? How much will I choose to invest in performance? 13 Investment in performance (continuing with airplane example) Suppose you’ve built a $90,000 hangar Increases value of performance by $180,000… …so value of performance is $150,000 + $180,000 = $330,000 Probability of breach = .5 e – z/40,000 Let D = damages I owe if I breach Same questions as before: What is efficient level of investment in performance? Enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/430,000 How much will I choose to invest in performance? Enough to reduce probability of breach to 40,000/(100,000 + D) 14 What do these results mean? What is the efficient level of investment in performance? Enough so that p(z) = 40,000/430,000 What will promisor do under various rules for damages? Enough so that p(z) = 40,000/(100,000 + D) So if D = 330,000, efficient investment in performance D = 330,000 is promisee’s benefit, including reliance So expectation damages, with benefit of reliance, leads to efficient investment in performance If D < 330,000, too little investment in performance If D > 330,000, too much Makes sense – think about externalities 15 Effects of different remedies on… decision to perform or breach decision to sign or not sign investment in performing investment in reliance 16 Paradox of compensation Expectation damages include benefit from reliance investments Expectation damages exclude benefit from reliance investments • Efficient breach • Inefficient breach • Efficient investment in performance • Underinvestment in performance • Over-reliance • Efficient reliance Is there a way to get efficient behavior by both parties? 17 We already saw one possible solution Have expectation damages include benefit from reliance… …but only up to the efficient level of reliance, not beyond That is, have damages reward efficient reliance investments, but not overreliance Promisee has no incentive to over-rely efficient reliance Promisor still bears full cost of breach efficient performance Problem: this requires court to calculate efficient level of reliance after the fact 18 Another clever (but unrealistic) solution The problem: Damages promisor pays should include gain from reliance if we want to get efficient performance Damages promisee receives should exclude gain from reliance if we want to get efficient reliance Solution: make damages promisor pays different from damages promisee receives! How do we do this? Need a third party 19 “Anti-insurance” You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: If you rely and I breach, I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) Bob keeps the difference You receive damages without benefit from reliance; I pay damages with benefit from reliance 20 “Anti-insurance” You (promisee) and I (promisor) offer Bob this deal: If you rely and I breach, I pay Bob value of promise with reliance (airplane plus hangar) Bob pays you value of promise without reliance (airplane alone) Bob keeps the difference You receive damages without benefit from reliance; I pay damages with benefit from reliance Offer the deal to two people, make them pay up front for it 21 Reminder: what do courts actually do? Foreseeable reliance Include benefits reliance that promisor could have reasonably anticipated 22 Another experiment: is trust a problem? 23 A two-player game, similar to the investment/agency game Player A starts with $10 Chooses how much of it to give to player B That money is tripled Player B has $10, plus 3x whatever A gave him/her Chooses how much (if any) to give back to player A So for example… if player A decides to send $3… then A has $7 left, and B has $19… and then B can send back to A any amount from 0 to $19 if A sends $9, B has $37, A has $1 plus whatever B sends back 24 A two-player game, similar to the investment/agency game We’ll try the game four different ways: Anonymously – A and B don’t know who each other are Privately – A and B don’t interact, but will learn who each other are after the game Face to face – A and B know who each other are, and can discuss the game before playing, but their actions remain private Publicly – A and B play out loud in front of the class 25 Repeated interactions 26 Repeated games 27 Repeated games Player 1 (you) Don’t Trust me Player 2 (me) (100, 0) Share profits (150, 50) Keep all the money (0, 200) Suppose we’ll play the game over and over After each game, 10% chance relationship ends, 90% chance we play at least once more… 28 Repeated games Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… Value of relationship = 50 500 50 50 .9 50 .9 50 .9 ... 1 .9 2 3 Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation 29 Repeated games Suppose you’ve chosen to trust me Keep all the money: I get $200 today, nothing ever again Share profits: I get $50 today, $50 tomorrow, $50 day after… Value of relationship = 50 500 50 50 .9 50 .9 50 .9 ... 1 .9 2 3 Since this is more than $200, we can get cooperation 30 Repeated games and reputation Diamond dealers in New York (Friedman) “…people routinely exchange large sums of money for envelopes containing lots of little stones without first inspecting, weighing, and testing each one” “Parties to a contract agree in advance to arbitration; if… one of them refuses to accept the arbitrator’s verdict, he is no longer a diamond merchant – because everyone in the industry now knows he cannot be trusted.” 31 Repeated games and reputation The first purpose of contract law is to enable cooperation, by converting games with noncooperative solutions into games with cooperative solutions The sixth purpose of contract law is to foster enduring relationships, which solve the problem of cooperation with less reliance on courts to enforce contracts Law assigns legal duties to certain long-term relationships Bank has fiduciary duty to depositors McDonalds franchisee has certain duties to franchisor 32 Repeated games and the endgame problem Suppose we’ll play agency game 60 times $50 x 60 = $3,000 > $200, so cooperation seems like no problem But… In game #60, reputation has no value to me Last time we’re going to interact So I have no reason not to keep all the money So you have no reason to trust me But if we weren’t going to cooperate in game #60, then in game #59… 33 Repeated games and the endgame problem Endgame problem: once there’s a definite end to our relationship, no reason to trust each other Example: collapse of communism in late 1980s Communism believed to be much less efficient than capitalism But fall of communism led to decrease in growth Under communism, lots of production relied on gray market Transactions weren’t protected by law, so they relied on long-term relationships Fall of communism upset these relationships 34 One other bit I like from Friedman 35 Friedman on premarital sex 36 Friedman on premarital sex 37 That’s it for contract law Purposes for contract law: Encourage cooperation Encourage efficient disclosure of information Secure optimal commitment to performance Secure efficient reliance Provide efficient default rules and regulations Foster enduring relationships End of material on second midterm Next week, we begin tort law 38