Residual income valuation: Are inflation adjustments necessary? John O'Hanlon* and Ken Peasnell** Management School Lancaster University Lancaster LA1 4YX UK July 17, 2003 * John O'Hanlon: email - J.O'hanlon@lancaster.ac.uk; telephone – (44) 1524 593631 ** Ken Peasnell: email - K.Peasnell@lancaster.ac.uk; telephone – (44) 1524 593977 Residual income valuation: Are inflation adjustments necessary? Abstract This paper explores the question of whether the residual income valuation relationship (RIVR) should be written in inflation-adjusted terms. This question is of particular interest in the light of Ritter and Warr's (2002) claim that the standard nominal historical cost RIVR undervalues firms because it fails to deal with inflation. We present three inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, each of which is based on an income measure from the inflation accounting literature, and one of which is a general case of Ritter and Warr's formulation. We show that none of these formulations is any more or less correct than the standard formulation of RIVR, and find no support for the view that it is necessary to write RIVR in inflation-adjusted terms. Finally we argue that, in a setting in which accounting numbers and forecasts thereof are normally presented in nominal historical cost terms, the inflation adjustment of RIVR is likely to bring unnecessary complication to the valuation process, with increased scope for error. Keywords: Equity valuation, residual income, inflation JEL classification: M4 Residual income valuation: Are inflation adjustments necessary? This paper explores the question of whether the residual income-based valuation relationship (RIVR) should be written in terms of inflation-adjusted residual incomes rather than in terms of nominal residual incomes. Until recently, the RIVR literature has been silent on the question of whether and how residual income forecasts should be adjusted to reflect expected inflation. The standard practice has been to work with nominal forecasts of historical cost residual income, discounted at the nominal cost of capital. However, a recent study by Ritter and Warr (2002) (RW) claims that this practice, as exemplified in the empirical work of Lee, Myers and Swaminathan (1999), can lead to under-valuation of firms. RW claim that for residual income models to produce accurate measures of true economic value 'they should use real required returns, adjust depreciation for the distorting effects of inflation, and make adjustments for leverage-induced capital gains' (RW, pp. 59-60). Bradley and Jarrell (2003) express a similar concern that accounting-based valuation models, including RIVR, fail to deal properly with the effect of inflation. In order to remedy the claimed shortcomings of the nominal historical costbased RIVR, RW propose a corrected inflation-adjusted formulation. RW report that this gives value estimates that differ markedly from those given by the nominal historical cost-based RIVR. Given the central role of RIVR in the theory and practice of accounting-based valuation, the possibility that RIVR fails to deal properly with the effects of inflation merits detailed analysis. In this paper, we carry out such an analysis. In our analysis, we present three formulations of RIVR, each of which is based on an inflation-adjusted income measure that has appeared in prior literature. The first formulation is based on current cost residual income. The second is based on real current cost residual income, being current cost residual income less a purchasing-power capital maintenance charge. These two residual income measures derive from income measures familiar from both the seminal work of Edwards and Bell (1961) and the now-defunct Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33: Financial Reporting and Changing Prices (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1979). The third formulation is based on real current cost residual income expressed in real terms as at the valuation date. This is a development of the residual income measures used in the first two inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, and forms the basis of the RW model. In presenting the three inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, we demonstrate that each is equivalent to the standard nominal historical cost-based RIVR and that, therefore, none of the three is any more correct or any less correct than the standard formulation of RIVR. Second, we demonstrate that, subject to a minor error, the RW model is a special case of the third of our inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, and is likewise no more or less correct than the standard nominal historical cost-based RIVR. We conclude that there is no logical basis for the view that RIVR needs to be written in terms of inflation-adjusted residual incomes rather than nominal historical cost-based residual incomes. In the light of this we argue that, in a setting in which accounting numbers and forecasts thereof are normally presented in nominal historical cost terms, complexity and potential for error are likely to be introduced into the valuation process by working with an inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR. The paper is organized as follows. Section 1 outlines the basis for residual income-based valuation in general, and outlines the criticisms levelled by RW at the nominal historical costbased formulation of RIVR. Section 2 presents three inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, as outlined above, and shows that all are theoretically equivalent to the standard nominal historical 2 cost-based formulation of RIVR. Section 3 shows that the RW model is a special case of one of the inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR presented in Section 2. Section 4 illustrates the complexity and potential for error that can be introduced into the valuation process by recasting nominal historical cost accounting inputs in inflation-adjusted terms. Conclusions are presented in Section 5. 1. The residual income-based valuation relationship (RIVR) This section outlines the basis for residual income-based valuation in general, and outlines the criticisms levelled by RW at the nominal historical cost-based formulation of RIVR. RIVR has three foundations. The first of these is the present value relationship (PVR) which is the cornerstone of the theory of asset valuation: Et [Ct s ] Vt s , s 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 (PVR) where V denotes the intrinsic value of equity, C denotes dividends net of new equity contributions, Re,t k denotes the one-period nominal cost of equity applicable to the equity capital as at time t+k-1, and Et [.] denotes expectations at time t. Here and throughout our exposition, all transactions are assumed to occur at the end of the relevant period. A second foundation of RIVR is the assumption that forecasts of dividends, accounting income and book value comply with the clean surplus relationship (CSR). A general statement of CSR is as follows: Bt s Bt s 1 Ct s Yt s , (CSR) 3 where B denotes the book value of equity and Y denotes accounting income. The third foundation is the definition of residual income, denoted RI, as income less a capital charge comprising the product of the cost of equity and the beginning-of-period book value of equity: RI t s Yt s Re,t s Bt s 1 . (RI) s Provided that Et [ Bt s ] / (1 Re,t k ) 0 as s ,1 the combination of PVR, CSR and RI k 1 yields the well-known RIVR:2 Et [ RI t s ] Vt Bt s . s 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 (RIVR) As long as forecast accounting numbers conform to CSR, the estimate of equity value given by RIVR is equal to the estimate, Vt , given by PVR. It is important to note that the theoretical equivalence between RIVR and PVR does not rely upon the valuation convention used in arriving at the forecasts of accounting incomes and book values. We now present the nominal historical cost-based formulation of RIVR that is conventionally used in the valuation literature, and outline RW's criticism of this formulation. We represent the historical cost balance sheet of the firm as comprising real (non-monetary) depreciable assets measured at historical cost net of depreciation, net debt, and equity measured on a historical cost basis.3 These three items are denoted A h , D and B h , respectively, where the superscript h indicates that the accounting number in question is measured on a historical cost basis. To avoid unnecessary complication, we assume throughout that debt is measured on the 4 same basis under both historical cost and current cost accounting.4 The historical cost book value of shareholders' equity at time t+s is the excess (or shortfall) of assets over debt: Bths Ath s Dt s . (1) Historical cost income for time t+s, denoted Y h is represented as comprising historical cost net income before depreciation, denoted HCIED, less historical cost depreciation, denoted DEPN th s : Yt hs HCIEDt s DEPN th s . (2) Historical cost residual income for time t+s, denoted RI th s , is as follows: RI th s Yt h s Re,t s Bth s 1 . (3) Provided that forecasts of historical cost income, historical cost book value of equity and dividends articulate in accordance with the historical cost CSR given by (4), Bths Bths1 Ct s Yt hs , (4) the value of equity can be written as follows: h E [ RI ] ts Vt h Bth s t s 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 Vt . (RIVR-H) RIVR-H is the nominal historical cost-based formulation of RIVR, where Vt h is the estimate of the value of equity in terms of the historical cost book value of equity and forecasts of future historical cost residual incomes and is equal to the value estimate, Vt , given by PVR. 5 Residual income-based valuation is conventionally based on RIVR-H. Empirical applications of RIVR-H are commonly based on the present value of analyst-based forecasts of nominal historical cost residual incomes for periods up to a horizon of two to five years, plus a terminal value term that includes the present value of all expected post-horizon residual incomes (Francis, Olsson and Oswald, 2000; Frankel and Lee, 1998; Lee et al., 1999). For example, an empirical valuation model used by Lee et al. (1999) and referred to by RW (p. 36) in motivating their analysis, is as follows: Vt h Bth Et [ RI th1 ] Et [ RI th2 ] Et [ RI th3 ] , (1 Re ) (1 Re ) 2 (1 Re ) 2 Re (5) where Re is the (assumed constant) nominal cost of equity. Here, the terminal value term comprises the nominal historical cost residual income forecast for time t+3 capitalized as a constant perpetuity. RW argue (pp. 36-38) that valuation models of the form of (5) have four shortcomings. First, the post-horizon residual incomes are capitalized as a flat perpetuity, which RW argue could be related to the erroneous application of a nominal discount rate to real flows. Second, such models fail to recognize a gain to equity-holders resulting from erosion in the purchasing power of monetary liabilities due to inflation ('debt capital gain'). Third, the use of the nominal required rate of return to calculate the residual income capital charge means that, in inflationary times, residual incomes are underestimated. Fourth, the depreciation expense embedded within residual income takes no account of increases in the current cost of depreciable assets. RW claim that the overall effect of these shortcomings will be to cause RIVR to undervalue firms. RW also present what they claim to be a corrected inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR, which gives 6 value estimates that differ markedly from those given by the standard formulation of RIVR. Bradley and Jarrell (2003) express concerns that are related to those of RW, and argue that the use of earnings or residual incomes in valuation models without inflation adjustment will result in under-valuation of firms. RIVR has a central role in the theory and practice of accounting-based valuation. The claim that the standard nominal historical cost-based formulation of the relationship is deficient with regard to its treatment of inflation, and that this results in the under-valuation of firms, is a serious one. In the next section, we present a number of inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR, and examine the claimed superiority of these formulations over the nominal historical cost-based formulation. 2. Residual income valuation using nominal and inflation-adjusted numbers In this section, we formulate versions of RIVR based on three inflation-adjusted residual income measures: (i) current cost residual income, (ii) real current cost residual income, being current cost residual income less a purchasing-power capital maintenance charge, and (iii) real current cost residual income expressed in real terms as at the valuation date. Current cost residual income and real current cost residual income are derived from income measures which appear in the seminal work of Edwards and Bell (1961), and which were required to be disclosed under the now-defunct Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33. The third measure, real current cost residual income as restated to real terms at the valuation date, is embedded within RW's inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR. The three inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR are presented in subsections 2.1, 2.2 and 2.3, respectively. For each inflation-adjusted 7 formulation, we show analytically that the inflation adjustment has no effect on the residual income-based value estimate. 2.1 Residual income and RIVR on a current cost basis The first inflation adjustment that we consider involves restating income and residual income to a current cost basis. We follow the tradition in the literature of assuming that current cost will normally be defined as the cost of replacing the firm's assets. 5 Nothing fundamental is involved in changing from historical cost to current cost. The current cost book value of shareholders' equity at time t+s is as follows: Btcs Atc s Dt s , (6) where Atc s is the cost at time t+s of replacing the non-monetary assets, based on the prices of those assets, and Btc s is the book value of equity at time t+s measured on a current cost basis. Current cost income for time t+s, denoted Yt c s , is as follows: Yt c s HCIEDt s DEPN tc s t s Atc s 1 Yt h s ADEPN t s t s Atc s 1 , (7) where DEPN tc s is the current cost depreciation charge, based on the replacement cost of the related assets, ADEPN t s is the adjustment required to convert the historical cost depreciation charge to the current cost depreciation charge (i.e., DEPN tcs DEPN ths ADEPNt s ), and t s is the rate of increase in the current cost of the firm's assets in period t+s. The item t s Atc s 1 , reflecting the periodic change in the current cost of the specific non-monetary assets, 8 is sometimes referred to in the inflation accounting literature as a 'holding gain' (Scapens, 1981, p. 61) or as a 'realizable cost saving' (Edwards and Bell, 1961, p. 94). Current cost residual income for time t+s, denoted RI tc s , is as follows: RI tc s Yt c s Re,t s Btc s 1 Yt h s ADEPN t s t s Atc s 1 Re,t s Btc s 1 . (8) Provided that forecasts of current cost income, current cost book value of equity and forecasts of dividends articulate in accordance with the current cost CSR given by (9), Btcs Btcs1 Ct s Ytcs , (9) the value of equity can be written as follows: c Et [ RI t s ] c c Vt Bt s s 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 (RIVR-C) Vt Vt h . RIVR-C is the current cost-based formulation of RIVR, where, Vtc is the value estimate in terms of the current cost book value of equity and forecasts of future current cost residual incomes. Vtc is equal to the value estimates, Vt and Vt h , given by PVR and RIVR-H, respectively. Properly applied, RIVR-H and RIVR-C must yield the same value estimate, since the accounting in each conforms to CSR. 2.2 Real current cost residual income The second inflation adjustment that we consider involves the subtraction from current cost income of a capital maintenance adjustment, to give real current cost income. This income 9 measure is described in Edwards and Bell (1961), and was required to be disclosed under Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33. The subtraction from this income measure of a real capital charge gives real current cost residual income. Real current cost income, denoted Y c ,real , is calculated by deducting from current cost income the amount by which opening equity needs to increase over the period in order for its beginning-of-period purchasing power to be maintained. This capital maintenance adjustment is calculated by reference to the rate of change in the general price level.6 Real current cost income can be represented as follows: Ytc,sreal Yt hs ADEPNt s t s Atcs1 pt s Btcs1 , (10) where pt s is the periodic rate of change in the general price level for period t+s. The capital maintenance adjustment in (10), pt s Btc s 1 , can be decomposed using (6) to give (i) a price level adjustment to the holding gain on assets and (ii) a gain resulting from the decline in the purchasing power of debt:7,8 Ytc,sreal Yt hs ADEPNt s pt s Dt s1 ( t s pt s ) Atcs1 . (11) The real current cost income measure in (10) breaches CSR.9 It is therefore not immediately obvious that a valuation model that uses the associated residual income measure will yield the same value estimate as models based on clean surplus residual income measures. Nevertheless, a formulation of RIVR based on real current cost residual incomes can be shown to be theoretically equivalent to a version based on nominal current cost residual incomes. This is so because nominal residual income contains an inflation component within the capital charge. The removal of this inflation component when the capital charge is restated to real terms exactly 10 cancels against the capital maintenance charge that is applied in arriving at real current cost income. Real current cost residual income and nominal current cost residual income are therefore identical, and so are the theoretical value estimates based on the two residual income measures. To establish this equivalence, note that subtraction of a real capital charge from the income measure in (11) gives real current cost residual income as follows: RI tc, real Yt c,sreal re,t s [ Btc s 1 (1 p t s )] s Yt h s ADEPN t s p t s Dt s 1 ( t s p t s ) Atc s 1 re,t s [ Btc s 1 (1 (12) p t s )] . where Btcs1 (1 pt s ) is the time t+s-1 (beginning-of-period) current cost book value of equity restated to express its purchasing power in terms of time t+s (end-of-period) money, and re,t s is the period t+s real cost of equity capital defined as follows: re,t s (1 Re,t s ) /(1 pt s ) 1 (13) ( Re,t s pt s ) /(1 pt s ) . Substitution of (13) into (12) gives: RI tc,real Yt h s ADEPN t s pt s Dt s 1 s ( t s pt s ) Atc s 1 ( Re,t s pt s ) Btc s 1 . (14) Since Btcs1 Atcs1 Dt s1 , the inflation adjustment to the residual income capital charge, pt s Btc s 1 , cancels exactly against the net of (i) the inflation adjustment to the holding gains on real assets, pt s Atc s 1 , and (ii) the gain from erosion of the purchasing power of debt capital pt s Dt s 1 . Expression (14) therefore collapses to RI tc,real Yt h s ADEPN t s t s Atc s 1 Re,t s Btc s 1 . s 11 (15) Since the right-hand side of (15) contains exactly the same elements as the right-hand side of (8), it follows that RI tc,real RI tcs . s (16) In other words, real current cost residual income is equal to nominal current cost residual income. From (16) and RIVR-C, the value of equity can be written as follows: Vt c ,real c , real E [ RI ] ts Btc s t s 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 (RIVR-CR) Vt Vt h Vt c . RIVR-CR is the real current cost residual income-based formulation of RIVR, where, Vt c,real is the value estimate in terms of the current cost book value of equity and forecasts of future real current cost residual incomes. Vt c,real is equal to the value estimates, Vt , Vt h and Vtc given by PVR, RIVR-H and RIVR-C, respectively. 2.3. Restatement of residual income to real terms as at the valuation date The third inflation adjustment that we consider involves restating real current cost residual income to real terms as at the valuation date, with an appropriate adjustment to the cost of capital applied to the residual income forecasts. This elaboration is embedded within the RW model. ,t Real residual income at time t+s stated in real terms at the valuation date t is denoted RI tc,real s and is defined as follows: 12 ,t RI tc,real s RI tc,real s s , (17) (1 pt k ) k 1 where p denotes the periodic rate of change in the general price level, as previously defined. The discount factor applicable to forecasts of this item is as follows: s s (1 re,t k ) k 1 (1 Re,t k ) k 1 s , (18) (1 pt k ) k 1 where re denotes the real cost of equity, as previously defined. Substitution of (17) and (18) into RIVR-CR enables the value of equity to be written as follows: Vt c ,real,t c , real,t E [ RI t s ] Btc s t s 1 (1 re,t k ) k 1 (RIVR-CRT) Vt Vt h Vt c Vt c ,real . RIVR-CRT is a formulation of RIVR in terms of real current cost residual incomes stated in real terms at the valuation date, t. Vtc,real,t , the value estimate within this formulation, is equal to the value estimates, Vt , Vt h , Vtc and Vt c,real given by PVR, RIVR-H, RIVR-C and RIVR-CR, respectively. 2.4 Summary We have now presented inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR based on current cost residual income, real current cost residual income, and real current cost residual income stated in real terms as at the valuation date. The formulations encompass inflation-adjusted income measures 13 which feature both in Edwards and Bell (1961) and in Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33, as well as the inflation-adjusted residual income measure which is embedded within the RW model. We have shown that the inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR are theoretically equivalent to the standard nominal historical cost-based formulation of RIVR, and are no more correct and no less correct than that formulation. Provided that CSR is maintained, there is no theoretical difference between the value estimate obtained from the use of nominal historical cost residual incomes and that obtained from the use of current cost residual incomes. Because of the compensating effects of the capital maintenance charge and the inflation adjustment to the residual income capital charge, the restatement of current cost residual incomes to real terms should have no effect either. Also, deflation of the real current cost residual incomes to real terms as at the valuation date, together with use of a real cost of equity rather than a nominal cost of equity, should have no effect. If the underlying forecasts have been prepared on a consistent and comparable basis, they should all lead to the same estimates of intrinsic value. Any differences that could arise must therefore be due to forecasting inconsistencies. After consideration of the RW model in Section 3, we present in Section 4 a numerical example which illustrates the equivalences that have been demonstrated in this section, and which illustrates forecasting inconsistencies that could cause differences between RIVR-H value estimates and those from inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR. 14 3. The Ritter-Warr (RW) model In this section we demonstrate that, with the exception of an insignificant difference that appears to result from an error in the derivation of the RW model, the RW model is simply a special case of RIVR-CRT. Expansion of the residual income-related term in RIVR-CRT, by substitution of (12) and (17) gives Vt c ,real,t Btc c h c r B Yt s ADEPN t s pt s Dt s 1 ( t s pt s ) At s 1 e ,t s t s 1 E s s s 1 s t s (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) k 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 . k 1 s s 1 (1 re,t k ) k 1 (19) The RW model contains a number of simplifying assumptions. First, the current cost depreciation adjustment is expected to remain constant in real terms10: s ADEPN t s ADEPN t (1 pt k ) s . k 1 (20) Second, the rate of holding gains is expected to remain equal to the rate of inflation: 11 t s pt s s . (21) The RW representation does not therefore allow for the re-distributive effects of inflation allowed by the real holding gains term, ( t s pt s ) Atcs1 , that appears in (12). Third, it is ,t assumed that, for s > 3, the rate of growth in RI tc,real , being real current cost residual income as s stated in real terms at the valuation date t, is expected to remain constant at the rate of g. Fourth, 15 the real cost of equity is assumed to be constant at the rate of re . Application of the RW assumptions to our expression (19) gives Vt c ,real,t Btc Yh p D E t t 1 ADEPN t t 1 t re Btc 1 pt 1 1 pt 1 1 re Yt h 2 pt 2 Dt 1 re Btc1 Et 2 ADEPN t 2 1 pt 1 (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) k 1 k 1 Yt h3 pt 3 Dt 2 re Btc 2 Et 3 ADEPN t 3 2 (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) k 1 k 1 k 1 (22) (1 re ) 2 (1 re ) 2 (re g ) . Without providing any formal analysis, RW claim the theoretically correct residual incomebased valuation model to be as follows (RW, pp. 38-39): Vt c ,real,t Btc Yh E t t 1 ADEPN t p t 1 Dt re Btc 1 p t 1 1 re Yt h 2 p t 2 Dt 1 re Btc1 Et 2 ADEPN t (1 p t 1 ) 1 p t 1 (1 p t k ) k 1 Yt h3 p t 3 Dt 2 re Btc 2 Et 3 ADEPN t 2 2 (1 p t k ) (1 pt k ) (1 pt k ) k 1 k 1 k 1 (23) (1 re ) 2 (1 re ) 2 (re g ) 16 . Expression (23) differs from (22) only in that the terms reflecting the inflation-related gain on 2 3 k 1 k 1 debt are greater by pt21 Dt /(1 pt 1 ) , pt22 Dt 1 / (1 pt k ) and pt23 Dt 2 / (1 pt k ) , respectively. This discrepancy appears to be due to an error in the RW model, which wrongly implies that the debt-related component of the capital maintenance charge in (11) and (19) is pt s Dt s 1 (1 pt s ) rather than pt s Dt s 1 , an overstatement of pt2s Dt s1 . To illustrate the nature of this error, suppose a firm owes $1,000 throughout a year when inflation is 5%. The amount required to maintain the purchasing power of the amount owing to the creditor is $50 (= 0.05 * $1,000), but RW measure the related adjustment to the real current cost income in (11) as $52.5 (= 0.05 * $1000 * 1.05), an overstatement of $2.5 (=0.052 * $1000). The impact of this additional squared inflation-rate term is likely to be empirically unimportant in most cases. We have shown that the RW model is essentially a special case of the formulation of RIVR in terms of real current cost residual income stated in real terms at the valuation date. We have previously shown that this formulation is theoretically equivalent to the standard historical cost residual income-based valuation model as given by RIVR-H. The RW model is therefore no more correct and, subject to an insignificant error, no less correct than the standard historical cost residual income-based valuation model. We may therefore conclude that we find no basis for RW's claims that the standard historical cost residual income-based valuation model must be adjusted to deal with inflation and that the RW inflation-adjusted residual income valuation model is theoretically more correct than the historical cost-based version. If the underlying forecasts have been prepared on a consistent and comparable basis, they should all lead to the 17 same estimates of intrinsic value. Any differences that could arise in empirical applications must therefore be due to forecasting inconsistencies. We consider this issue in the next section. 4. Potential problems is working with inflation adjusted formulations of RIVR In Section 2 we presented formulations of RIVR in terms of a number of inflation-adjusted residual income measures, and in Section 3 we showed that the RW model is a special case of the last of these formulations. We have shown that all of these inflation-adjusted formulations are theoretically equivalent to the standard nominal historical cost-based formulation of RIVR. We can find no justification for RW's claim that, for residual income models to produce accurate measures of true economic value, it is necessary to '… use real required returns, adjust depreciation for the distorting effects of inflation, and make adjustments for leverage-induced capital gains' (RW, pp. 59-60). Having demonstrated that there is no need to work with an inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR, we now highlight the possibility that there might be important practical disadvantages in working with such a formulation in a setting in which the raw accounting inputs to RIVR are conventionally stated in nominal historical cost terms. We note that International Accounting Standard No. 29 (International Accounting Standards Committee, 1994) recommends that, in hyperinflationary economies, financial statements should be stated in terms of the measuring unit current at the balance sheet date, and where this happens there may be practical advantages in working with inflation-adjusted numbers.12 However, in a setting in which accounting numbers and forecasts thereof are not generally prepared in inflationadjusted form, the unnecessary inflation adjustment of readily available nominal numbers is likely to introduce undesirable added complexity to the valuation procedure. We make this point 18 using two approaches. First, we use a numerical illustration of the equivalence of the value estimates given by PVR, RIVR-H, RIVR-C, RIVR-CR and RIVR-CRT. This example is a simplified one, but it allows us to illustrate a number of forecasting inconsistencies that can arise when implementing an inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR on the basis of inputs initially framed in nominal historical cost terms. Second, we explore analytically the relationship between growth in nominal historical cost residual incomes and current cost residual incomes. We argue that the potentially complicated nature of this relationship is likely to hinder the recasting of nominal forecasts of growth in inflation-adjusted terms. 4.1 A numerical illustration Table 1 sets out a numerical example which illustrates that, properly done, valuations based on PVR, RIVR-H, RIVR-C, RIVR-CR and RIVR-CRT all yield identical results. We then go on to illustrate potential forecasting inconsistencies that could give rise, even in this very simple setting, to differences between RIVR-H value estimates and value estimates from inflationadjusted formulations of RIVR. To this end, we include within the example a number of apparently short-lasting differences between the properties of historical cost- and current costbased accounting measures. In particular, the example includes the following features. First, both dividends and historical cost residual incomes grow at the constant rate of 5% after year 2 in perpetuity. As observed by Lundholm and O'Keefe (2001), it is not correct in general to assume that both items have the same constant post-horizon rate of growth, but this example is constructed such that growth in both items is equal after year 2. Second, current cost residual incomes do not grow at the same rate as dividends and historical cost residual incomes in years 19 1, 2 and 3, but they do grow at the same constant rate of 5% after year 3 in perpetuity. As illustrated by the example, it is not correct in general to assume that current cost residual incomes and historical cost residual incomes grow at the same rate, but this example is constructed such that growth in both items is equal after year 3. The effect of these growth patterns is that PVR and RIVR-H include a terminal value term reflecting flows from year 2 onward, and RIVR-C, RIVR-CR and RIVR-CRT include a terminal value term reflecting flows from year 3 onward. Third, the nominal cost of equity is 7% in year 1 and 10% thereafter. Fourth, the general inflation rate is 1% in year 1 and 3% thereafter. Fifth, the rate of current cost holding gains is not equal to the rate of general inflation in year 1 or year 2, but is equal to this rate from year 3 onwards (3%). Note that the general equivalence of the valuation approaches does not depend upon any of these features. Panel A gives the value estimates for PVR and RIVR-H, Panel B gives the estimate for RIVR-C, and Panel C gives those for RIVR-CR and RIVR-CRT. The value estimate given by each valuation method is equal to 192.5234. To aid understanding, we explain here the calculations for PVR, RIVR-H, RIVR-C and RIVR-CRT. The calculation for PVR is as follows: V0 E0 [C1 ] E0 [C 2 ] (1 Re,1 ) (1 Re,1 )( Re, 2 G3h ) 6.0000 10.0000 1.07 (1.07)(. 10 .05) 5.6075 186.9159 192.5234 , where G3h is the rate of post-horizon (i.e.: post-year 2) growth in both historical cost residual incomes and dividends. The calculation for RIVR-H is as follows: 20 V0h B0h E0 [ RI 1h ] E0 [ RI 2h ] (1 Re,1 ) (1 Re,1 )( Re, 2 G 3h ) 60.0000 15.0000 (.07 * 60.0000) 13.4500 (.10 * 69.0000) 1.07 (1.07)(.10 .05) 60.0000 10.0935 122.4299 192.5234. The calculation for RIVR-C is as follows: V0c B0c E 0 [ RI 1c ] E 0 [ RI 2c ] E 0 [ RI 3c ] (1 Re,1 ) (1 Re,1 )(1 Re, 2 ) (1 Re,1 )(1 Re, 2 )( Re,3 G c ) 4 21.0000 (.07 * 80.0000) 16.0625 (.10 * 95.0000) 1.07 (1.07)(1.10) 15.5531 (.10 *101.0625) (1.07)(1.10)(. 10 .05) 80.0000 80.0000 14.3925 5.5756 92.5553 192.5234 , where G 4c is the rate of post-horizon (i.e.: post-year 3) growth in current cost residual incomes. The calculation for RIVR-CRT, written in the form of expression (19) which links directly with the RW model, is as follows: 21 V0c ,real,0 B0c Y1h ADEPN1 p1 D0 ( 1 p1 ) A0c E0 re,1 B0c 1 p1 1 p1 1 p1 1 p1 1 re,1 c ADEPN 2 Y2h p 2 D1 ( 2 p 2 ) A1c re, 2 B1 E0 2 2 2 2 1 p1 (1 p k ) (1 p k ) (1 p k ) ( 1 p ) k k 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 2 (1 re,k ) k 1 re,3 B2c ADEPN 3 Y3h p 3 D2 ( 3 p3 ) A2c E0 3 3 3 3 2 (1 p k ) (1 p k ) (1 p k ) (1 p k ) (1 p k ) k 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 2 . (1 re,k )( re,3 g 4 ) k 1 80.0000 8.0000 .01 * 120.0000 15.0000 (12.0000 10.0000) (.01 * 40.0000) 120.0000 (.059406 * 80.0000) 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.01 1.059406 5.2125 .03 * 135.0000 (13.5000 10.9000) (.03 * 40.0000) 135.0000 13.4500 .067961 * 95.0000 (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) 1.01 (1.059406)(1.067961) (14.3063 11.4450) (.03 * 42.0000) (.03 .03) * 143.0625 .067961 * 101.0625 14.1225 2 (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.059406)(1.067961)(. 067961 .019417) 80.0000 14.3925 5.5756 92.5553 192.5234 , where g 4 is the rate of post-horizon (i.e.: post-year 3) growth in real current cost residual incomes as expressed in real terms at the valuation date. 22 This example shows that proper application of the various valuation approaches to internally consistent inputs will yield identical value estimates. Our prime purpose in presenting this example is to illustrate errors that could be made in applying an inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR, and which could result in erroneous differences between value estimates obtained from the historical cost and inflation-adjusted formulations of RIVR. Examples of possible errors are considered below. Incorrect assumption that current cost residual income grows at the same rate as historical cost residual income in year 3. In the example, the growth rate in historical cost residual income is constant at 5% after year 2. The growth rate in nominal and real current cost residual income is -17% in year 3 and is constant at 5% after year 3. The growth rates in real current cost residual income as stated in real terms at the valuation date are -19.4175% (=(1-0.17)/(1+0.03)-1) for year 3 and 1.9417% (=(1+0.05)/(1+0.03)-1) after year 3. Consider the effect of an erroneous assumption that, after year 2, nominal (and real) current cost residual incomes are expected to grow at the same rate as historical cost residual incomes, and are therefore expected to grow at the constant rate of 5% after year 2. (Consistent with this, real current cost residual incomes as stated in real terms at the valuation date are now expected to grow at the rate of 1.9417% after year 2.) This erroneous assumption gives a value estimate of 217.0561. (See the Appendix for detailed calculations). The apparently innocuous assumption that the year 3 rate of growth in nominal historical cost residual incomes can be applied to current cost residual incomes has given rise to a value estimate that is about 12.7% higher than the correct value estimate of 192.5234 calculated above. In subsection 4.2, we consider more formally the potentially complicated nature of the 23 relationship between the rates of growth in nominal historical cost residual incomes and current cost residual incomes, and highlight further the danger of assuming that the rates of growth are equal. Inconsistency between the nominal and real rates for the cost of equity and the post-horizon growth rate. Another potential pitfall is to make the apparently innocuous assumption that the real cost of equity and the real rate of growth in post-horizon flows can be approximated by subtracting the inflation rate from the nominal cost of equity and the nominal growth rate, respectively. This yields estimated real costs of equity of 6% in year 1 and 7% thereafter (instead of 5.9406% and 6.7961%), and an estimated real post-horizon growth rate in real current cost residual incomes of 2% (instead of 1.9417%). The detailed calculations given in the Appendix show that these apparently innocuous approximations within RIVR-CRT yield an incorrect value estimate of 185.9588, which is about 3.4% less than the correct value estimate of 192.5234. Inconsistency (lack of articulation) between current cost holding gains, current cost depreciation and movements in the current cost book value of assets. It should be noted that the proper application of a formulation of RIVR employing current cost income should use forecasts that comply with the current cost version of CSR. This requires that changes in successive current cost balance sheet values of equity should articulate with periodic dividends and current cost incomes, inclusive of both holding gains and current cost depreciation. Failure to obey this articulation will result in value estimates that erroneously differ from those given by RIVR-H. The complicated nature of the required articulation, even within our simplified example, illustrates how easy it would be to fall into such error. 24 In this subsection, by reference to a numerical example we have illustrated some of the complications and errors that might result from attempts to refashion nominal historical costbased accounting data to a form appropriate for use within an inflation-adjusted formulation of RIVR. In the next subsection, we use a formal model of the relationship between growth in nominal historical cost residual incomes and current cost residual incomes to emphasise this point. 4.2 A model of the relationship between growth in nominal historical cost residual incomes and growth in current cost residual incomes We now explore analytically, in a simplified setting, the relationship between growth in historical cost residual incomes and growth in current cost residual incomes (real or nominal). 13 The setting is as follows. An all-equity firm is created at time t, with an initial contribution of equity capital, which is invested in its entirety in operating assets (i.e: Bth Ath ). It is expected that the firm will generate a constant pre-depreciation accounting rate of return of , that reducing balance depreciation at the rate d (where d ) will be applied, that the time t+s nominal historical cost pre-tax income of At s 1 ( d ) will be taxed at the constant rate of , that the dividend payout ratio will remain constant at , that all retained earnings will be invested in operating assets, and that the nominal cost of equity will remain constant at Re . Under these assumptions, Et [ RI th s ] Ath (1 G h ) s 1 (( d )(1 ) Re ) , (24) where G h ( d )(1 )(1 ) is the constant rate of growth in both the historical cost book value of equity and the historical cost residual income. 25 Now consider the situation if expectations are framed in terms of current cost residual incomes, where the assumed constant rate of holding gains is and where the depreciation rate d is now applied to the current cost of assets. Current cost residual income, both nominal and real, is expected to evolve as follows: RI tc1 Ath (( d )(1 ) Re ) RI tc 2 Ath (1 G h )(( d )(1 ) Re ) Ath ( d Re ) RI tc3 Ath (1 G h ) 2 (( d )(1 ) Re ) Ath [(1 G h ) (1 d )]( d Re ) RI tc 4 Ath (1 G h ) 3 (( d )(1 ) Re ) Ath [(1 G h ) 2 (1 G h )(1 d ) (1 d ) 2 ]( d Re ) etc..... (25) Generalising, Et [ RI tc s ] Ath (1 G h ) s 1 (( d )(1 ) Re ) (1 G h ) s 1 (1 d ) s 1 Ath ( d Re ) . h ( 1 G ) ( 1 d ) (26) As s increases, the first term on the right-hand side of (26) grows at the constant rate of G h , but the second term grows at the more complex time-varying rate of: (1 G h ) s 1 (1 d ) s 1 1 . (1 G h ) s 2 (1 d ) s 2 (27) For G h d , the growth rate given by (27) asymptotes to G h , and the overall growth rate in current cost residual income asymptotes to G h ; for G h d , by L'Hospital's rule, the term in square brackets in (26) reduces in the limit to ( s 1)(1 G h ) s 2 , and the growth rate in current cost residual income asymptotes to G h ; for G h d , the growth rate given by (27) 26 asymptotes to d , and the overall growth rate in current cost residual income also asymptotes to d . These asymptotic growth rates have an intuitive interpretation. If growth in nominal historical cost residual income is greater than or equal to the rate of current cost holding gains (less depreciation), then the nominal historical cost growth rate dominates; in the event that growth in nominal historical cost residual income is less than the rate of current cost holding gains (less depreciation), then the holding gain term (net of depreciation) dominates. Note, however, that these are rates to which current cost residual income growth will asymptote in the long term, and it is not correct in general to use as the rate of growth in current cost residual incomes the rate of growth in forecasts of historical cost residual incomes, or a simple transform thereof. Table 2 illustrates the patterns of current cost residual income growth in the presence of constant residual income growth for two different rates of current cost holding gains, : 1% (0.01) and 5% (0.05). Other parameters are as follows: A th = 100, = 0.40, d = 0.20, = 0.25, = 0.60, and the nominal cost of equity, Re , is 0.10. The parameters , d, , and give rise to a rate of growth in historical cost residual income of 6% (0.06): G h ( d )(1 )(1 ) (0.40 0.20)(1 0.25)(1 0.60) 0.06 . For = 0.01, the growth rate in current cost residual income reaches 0.036 after 5 years, 0.053 after 10 years, and 0.058 after 15 years. In contrast, where takes a value of 0.05, which is much closer to that of G h , the growth in current cost residual income takes a lot longer to approximate to the rate of growth in historical cost residual income. Under this circumstance, the 27 growth rate in current cost residual income is -0.031 after 5 years, 0.018 after 10 years, and 0.044 after 15 years. As can be seen from this simplified illustration, the theoretical link between growth in historical cost residual income and growth in its current cost counterpart can be complex. If the valuer of a company has access to a readily available estimate of growth in historical cost residual incomes, the unnecessary and potentially complex task of correctly recasting this estimate to a current cost basis is likely to create significant scope for error. 4.3 Summary In previous sections, we have demonstrated that there is no need to work with an inflationadjusted formulation of RIVR. In this section, using both a numerical example and a model of the relationship between growth in historical cost and current cost residual incomes, we have illustrated the potentially complicated nature of adjustments that have to be made in transforming the nominal historical cost-based inputs to RIVR into a form that could be used in inflationadjusted formulations of RIVR. On the basis of our analysis, we conclude that inflation adjustment of RIVR is not only unnecessary, but is a likely source of complexity and error. 5. Conclusion Inflation can have marked effects on both the appearance and the reality of corporate profitability. An issue that has exercised many accountants and economists over the years is whether these effects are of such a nature and magnitude as to require the wholesale transformation of traditional accounting data before reliable inferences can be drawn. Until 28 recently, the literature on accounting-based valuation models has been silent on the questions of whether and how such models should be written in inflation-adjusted form. However, a recent study by Ritter and Warr (2002) claims that failure to deal with inflation within RIVR can lead to under-valuation of firms, a point that has been echoed in Bradley and Jarrell (2003). Our paper explores the issue of whether it is indeed necessary to adjust RIVR in order to deal properly with inflation. We find that formulations of the RIVR based on a number of inflation-adjusted income measures from prior literature, including a formulation of which the Ritter and Warr (2002) model is a special case, are each no more correct and no less correct than the standard formulation based on nominal historical cost residual incomes. We have therefore established that inflation adjustment of RIVR, as advocated by Ritter and Warr (2002) is unnecessary. Any theoretical superiority claimed for the inflation-adjusted residual income valuation model over the standard nominal historical cost formulation, due for example to inclusion of gains from debt in periods of inflation, is therefore illusory. Any case for using inflation-adjusted forecasts must rest on the practical ground that such forecasts are easier to obtain or more reliable or both. Only in economies experiencing high inflation are inflation-adjusted income forecasts likely to be readily available. As we have illustrated, in other settings the inflation adjustment of readily available forecasts of nominal accounting numbers may well introduce unnecessary and undesirable complexity, and scope for error. We emphasise that we do not argue that the effects of inflation should be ignored in framing forecasts for use in RIVR by, for example, assuming zero growth for flows that are expected to grow in line with inflation. The estimation of post-horizon residual income growth 29 should take account not only of matters related to competitive advantage, but also of the impact of inflation on expectations regarding accounting numbers, under whatever convention those numbers are constructed. However, we emphasis that, as long as forecast flows are represented in a consistent manner, a nominal historical cost formulation of RIVR is as correct as an inflationadjusted formulation. 30 Appendix Calculations relating to numerical example in Section 4 Incorrect assumption that current cost residual income grows at the same rate as historical cost residual income in year 3. Consider the effect of an incorrect assumption that current cost residual incomes (and real current cost residual incomes) grow at the constant rate of 5% after year 2. This gives an incorrect value estimate of 217.0561, about 12.7% greater than the correct estimate of 192.5234: V0c 80.0000 21.0000 (.07 * 80.0000) 16.0625 (.10 * 95.0000) 1.07 (1.07)(.10 .05) 80.0000 14.3925 122.6636 217.0561. The erroneous assumption that nominal (and real) current cost residual incomes grow at the constant rate of 5% after year 2 is equivalent to assuming that real current cost residual incomes as stated in real terms at the valuation date grow at the rate of 1.9417% after year 2. This representation, based on expression (19), gives the same value estimate: V0c ,real,0 80.0000 8.0000 .01 * 120.0000 15.0000 (12.0000 10.0000) (.01 * 40.0000) 120.0000 (.059406 * 80.0000) 1 . 01 1 . 01 1 . 01 1 . 01 1.059406 5.2125 .03 * 135.0000 (13.5000 10.9000) (.03 * 40.0000) 135.0000 13.4500 .067961 * 95.0000 (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) 1.01 (1.059406)(. 067961 .019417) 80.0000 14.3925 122.6636 217.0561 31 Inconsistency between the nominal and real rates for the cost of equity and the post-horizon growth rate. The assumption that the real cost of equity and the real rate of growth in post-horizon flows can be approximated by subtracting the inflation rate from the nominal cost of equity and the nominal growth rate, respectively, yields estimated real costs of equity of 6% in year 1 and 7% thereafter (instead of 5.9406% and 6.7961%), and an estimated real post-horizon growth rate in real current cost residual incomes of 2% (instead of 1.9417%). Use of these apparently innocuous approximations within RIVR-CRT yields an incorrect value estimate of 185.9588, which is about 3.4% less than the correct value estimate of 192.5234. The calculation is as follows, based on expression (19): V0c ,real,0 80.0000 8 .01 * 120.0000 15.0000 (12.0000 10.0000) (.01 * 40.0000) 120 (.06 * 80.0000) 1 . 01 1 . 01 1 . 01 1 . 01 1.06 5.2125 .03 * 135.0000 (13.5000 10.9000) (.03 * 40.0000) 135.0000 13.4500 .07 * 95.0000 (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) 1.01 (1.06)(1.07) (14.3063 11.4450) (.03 * 42.0000) (.03 .03) * 143.0625 .07 * 101.0625 14.1225 2 (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.01)(1.03) 2 (1.06)(1.07)(. 07 .02) 80.0000 14.3396 5.3928 86.2264 185.9588 . 32 Notes 1 This condition is exactly met if the firm is expected to be wound up at some finite date in the future, since after that date book value is zero. 2 Our exposition allows the cost of equity to vary over time. In practical applications, it is commonly assumed that the cost of equity is constant, i.e., its term structure is flat. 3 We assume the firm's balance sheets contain only depreciable plant and equipment financed by debt and equity, and this assumption is also made by RW. The assumption is less restrictive than appearances might suggest. Assets such as inventories and real estate, which are not normally subject to depreciation, can be thought of as special forms of depreciable asset. For such assets, the depreciation rate can be taken to be zero until the asset is sold or otherwise disposed of, at which time the depreciation rate is 100%. Likewise, a typical firm will have significant monetary liabilities other than interest-bearing debt (notably amounts owed to suppliers); it will also have monetary assets, such as cash balances and trade credit extended to customers. The concept of debt must therefore be expanded to include monetary working capital items, with the rate of interest on these items being set equal to zero. 4 This treatment is in line with that required by all of the inflation accounting standards that have appeared in Anglo-Saxon countries, including Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33. An alternative way of motivating this treatment is to assume that all debt is issued on a floating-rate basis. 5 This assumption is also made by RW. It should be noted however that all the arguments made in this paper would apply equally to other ways of measuring changes in the value of a firm's assets, such as by reference to realizable proceeds. 33 6 Further details on the real current cost income measure are provided in Edwards and Bell (1961, chapter 8), Scapens (1981, chapter 6) and Edwards, Kay and Mayer (1987, chapter 5). The now defunct Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33 (Financial Accounting Standards Board, 1979) required real current cost income to be presented as supplementary information within U.S. financial statements. 7 The terms on the right-hand side of expression (11) correspond to items in the illustration appearing in Appendix A of Schedule A of Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33. The first two terms taken together correspond to the 'loss from continuing operations adjusted for changes in specific prices'. (In the illustration given in the standard, current cost income is negative.) The third term corresponds to the 'gain from decline in purchasing power of net amounts owed'. The fourth term corresponds to the 'increase in specific prices (current cost) of inventories and property, plant, and equipment held during the year' less the 'effect of increase in general price level' in respect of those items. 8 Of course, any anticipated decline in the purchasing power of money will be reflected in interest charged on debt, and deducted as an expense in arriving at Yt h s . 9 This is so because the last term, pt s Btc s 1 , is not reflected in the change in book value between time t+s-1 and time t+s. 10 The assumption that the extra depreciation charge is expected to increase at the general rate of inflation is a restrictive one. A set of circumstances under which it would hold is as follows. First, the firm is in steady state with a seasoned stock of identical depreciable assets of varying vintage such that the annual outlay on replacement is equal to the current cost depreciation. (The 34 method used to depreciate the assets is of no consequence.) Second, the rate of change in the current replacement cost of the assets remains equal to the (constant) rate of general inflation. If inflation were time-varying and current cost depreciation increased in step with inflation, its historical cost counterpart would not do so, and neither would the extra depreciation charge (the difference between the two). 11 This is consistent with RW's assumption that the extra depreciation charge (ADEPN) rises in line with general inflation. 12 However, even in a hyperinflationary economy, RIVR calculations based on nominal historical cost residual incomes should, if done properly, yield the same value estimates as those obtained using inflation-adjusted residual incomes. 13 Recall from Section 2 that real current cost residual income, RI c,real , is equal to nominal current cost residual income RI c . References Bradley, M. and G. Jarrell. (2003). "Inflation and the constant growth valuation model: A clarification." Working Paper, Duke University and University of Rochester. Edwards, E. and P. Bell. (1961). The Theory and Measurement of Business Income, University of California Press. Edwards, J., Kay, J. and C. Mayer. (1987). The Economic Analysis of Accounting Profitability, Oxford University Press. Financial Accounting Standards Board. (1979). Statement of Financial Accounting Standards No. 33: Financial Reporting and Changing Prices. Francis, J., P. Olsson and D. Oswald. (2000). "Comparing the accuracy and explainability of dividend, free cash flow, and abnormal earnings equity value estimates." Journal of Accounting Research 38, 45-70. Frankel, R. and C. Lee. (1998). "Accounting valuation, market expectation and cross-sectional stock returns." Journal of Accounting and Economics 25, 283-319. International Accounting Standards Committee. (1994). International Accounting Standard No. 29: Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies. Lee, C., J. Myers and B. Swaminathan. (1999). "What is the intrinsic value of the Dow?" Journal of Finance 54, 1693-1741. Lundholm, R. and T. O'Keefe. (2001). "Reconciling Value Estimates from the Discounted Cash Flow Model and the Residual Income Model." Contemporary Accounting Research, 18, 331-335. 36 Ritter, J., and R. Warr. (2002). "The decline of inflation and the bull market of 1982-1999." Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 37, 29-61. Scapens, R. (1981). Accounting in an Inflationary Environment, 2nd edition, Macmillan. 37 Table 1 Numerical example of the equivalence of formulations of RIVR based on historical cost and inflation-adjusted residual income measures This example illustrates the consistency between valuation approaches based on dividends, historical cost residual incomes, and various inflation adjusted residual income measures. In this example, both dividends and historical cost residual incomes grow at the constant rate of 5% after year 2. Current cost residual incomes grow at this rate after year 3, but not in year 3. The cost of equity and inflation vary from year 1 to year 2, but each remains constant thereafter. These features are incorporated to facilitate exposition, and the general equivalence of the approaches does not depend upon them. Panel A: Value estimates based on dividends and historical cost (HC) residual incomes (PVR and RIVR-H) Year 0 Income statement HC income (excluding depreciation) (1) HC depreciation (10%) (2) HC net income Dividend HC retained earnings Balance sheet HC Assets Debt HC Equity Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 - 25.0000 -10.0000 15.0000 -6.0000 9.0000 24.3500 -10.9000 13.4500 -10.0000 3.4500 25.5675 -11.4450 14.1225 -10.5000 3.6225 26.8459 -12.0173 14.8286 -11.0250 3.8036 100.0000 40.0000 60.0000 109.0000 40.0000 69.0000 114.4500 42.0000 72.4500 120.1725 44.1000 76.0725 126.1811 46.3050 79.8761 Cost of equity (3) - 0.07 0.10 0.10 0.10 Growth in dividends Present value at year 0 of dividends - 5.6075 0.6667 186.9159 (Terminal value) (6) 0.0500 0.0500 HC capital charge (4) HC residual income Growth in HC residual incomes (5) Present value at year 0 of HC residual incomes - 4.2000 10.8000 10.0935 6.9000 6.5500 -0.3935 122.4299 (Terminal value) (6) 7.2450 6.8775 0.0500 38 Year 0 Equity TOTAL 192.5234 (PVR) 7.6072 7.2214 0.0500 60.0000 192.5234 (RIVR-H) 39 Table 1 Numerical example of the equivalence of formulations of RIVR based on historical cost and inflation-adjusted residual income measures Panel B: Value estimate based on current cost (CC) residual incomes (RIVR-C) Year 0 Income statement HC income (excluding depreciation) (1) CC depreciation (1) (2) CC holding gain (8) CC net income Dividend CC retained earnings Balance Sheet CC Assets Debt CC Equity Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 - 25.0000 -12.0000 8.000 21.0000 -6.0000 15.0000 24.3500 -13.5000 5.2125 16.0625 -10.0000 6.0625 25.5675 -14.3063 4.2919 15.5531 -10.5000 5.0531 26.8459 -15.0216 4.5065 16.3308 -11.0250 5.3058 120.0000 40.0000 80.0000 135.0000 40.0000 95.0000 143.0625 42.0000 101.0625 150.2156 44.1000 106.1156 157.7264 46.3050 111.4214 - Cost of equity (3) - .07 .10 .10 .10 CC capital charge (4) CC residual income Growth in CC residual incomes (7) Present value at year 0 of CC residual incomes - 5.6000 15.4000 14.3925 9.5000 6.5625 -0.5739 5.5756 10.1062 5.4469 -0.1700 92.5553 (Terminal value) (6) 10.6116 5.7192 0.0500 40 Year 0 Equity TOTAL 80.0000 192.5234 (RIVR-C) Table 1 Numerical example of the equivalence of formulations of RIVR based on historical cost and inflation-adjusted residual income measures Panel C: Value estimates for real current cost (CC) residual incomes (RIVR-CR and RIVR-CRT) Year 0 Income Statement HC income (excluding depreciation) (1) CC depreciation (1) (2) CC holding gain (8) Capital maintenance charge: Assets (9) Capital maintenance charge: Debt (9) Real CC net income Dividend Real CC retained earnings (11) Balance Sheet CC Assets Debt CC Equity - 120.0000 40.0000 80.0000 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 25.0000 -12.0000 8.000 -1.2000 0.4000 20.2000 -6.0000 14.2000 24.3500 -13.5000 5.2125 -4.0500 1.2000 13.2125 -10.0000 3.2125 25.5675 -14.3063 4.2919 -4.2919 1.2600 12.5212 -10.5000 2.0212 26.8459 -15.0216 4.5065 -4.5065 1.3230 13.1473 -11.0250 2.1223 135.0000 40.0000 95.0000 143.0625 42.0000 101.0625 150.2156 44.1000 106.1156 157.7264 46.3050 111.4214 Nominal cost of equity (3) General Inflation rate Real cost of equity (3) - .07 .01 .059406 .10 .03 .067961 .10 .03 .067961 .10 .03 .067961 Base for real CC capital charge (4) Real CC capital charge (4) Real CC residual income Growth in real CC residual income Present value of real CC residual incomes - 80.8000 4.8000 15.4000 14.3925 97.8500 6.6500 6.5625 -0.5739 5.5756 109.2991 7.4281 5.7192 0.0500 Real CC residual income in real terms as at year 0 (10) Growth in real CC residual income in real terms as at year 0 Present value of real CC residual incomes in real terms as at year 0 - 15.2475 6.3083 104.0944 7.0743 5.4469 -0.1700 92.5553 (Terminal value) (6) 5.0834 -0.586273 -0.194175 0.019417 5.5756 92.5553 (Terminal value) (6) - 14.3925 41 Year 0 equity TOTAL 80.0000 192.5234 (RIVR-CR) 80.0000 192.5234 (RIVR-CRT) 5.1821 Notes to Table 1: 1. HC denotes historical cost. CC denotes current cost. 2. Depreciation is at the rate of 10% on a reducing balance basis, applied to the opening net book value of assets. 3. The nominal cost of equity is allowed to vary between years 1 and 2, and remains constant at 10% from year 2 onwards. The real costs of equity for years 1 and 2, based on the inflation rates for years 1 and 2 of 1% and 3%, are calculated as follows: ((1.07)/(1.01)) - 1 = 0.059406; ((1.10)/(1.03)) - 1 = 0.067961. 4. The historical cost capital charge is calculated by applying the cost of equity for the year to the opening historical cost book value of equity for the year. For example, the capital charge for year 1 is 0.07 * 60.0000 = 4.2000. The current cost capital charge is calculated by applying the cost of equity for the year to the opening current cost book value of equity for the year. For example, the capital charge for year 1 is 0.07 * 80.0000 = 5.6000. The real current cost capital charge is calculated by applying the real cost of equity for the year to the opening current cost book value of equity as augmented at the rate of inflation for the year. For example, the capital charge for year 1 is 0.059406*(80.0000 * 1.01) = 0.059406* 80.8000 = 4.8000. 5. It is not true in general that the rate of growth in historical cost residual incomes is equal to that in dividends. This example is constructed such that the two items grow at the same rate after year 2. 6. All terminal value calculations reflect expected growth at a constant rate in perpetuity. The terminal value of dividends is calculated as follows: [10.0000/(0.10-0.05)]/1.07 = 186.9159. The terminal value of nominal historical cost residual incomes is calculated as follows: [6.5500/(0.10-0.05)]/1.07 = 122.4299. The terminal value of current cost residual incomes is calculated as follows: [5.4469/(0.10-0.05)]/[(1.07)(1.10)] = 92.5553. The same calculation applies for the terminal value of real current cost residual incomes, since nominal and real current cost residual incomes are identical to each other. The terminal value of real residual incomes as stated in real terms at the valuation date is calculated as follows: [5.0834/(.067961-0.019417)]/[(1.059406)(1.067961)] = 92.5553. 7. It is not true in general that the rate of growth in current cost residual incomes is equal to that of historical cost residual incomes. This example is constructed such that the two items grow at the same rate after year 3. 8. In years 1 and 2, the current cost holding gains do not accrue at the rate of general inflation. From year 3 onwards, they accrue at the general rate of inflation (=3%). The year 3 holding gain is 3% of 143.0625 = 4.2919. 9. The capital maintenance charges are calculated by applying the general rate of inflation for the period to the beginning-of-period balances of the items in question. 10. The real CC residual income in real terms as at year 0 is calculated by dividing by the cumulative effect of inflation. For example, the figure for year 2 is calculated as follows: 6.5625/(1.01)(1.03) = 6.3083. 11. Note that, because of the capital maintenance charge, real current cost retained earnings is not equal to the periodic change in the book value of equity. 42 Table 2 Illustration of patterns of growth in nominal historical cost residual income and current cost residual income Year t+1 t+2 t+3 t+4 t+5 t+6 t+7 t+8 t+9 t+10 t+11 t+12 t+13 t+14 t+15 Nominal historical cost residual income Level Growth 5.000 5.300 .060 5.618 .060 5.955 .060 6.312 .060 6.691 .060 7.093 .060 7.518 .060 7.969 .060 8.447 .060 8.954 .060 9.491 .060 10.061 .060 10.665 .060 11.305 .060 Current cost residual income (holding gain rate =1%) Level Growth 6.000 6.070 .012 6.199 .021 6.381 .029 6.610 .036 6.881 .041 7.193 .045 7.543 .049 7.929 .051 8.351 .053 8.809 .055 9.302 .056 9.832 .057 10.398 .058 11.003 .058 43 Current cost residual income (holding gain rate =5%) Level Growth 10.000 9.350 -0.065 8.849 -0.054 8.476 -0.042 8.217 -0.031 8.058 -0.019 7.987 -0.009 7.994 0.001 8.073 0.010 8.217 0.018 8.421 0.025 8.680 0.031 8.991 0.036 9.353 0.040 9.763 0.044 Note to Table 2: This table illustrates the behaviour of growth in historical cost residual incomes ( RI h ) and in current cost residual incomes ( RI c ), in accordance with the following generating processes described in the text: Et [ RI th s ] Ath (1 G h ) s 1 (( d )(1 ) Re ) (24) (1 G h ) s 1 (1 d ) s 1 Et [ RI tc s ] Ath (1 G h ) s 1 (( d )(1 ) Re ) Ath (26) ( d Re ) . h (1 G ) (1 d ) As described in the text, the setting is as follows. An all-equity firm is created at time t, with an initial contribution of equity capital of Ath (=100), which is invested in its entirety in operating assets. The firm generates a constant pre-depreciation accounting rate of return of (=0.40), reducing balance depreciation is charged at the rate d (=0.20), historical cost pre-tax income is taxed at the rate of (=0.25), the dividend payout ratio is (=0.60), all retained earnings are invested in operating assets, and the nominal cost of equity is constant at Re (=0.10). Two rates of current cost holding gains, , are considered: 0.01 (1%) and 0.05 (5%). The rate of growth in historical cost residual incomes, G h , is as follows: G h ( d )(1 )(1 ) (0.40 0.20)(1 0.25)(1 0.60) 0.06 . 44