DEDICATING NEW REAL ESTATE TRANSFER TAXES FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY

advertisement

DEDICATING NEW REAL

ESTATE TRANSFER TAXES

FOR ENERGY EFFICIENCY

A REVENUE OPTION FOR SCALING UP

GREEN RETROFIT PROGRAMS

T. William Lester

Assistant Professor

Department of City and Regional Planning

University of North Carolina, Chapel Hill twlester@unc.edu

Outline

Motivation

Design of an Energy Efficiency Transfer Tax (EETT)

Implementation and political feasibility

How to model net impacts?

Quantitative Exercise from NC

Findings from IMPLAN

Context and conclusion

Motivation

Huge potential of energy efficiency

Residential structures consume 22% of all energy (EIA, 2008)

Retrofitting existing structure essential to reduced energy use

What are residential retrofit measures?

HVAC replacement

Windows/Doors

Appliances/Lighting

Weatherization

Potential to save 40% on energy bills from retrofit (McKinsey, 2009)

Most policies offer “carrots”

Utility rebates

Federal Tax credits (e.g. $500 down from $1,500 under ARRA)

…..Failure to achieve critical mass

Historically high unemployment

9.1% overall (May 2011)

16.3% in construction sector (May 2011)

Background

We may need to start using more “sticks”

Real Estate Transfer Taxes (document stamps)

One of the oldest forms of taxation

Originally a federal tax, enacted in 1921

Repealed in 1965, but devolved

Currently 37 states have some level of transfer tax

Ranges from 0.1 (CO) to 2.2 percent (DC) of assessed value

Policy Design: An Energy Efficiency

Transfer Tax

Level: $25 per $1,000 of assessed valuation, or 2.5%

Home buyers liable

Immediately rebated when a) audit and b) qualifying residential retrofit activities completed

Apply to existing homes built before 2000.

Energy Star homes exempt

Creates seller incentive

Pay or Play

Residual rebates apply to existing LIEE program funds

Pros: Progressive and proportional

Cons: May distort fragile housing market

Implementation and political feasibility

Option 1: Traditional Transfer Tax

Collected at time of purchase (i.e. on closing statement)

County recorder of deeds and state LIEE agency

Benefits: Follows existing policy infrastructure

Pitfalls: Lenders may balk at extra closing costs

Option 2: “Synthetic Tax”

Off statement

Administered through income tax code

2 years to complete the work, or pay the tax

More politically feasible

Will this policy create net new jobs?

P d

P

P s

A. Revenue for EE

(from consumer surplus)

B. Revenue for EE

(from producer surplus)

δ =Deadweight loss of tax

Q ’ Q

What to measure

Positive

Investment dollars for construction and energy audits

Energy savings

Negative

Behavioral response in housing market (i.e. price elasticity)

Reduced household spending

Falling demand for energy production

Calculating EE Investment Level: NC

Factor

A. Number of existing home sales in 2011

B. Share of existing homes sold built <2000

C. Average Price of Existing Homes in NC

D. Energy Efficiency Transfer Tax Rate

E. Behavioral Response to EETT increase

(price elasticity of -0.8)

F. Total estimated quantity sold subject to EETT

G. Estimated EETT Tax per home sold

H. Total Investment Level

Value

127,182

60.49%

$203,071

2.5%

-2.0%

75,394

$5,077

$382,757,075

Calculating Energy Savings

Factor

Average annual household expenditures on electricity and gas in NC

Energy Efficiency Transfer Tax Due on Typical Home

Less $500 Federal Tax Credit

Assumed Energy Efficiency Improvement Level

10%

20%

30%

40% (McKinsey, 2009)

50%

Estimated Post-Project Annual Energy Costs/Household

Annual Savings Per Household

Aggregate Energy Savings

Value

$ 3,014

$ 5,077

$ 4,577

Pay Back Period years

15.19

7.59

5.06

3.80

3.04

$1,808

$1,206

$90,894,698

How is EETT paid for?

Summary of IMPLAN Model Inputs

Activities in Scenario 1: Financing Available Activities in Scenario 2: No Financing

Increase demand in construction and energy auditor sectors by $382M.

Decrease in household spending of

$58M to account for net present value of interest payments only, paid over five years.

Decrease in commodity demand of

$90.8M in electricity and natural gas.

Increase demand in construction and energy auditor sectors by $382M.

Increase in household spending of

$90.8M due to energy savings

Decrease in household spending of

$345M (net of Federal rebates).

Decrease in commodity demand of

$90.8M in electricity and natural gas.

IMPLAN Economic Impact Results

Scenario 1: Financed

Impact Type

Direct Effect

Indirect Effect

Induced Effect

Total Effect

Net Fiscal Imact =

Scenario 2: Cash up front

Impact Type

Direct Effect

Indirect Effect

Induced Effect

Total Effect

Net Fiscal Imact =

Employment Labor Income

3,629

854

1,418

5,900

Output

$138,361,004 $291,917,086

$36,170,666

$53,668,747

$ 56,837,225

$92,106,155

$166,687,539

$228,200,417 $550,710,780

Employment Labor Income

3,629

854

-843

3,639

Output

$138,361,004 $291,917,086

$36,170,666 $92,106,155

($31,948,714) ($98,744,653)

$142,582,957 $285,278,588

$ 19,561,586

Results: Job Impacts

7 000

6 000

5 000

4 000

3 000

2 000

1 000

-

(1 000)

(2 000)

5,900 Total Jobs

1 418

854

3 629

3,485 Construction

144 Auditors

3,639 Total Jobs

854

3 629

(843)

Scenario 1: Financed

Direct Indirect Induced

Scenario 2: Cash up front

Job Creation Figures in Context

Is 3,485 construction jobs and 5,900 jobs overall in

North Carolina significant?

Compare to current number of unemployed workers

If enacted in 2011, the EETT would:

 Decrease overall unemployment rate from 9.7 to 9.5%

 Decrease construction industry unemployment by 1.2%

 Add $56 million to state and local coffers

Conclusion

Bottom line: EETT can have a net positive impact on job creation

Policy makers shouldn’t be afraid to use the “stick”

Messaging and communication is key

Tied to saving mortgage interest deduction

Responsibility of home ownership

Precedents:

Building codes for new construction

Recycling mandates

Download