Econ 522 Economics of Law Dan Quint Spring 2013

advertisement

Econ 522

Economics of Law

Dan Quint

Spring 2013

Lecture 6

Our story so far on property law…

 Coase: absent transaction costs, if property rights are complete and tradable, we’ll get efficiency through voluntary negotiation

 So we can always get efficient outcomes “automatically”…

 …provided there are no transaction costs

 But what to do when there are?

1

Different types/sources of transaction costs

 Search costs

 Bargaining costs

Asymmetric information/adverse selection

Private information/not knowing each others’ threat points

Uncertainty about property rights/threat points

Large numbers of buyers/sellers – holdout, freeriding

Hostility

 Enforcement costs

2

Two normative approaches to the law

 Normative Coase: aim to minimize transaction costs

 Normative Hobbes: aim to allocate rights efficiently (or minimize the need for bargaining/trade)

 How to choose between the two?

When transaction costs are low and information costs high, design law to minimize transaction costs

What transaction costs are high and information costs are low, design law to allocate rights efficiently

3

Two normative approaches to the law

 Defaulting to the normative Coase approach means relying on bargaining to reallocate rights efficiently

 Is it realistic to think this will work in real life?

 Is it realistic to think this would work in a room full of undergrad econ majors?

4

An experiment on

“Coasian bargaining”

5

Experiment: Coasian bargaining

 Round 1 (full information)

Ten people, five of them have a poker chip to start

Each person is given a personal value for a poker chip

At the end of the round, that’s how much you can trade in a chip for

Purple chip is worth that number, red chip is worth 2 x your number

So if your number is 6 and you end up with a purple chip, I’ll give you

$6 for it; if you end up with a red chip, I’ll give you $12 for it

Each person can only sell back one chip

Your number is on your nametag (common knowledge)

6

Experiment: Coasian bargaining

 Round 2 (private information)

Ten people, five of them have a poker chip to start

Each person is given a personal value for a poker chip

At the end of the round, that’s how much you can trade in a chip for

Purple chip is worth that number, red chip is worth 2 x your number

So if your number is 6 and you end up with a purple chip, I’ll give you

$6 for it; if you end up with a red chip, I’ll give you $12 for it

Each person can only sell back one chip

Only you know your number

7

Experiment: Coasian bargaining

 Round 3 (uncertainty)

Six people, three poker chips

Value of each chip is determined by a die roll

If seller keeps the chip, it’s worth 2 x roll of the die

If new buyer buys chip, it’s worth 3 x roll of the die

No contingent trades – buyer must pay cash

Nobody sees the die roll until the end

8

Experiment: Coasian bargaining

 Round 4 (asymmetric information)

Six people, three poker chips

Value of each chip is determined by a die roll

If seller keeps the chip, it’s worth 2 x roll of the die

If new buyer buys chip, it’s worth 3 x roll of the die

No contingent trades – buyer must pay cash

Seller sees the die roll initially, buyer does not

9

Back to work

10

Last week: what things should be privately owned?

 Public Goods

 non-rivalrous, non-excludable tend to be underprovided when privately supplied tend to have high transaction costs (many people involved)

 suggests public provision/regulation preferable

 Private goods

 rivalrous, excludable

 tend to be overexploited when publicly owned tend to have low transaction costs (one buyer, one seller) suggests private ownership preferable

11

A different view: transaction costs

 Clean air

 Large number of people affected  transaction costs high

 injunctive relief unlikely to work well

 Still two options

One: give property owners right to clean air, protected by damages

Two: public regulation

 Argue for one or the other by comparing costs of each

Damages: costs are legal cost of lawsuits or pretrial negotiations

Regulation: administrative costs, error costs if level is not chosen correctly

12

Next question: choosing a remedy for property rights violations

 Injunctive relief : court clarifies right, bars future violation; violations are punished as crimes (but right is tradable)

 Damages : court determines how much harm was done by violation, awards payment to injuree

 Coase: should be equally efficient if there are no transaction costs

 But in “real world”, which is more efficient?

13

Calabresi and Melamed treat property and liability under a common framework

 Calabresi and Melamed (1972), Property Rules, Liability

Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral

 Liability

 Is the rancher liable for the damage done by his herd?

 Property

 Does the farmer’s right to his property include the right to be free from trespassing cows?

 Entitlements

Is the farmer entitled to land free from trespassing animals?

Or is the rancher entitled to the natural actions of his cattle?

14

Three possible ways to protect an entitlement

 Property rule / injunctive relief

Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime

( Injunction : court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)

But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)

15

Three possible ways to protect an entitlement

 Property rule / injunctive relief

Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime

( Injunction : court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)

But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)

 Liability rule / damages

Violations of my entitlement are compensated

Damages – payment to victim to compensate for damage done

 Inalienability

 Violations punished as a crime

 Unlike property rule, the entitlement cannot be sold

16

Comparing property/injunctive relief to liability/damages rule

 Injuree (person whose entitlement is violated) always prefers a property rule

 Injurer always prefers a damages rule

 Why?

Punishment for violating a property rule is severe

If the two sides need to negotiate to trade the right, injurer’s threat point is lower

Even if both rules eventually lead to the same outcome, injurer may have to pay more

17

Comparing injunctive relief to damages – example

E profits = 1,000

L profits = 300  100

E prevention = 500

L prevention = 100

 Electric company E emits smoke, dirties the laundry at a laundromat L next door

 E earns profits of 1,000

 Without smoke, L earns profits of 300

 Smoke reduces L’s profits from 300 to 100

 E could stop polluting at cost 500

 L could prevent the damage at cost 100

18

First, we consider the non-cooperative outcomes

 Polluter’s Rights ( no remedy )

E earns 1,000

L installs filters, earns 300 – 100 = 200

 Laundromat has right to damages

E earns 1,000, pays damages of 200  800

L earns 100, gets damages of 200  300

 Laundromat has right to injunction

 E installs scrubbers, earns 1,000 – 500 = 500

 L earns 300

E profits = 1,000

L profits = 300  100

E prevention = 500

L prevention = 100

19

Noncooperative payoffs

E payoff

(non-coop)

L payoff

(non-coop)

Combined payoff

(non-coop)

Polluter’s Rights

1,000

200

1,200

Damages

800

300

1,100

E profits = 1,000

L profits = 300  100

E prevention = 500

L prevention = 100

Injunction

500

300

800

20

What about with bargaining?

E payoff

(non-coop)

L payoff

(non-coop)

Combined payoff

(non-coop)

Gains from Coop

E payoff (coop)

L payoff (coop)

Combined

Polluter’s Rights

1,000

200

1,200

0

1,000

200

1,200

Damages

800

300

1,100

100

1,200

E profits = 1,000

L profits = 300  100

E prevention = 500

L prevention = 100

Injunction

500

300

800

400

1,200

21

Comparing injunctions to damages…

 Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer

 No need for court to calculate amount of harm done

22

Comparing injunctions to damages…

 Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer

 No need for court to calculate amount of harm done

 Damages are generally more efficient when private bargaining is impossible

Three possibilities: injurer prevents harm, injuree prevents harm, nobody prevents harm (someone pays for it)

Efficiency: cheapest of the three

Damages: injurer can prevent harm or pay for it; injurer chooses whichever is cheapest

Injunction: injurer can only prevent harm

23

So now we know…

 Any rule leads to efficient outcomes when TC are low

 Injunctions are cheaper to implement

 Damages lead to more efficient outcomes when TC high

 Leads Calabresi and Melamed to the following conclusion:

When transaction costs are low , a property rule (injunctive relief) is more efficient

When transaction costs are high , a liability rule (damages) is more efficient

24

Exactly agrees with our earlier principle

 Transactions costs low: design law to facilitate trade

 Property rule does this: clarifies right, allows trade

 Transaction costs high: design law to minimize losses due to failures of private bargaining

 Liability rule does this: gives injurer right to violate entitlement when efficient, even without prior consent

25

High transaction costs  damages

Low transaction costs  injunctive relief

“Private bargaining is unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed strangers because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior is likely to occur. Large numbers of land owners are typically affected by nuisances , such as air pollution or the stench from a feedlot. In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy.

On the other hand, property disputes generally involve a small number of parties who live near each other and can monitor each others’ behavior easily after reaching a deal; so injunctive relief is usually used in these cases.”

(Cooter and Ulen)

26

A different view of the high-transaction-costs case…

“When transaction costs preclude bargaining, the court should protect a right by an injunctive remedy if it knows which party values the right relatively more and it does not know how much either party values it absolutely .

Conversely, the court should protect a right by a damages remedy if it knows how much one of the parties values the right absolutely and it does not know which party values it relatively more .”

(Cooter and Ulen)

27

Low transaction costs  injunctive relief

 Cheaper for the court to administer

 With low transaction costs, we expect parties to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently

 But … do they really?

Ward Farnsworth (1999), Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain

After Judgment? A Glimpse Inside The Cathedral

20 nuisance cases: no bargaining after judgment

“In almost every case the lawyers said that acrimony between the parties was an important obstacle to bargaining…

Frequently the parties were not on speaking terms...

…The second recurring obstacle involves the parties’ disinclination to think of the rights at stake… as readily commensurable with cash.”

28

So, do we buy it?

 Coase relies on parties being able to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently

 Low-TC case: injunctions more efficient, assuming bargaining works if “wrong” party is awarded the right

 But does it work?

Paper by Farnsworth shows no bargaining after 20 nuisance cases

Our experiment showed various transaction costs that could be a problem: private information, uncertainty, asymmetric information

29

Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability

 Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable

 Allocative externalities

(enriched uranium)

30

Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability

 Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable

 Allocative externalities

(enriched uranium)

 “Indirect” externalities

(human organs)

31

Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability

 Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable

 Allocative externalities

(enriched uranium)

 “Indirect” externalities

(human organs)

 Paternalism source: http://www.shanghaidaily.com/nsp/

National/2011/06/02/Boy%2Bregrets%2Bselling

%2Bhis%2Bkidney%2Bto%2Bbuy%2BiPad/

32

How do we design an efficient property law system?

what can be privately owned?

what can an owner do?

how are property rights established?

what remedies are given?

33

What can an owner do with his property?

 Principle of maximum liberty

 Owners can do whatever they like with their property, provided it does not interfere with other’ property or rights

 That is, you can do anything you like so long as it doesn’t impose an externality ( nuisance ) on anyone else

34

How do we design an efficient property law system?

what can be privately owned?

what can an owner do?

how are property rights established?

what remedies are given?

35

Fugitive property

 Hammonds v. Central

Kentucky Natural Gas Co.

Central Kentucky leased land lying above natural gas deposits

Geological dome lay partly under Hammonds’ land

Central Kentucky drilled down and extracted the gas;

Hammonds sued, claiming some of the gas was his

(Anybody see “There Will

Be Blood”?)

Hammonds Central KY

36

Two principles for establishing ownership

 First Possession

 nobody owns fugitive property until someone possesses it first to “capture” a resource owns it

 Central Kentucky would own all the gas

 Tied Ownership

 ownership of fugitive property tied to something else (here, surface) so ownership already determined before resource is extracted

 Hammonds would own some of the gas, since under his land principle of accession – a new thing is owned by the owner of the proximate or prominent property

37

First Possession versus Tied Ownership

 First Possession

 simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first

 incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership

 example: $100 of gas, two companies drilling fast or slow drilling slowly costs $5, drilling fast costs $25 drill same speed  each gets half the gas, one drills fast  75/25

Slow

Firm 2

Fast

Slow 45, 45 20, 50

Fast 50, 20 25, 25

38

First Possession versus Tied Ownership

 First Possession

 simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first

 incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership

 Tied Ownership

 encourages efficient use of the resource

Slow Fast

Slow 45, 45 45, 25

Fast 25 , 45 25, 25

39

This brings us to the following tradeoff:

Rules that link ownership to possession have the advantage of being easy to administer , and the disadvantage of providing incentives for uneconomic investment in possessory acts .

Rules that allow ownership without possession have the advantage of avoiding preemptive investment and the disadvantage of being costly to administer .

40

A nice historical example: the Homestead

Act of 1862

 Meant to encourage settlement of the Western U.S.

 Citizens could acquire 160 acres of land for free, provided

 head of a family or 21 years old

“for the purpose of actual cultivation, and not… for the use or benefit of someone else” had to live on the claim for 6 months and make “suitable” improvements

 Basically a first possession rule for land – by living on the land, you gained ownership of it

 Friedman: caused people to spend inefficiently much to gain ownership of the land

41

Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862

“The year is 1862; the piece of land we are considering is… too far from railroads, feed stores, and other people to be cultivated at a profit.

…The efficient rule would be to start farming the land the first year that doing so becomes profitable, say 1890. But if you set out to homestead the land in 1890, you will get an unpleasant surprise: someone else is already there.

…If you want to get the land you will have to come early. By farming it at a loss for a few years you can acquire the right to farm it thereafter at a profit.

42

Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862

How early will you have to come?

Assume the value of the land in 1890 is going to be $20,000, representing the present value of the profit that can be made by farming it from then on. Further assume that the loss from farming it earlier than that is $1,000 a year.

If you try to homestead it in 1880, you again find the land already taken. Someone who homesteads in 1880 pays $10,000 in losses for $20,000 in real estate

– not as good as getting it for free, but still an attractive deal.

…The land will be claimed about 1870, just early enough so that the losses in the early years balance the later gains.

It follows that the effect of the Homestead Act was to wipe out, in costs of premature farming, a large part of the land value of the

United States.

43

So, what does an efficient property law system look like?

 What things can be privately owned?

 Private goods are privately owned, public goods are publicly provided

 What can owners do with their property?

 Maximum liberty

 How are property rights established?

 (Tradeoff between first possession and tied ownership; more examples to come)

 What remedies are given?

 Injunctions when transaction costs are low; damages when transaction costs are high 44

Download