Dan Quint
Spring 2013
Lecture 6
Our story so far on property law…
Coase: absent transaction costs, if property rights are complete and tradable, we’ll get efficiency through voluntary negotiation
So we can always get efficient outcomes “automatically”…
…provided there are no transaction costs
But what to do when there are?
1
Different types/sources of transaction costs
Search costs
Bargaining costs
Asymmetric information/adverse selection
Private information/not knowing each others’ threat points
Uncertainty about property rights/threat points
Large numbers of buyers/sellers – holdout, freeriding
Hostility
Enforcement costs
2
Two normative approaches to the law
Normative Coase: aim to minimize transaction costs
Normative Hobbes: aim to allocate rights efficiently (or minimize the need for bargaining/trade)
How to choose between the two?
When transaction costs are low and information costs high, design law to minimize transaction costs
What transaction costs are high and information costs are low, design law to allocate rights efficiently
3
Two normative approaches to the law
Defaulting to the normative Coase approach means relying on bargaining to reallocate rights efficiently
Is it realistic to think this will work in real life?
Is it realistic to think this would work in a room full of undergrad econ majors?
4
An experiment on
“Coasian bargaining”
5
Experiment: Coasian bargaining
Round 1 (full information)
Ten people, five of them have a poker chip to start
Each person is given a personal value for a poker chip
At the end of the round, that’s how much you can trade in a chip for
Purple chip is worth that number, red chip is worth 2 x your number
So if your number is 6 and you end up with a purple chip, I’ll give you
$6 for it; if you end up with a red chip, I’ll give you $12 for it
Each person can only sell back one chip
Your number is on your nametag (common knowledge)
6
Experiment: Coasian bargaining
Round 2 (private information)
Ten people, five of them have a poker chip to start
Each person is given a personal value for a poker chip
At the end of the round, that’s how much you can trade in a chip for
Purple chip is worth that number, red chip is worth 2 x your number
So if your number is 6 and you end up with a purple chip, I’ll give you
$6 for it; if you end up with a red chip, I’ll give you $12 for it
Each person can only sell back one chip
Only you know your number
7
Experiment: Coasian bargaining
Round 3 (uncertainty)
Six people, three poker chips
Value of each chip is determined by a die roll
If seller keeps the chip, it’s worth 2 x roll of the die
If new buyer buys chip, it’s worth 3 x roll of the die
No contingent trades – buyer must pay cash
Nobody sees the die roll until the end
8
Experiment: Coasian bargaining
Round 4 (asymmetric information)
Six people, three poker chips
Value of each chip is determined by a die roll
If seller keeps the chip, it’s worth 2 x roll of the die
If new buyer buys chip, it’s worth 3 x roll of the die
No contingent trades – buyer must pay cash
Seller sees the die roll initially, buyer does not
9
Back to work
10
Last week: what things should be privately owned?
Public Goods
non-rivalrous, non-excludable tend to be underprovided when privately supplied tend to have high transaction costs (many people involved)
suggests public provision/regulation preferable
Private goods
rivalrous, excludable
tend to be overexploited when publicly owned tend to have low transaction costs (one buyer, one seller) suggests private ownership preferable
11
A different view: transaction costs
Clean air
Large number of people affected transaction costs high
injunctive relief unlikely to work well
Still two options
One: give property owners right to clean air, protected by damages
Two: public regulation
Argue for one or the other by comparing costs of each
Damages: costs are legal cost of lawsuits or pretrial negotiations
Regulation: administrative costs, error costs if level is not chosen correctly
12
Next question: choosing a remedy for property rights violations
Injunctive relief : court clarifies right, bars future violation; violations are punished as crimes (but right is tradable)
Damages : court determines how much harm was done by violation, awards payment to injuree
Coase: should be equally efficient if there are no transaction costs
But in “real world”, which is more efficient?
13
Calabresi and Melamed treat property and liability under a common framework
Calabresi and Melamed (1972), Property Rules, Liability
Rules, and Inalienability: One View of the Cathedral
Liability
Is the rancher liable for the damage done by his herd?
Property
Does the farmer’s right to his property include the right to be free from trespassing cows?
Entitlements
Is the farmer entitled to land free from trespassing animals?
Or is the rancher entitled to the natural actions of his cattle?
14
Three possible ways to protect an entitlement
Property rule / injunctive relief
Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime
( Injunction : court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)
But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)
15
Three possible ways to protect an entitlement
Property rule / injunctive relief
Violation of my entitlement is punished as a crime
( Injunction : court order clarifying a right and specifically barring any future violation)
But entitlement is negotiable (I can choose to sell/give up my right)
Liability rule / damages
Violations of my entitlement are compensated
Damages – payment to victim to compensate for damage done
Inalienability
Violations punished as a crime
Unlike property rule, the entitlement cannot be sold
16
Comparing property/injunctive relief to liability/damages rule
Injuree (person whose entitlement is violated) always prefers a property rule
Injurer always prefers a damages rule
Why?
Punishment for violating a property rule is severe
If the two sides need to negotiate to trade the right, injurer’s threat point is lower
Even if both rules eventually lead to the same outcome, injurer may have to pay more
17
Comparing injunctive relief to damages – example
E profits = 1,000
L profits = 300 100
E prevention = 500
L prevention = 100
Electric company E emits smoke, dirties the laundry at a laundromat L next door
E earns profits of 1,000
Without smoke, L earns profits of 300
Smoke reduces L’s profits from 300 to 100
E could stop polluting at cost 500
L could prevent the damage at cost 100
18
First, we consider the non-cooperative outcomes
Polluter’s Rights ( no remedy )
E earns 1,000
L installs filters, earns 300 – 100 = 200
Laundromat has right to damages
E earns 1,000, pays damages of 200 800
L earns 100, gets damages of 200 300
Laundromat has right to injunction
E installs scrubbers, earns 1,000 – 500 = 500
L earns 300
E profits = 1,000
L profits = 300 100
E prevention = 500
L prevention = 100
19
Noncooperative payoffs
E payoff
(non-coop)
L payoff
(non-coop)
Combined payoff
(non-coop)
Polluter’s Rights
1,000
200
1,200
Damages
800
300
1,100
E profits = 1,000
L profits = 300 100
E prevention = 500
L prevention = 100
Injunction
500
300
800
20
What about with bargaining?
E payoff
(non-coop)
L payoff
(non-coop)
Combined payoff
(non-coop)
Gains from Coop
E payoff (coop)
L payoff (coop)
Combined
Polluter’s Rights
1,000
200
1,200
0
1,000
200
1,200
Damages
800
300
1,100
100
1,200
E profits = 1,000
L profits = 300 100
E prevention = 500
L prevention = 100
Injunction
500
300
800
400
1,200
21
Comparing injunctions to damages…
Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer
No need for court to calculate amount of harm done
22
Comparing injunctions to damages…
Injunctions are generally cheaper to administer
No need for court to calculate amount of harm done
Damages are generally more efficient when private bargaining is impossible
Three possibilities: injurer prevents harm, injuree prevents harm, nobody prevents harm (someone pays for it)
Efficiency: cheapest of the three
Damages: injurer can prevent harm or pay for it; injurer chooses whichever is cheapest
Injunction: injurer can only prevent harm
23
So now we know…
Any rule leads to efficient outcomes when TC are low
Injunctions are cheaper to implement
Damages lead to more efficient outcomes when TC high
Leads Calabresi and Melamed to the following conclusion:
When transaction costs are low , a property rule (injunctive relief) is more efficient
When transaction costs are high , a liability rule (damages) is more efficient
24
Exactly agrees with our earlier principle
Transactions costs low: design law to facilitate trade
Property rule does this: clarifies right, allows trade
Transaction costs high: design law to minimize losses due to failures of private bargaining
Liability rule does this: gives injurer right to violate entitlement when efficient, even without prior consent
25
High transaction costs damages
Low transaction costs injunctive relief
“Private bargaining is unlikely to succeed in disputes involving a large number of geographically dispersed strangers because communication costs are high, monitoring is costly, and strategic behavior is likely to occur. Large numbers of land owners are typically affected by nuisances , such as air pollution or the stench from a feedlot. In these cases, damages are the preferred remedy.
On the other hand, property disputes generally involve a small number of parties who live near each other and can monitor each others’ behavior easily after reaching a deal; so injunctive relief is usually used in these cases.”
(Cooter and Ulen)
26
A different view of the high-transaction-costs case…
“When transaction costs preclude bargaining, the court should protect a right by an injunctive remedy if it knows which party values the right relatively more and it does not know how much either party values it absolutely .
Conversely, the court should protect a right by a damages remedy if it knows how much one of the parties values the right absolutely and it does not know which party values it relatively more .”
(Cooter and Ulen)
27
Low transaction costs injunctive relief
Cheaper for the court to administer
With low transaction costs, we expect parties to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently
But … do they really?
Ward Farnsworth (1999), Do Parties to Nuisance Cases Bargain
After Judgment? A Glimpse Inside The Cathedral
20 nuisance cases: no bargaining after judgment
“In almost every case the lawyers said that acrimony between the parties was an important obstacle to bargaining…
Frequently the parties were not on speaking terms...
…The second recurring obstacle involves the parties’ disinclination to think of the rights at stake… as readily commensurable with cash.”
28
So, do we buy it?
Coase relies on parties being able to negotiate privately if the right is not assigned efficiently
Low-TC case: injunctions more efficient, assuming bargaining works if “wrong” party is awarded the right
But does it work?
Paper by Farnsworth shows no bargaining after 20 nuisance cases
Our experiment showed various transaction costs that could be a problem: private information, uncertainty, asymmetric information
29
Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability
Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable
Allocative externalities
(enriched uranium)
30
Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability
Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable
Allocative externalities
(enriched uranium)
“Indirect” externalities
(human organs)
31
Third way to protect an entitlement: inalienability
Inalienability: when an entitlement is not transferable or saleable
Allocative externalities
(enriched uranium)
“Indirect” externalities
(human organs)
Paternalism source: http://www.shanghaidaily.com/nsp/
National/2011/06/02/Boy%2Bregrets%2Bselling
%2Bhis%2Bkidney%2Bto%2Bbuy%2BiPad/
32
How do we design an efficient property law system?
what can be privately owned?
what can an owner do?
how are property rights established?
what remedies are given?
33
What can an owner do with his property?
Principle of maximum liberty
Owners can do whatever they like with their property, provided it does not interfere with other’ property or rights
That is, you can do anything you like so long as it doesn’t impose an externality ( nuisance ) on anyone else
34
How do we design an efficient property law system?
what can be privately owned?
what can an owner do?
how are property rights established?
what remedies are given?
35
Fugitive property
Hammonds v. Central
Kentucky Natural Gas Co.
Central Kentucky leased land lying above natural gas deposits
Geological dome lay partly under Hammonds’ land
Central Kentucky drilled down and extracted the gas;
Hammonds sued, claiming some of the gas was his
(Anybody see “There Will
Be Blood”?)
Hammonds Central KY
36
Two principles for establishing ownership
First Possession
nobody owns fugitive property until someone possesses it first to “capture” a resource owns it
Central Kentucky would own all the gas
Tied Ownership
ownership of fugitive property tied to something else (here, surface) so ownership already determined before resource is extracted
Hammonds would own some of the gas, since under his land principle of accession – a new thing is owned by the owner of the proximate or prominent property
37
First Possession versus Tied Ownership
First Possession
simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first
incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership
example: $100 of gas, two companies drilling fast or slow drilling slowly costs $5, drilling fast costs $25 drill same speed each gets half the gas, one drills fast 75/25
Slow
Firm 2
Fast
Slow 45, 45 20, 50
Fast 50, 20 25, 25
38
First Possession versus Tied Ownership
First Possession
simpler to apply – easy to determine who possessed property first
incentive to invest too much to early in order to establish ownership
Tied Ownership
encourages efficient use of the resource
Slow Fast
Slow 45, 45 45, 25
Fast 25 , 45 25, 25
39
This brings us to the following tradeoff:
Rules that link ownership to possession have the advantage of being easy to administer , and the disadvantage of providing incentives for uneconomic investment in possessory acts .
Rules that allow ownership without possession have the advantage of avoiding preemptive investment and the disadvantage of being costly to administer .
40
A nice historical example: the Homestead
Act of 1862
Meant to encourage settlement of the Western U.S.
Citizens could acquire 160 acres of land for free, provided
head of a family or 21 years old
“for the purpose of actual cultivation, and not… for the use or benefit of someone else” had to live on the claim for 6 months and make “suitable” improvements
Basically a first possession rule for land – by living on the land, you gained ownership of it
Friedman: caused people to spend inefficiently much to gain ownership of the land
41
Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862
“The year is 1862; the piece of land we are considering is… too far from railroads, feed stores, and other people to be cultivated at a profit.
…The efficient rule would be to start farming the land the first year that doing so becomes profitable, say 1890. But if you set out to homestead the land in 1890, you will get an unpleasant surprise: someone else is already there.
…If you want to get the land you will have to come early. By farming it at a loss for a few years you can acquire the right to farm it thereafter at a profit.
42
Friedman on the Homestead Act of 1862
How early will you have to come?
Assume the value of the land in 1890 is going to be $20,000, representing the present value of the profit that can be made by farming it from then on. Further assume that the loss from farming it earlier than that is $1,000 a year.
If you try to homestead it in 1880, you again find the land already taken. Someone who homesteads in 1880 pays $10,000 in losses for $20,000 in real estate
– not as good as getting it for free, but still an attractive deal.
…The land will be claimed about 1870, just early enough so that the losses in the early years balance the later gains.
It follows that the effect of the Homestead Act was to wipe out, in costs of premature farming, a large part of the land value of the
United States.
”
43
So, what does an efficient property law system look like?
What things can be privately owned?
Private goods are privately owned, public goods are publicly provided
What can owners do with their property?
Maximum liberty
How are property rights established?
(Tradeoff between first possession and tied ownership; more examples to come)
What remedies are given?
Injunctions when transaction costs are low; damages when transaction costs are high 44