POLITICAL CUES? EFFECTS OF ELITE ENDORSEMENTS ON VOTER AWARENESS OF BALLOT PROPOSITIONS DURING DIRECT DEMOCRATIC ELECTIONS Chad Scott B.A., California State University, Stanislaus, 2005 THESIS Submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS in GOVERNMENT at CALIFORNIA STATE UNIVERSITY, SACRAMENTO FALL 2010 © 2010 Chad Scott ALL RIGHTS RESERVED ii POLITICAL CUES? EFFECTS OF ELITE ENDORSEMENTS ON VOTER AWARENESS OF BALLOT PROPOSITIONS DURING DIRECT DEMOCRATIC ELECTIONS A Thesis by Chad Scott Approved by: __________________________________, Committee Chair Kimberly Love Nalder, Ph.D. __________________________________, Second Reader James Cox, Ph.D. ____________________________ Date iii Student: Chad Scott I certify that this student has met the requirements for format contained in the University format manual, and that this thesis is suitable for shelving in the Library and credit is to be awarded for the thesis. __________________________, Department Chair ___________________ Bahman Fozouni, Ph.D. Date Department of Government iv Abstract of POLITICAL CUES? EFFECTS OF ELITE ENDORSEMENTS ON VOTER AWARENESS OF BALLOT PROPOSITIONS DURING DIRECT DEMOCRATIC ELECTIONS by Chad Scott Direct democracy is a form of political participation that allows individual citizens to make decisions about policy that will have an impact on the larger population. Direct democratic elections place a great deal of power and responsibility within the hands of voters, because the process bypasses the institutional lawmaking arena. Much research on direct democracy focuses on whether individual citizens have the capacity to yield so much power and assume such responsibility. The majority of research in this area has focused on individual level measures, such as: demographic and background data; level of knowledge about an issue; how voters make policy decisions; and how voters become informed. However, until recently the external factors that frame a political election cycle, and levels of voter awareness about ballot propositions have not been accounted for. This analysis takes the assessment of voter awareness one step further. First, by retesting the importance of the political environment during proposition elections. Second, by measuring the effect of elite endorsements on voter awareness of specific ballot propositions. Both of these are important for understanding the context of an election and how this shapes how voters become informed of ballot propositions. v This analysis utilized data collected from a variety of sources. The dependent variable, ballot proposition awareness, was measured by using survey data from the California Field Poll, years 1956-2008. Newspaper articles and editorials from the Los Angeles Times provided an assessment whether a ballot proposition received an elite endorsement. The Fair Political Practices Commission, the California Historical Archives and the California Secretary of State provided the reported total campaign spending for each ballot measure. All other aggregate data were collected from the California Secretary of State. The findings of this analysis substantiate the importance of the political environment during an election. The political environment provides an important context to an election cycle. The context of an election should be considered along with individual-level measures when attempting to gauge voter awareness of political issues, as wells as efforts directed toward predicting voter behavior in elections. While this analysis confirmed the impact of the political environment, there was insufficient evidence to support the thesis that endorsements made by political elites increase ballot proposition awareness during an election cycle. _______________________, Committee Chair Kimberly Love Nalder, Ph.D. _______________________ Date vi ACKNOWLEDGMENTS When this project was still in the conception stage, one of my professors asked, “are you sure you want to do a thesis? Theses can linger, and before you know it years will pass. You should take the exams and be done with them.” After taking these words into consideration, I selected the thesis option. But, I must admit those words grew to haunt me over the course of the project, especially when things didn’t go as planned. Now that the project has come to a conclusion, and I no longer want to read or hear about ballot propositions again, at least not for a long time, I can say without a doubt that making the choice to complete this thesis was the right decision. The journey of this project was challenging and arduous, while simultaneously rewarding. Having said that, this thesis would not have been possible in anyway, shape, or form if it had not been for the love, care, and support of a great number of people. First, and foremost is my wonderful wife Chyllis. Thank you so much for believing in me, and having the patience to help me see this through. It will take me a lifetime to begin to reciprocate the love, encouragement, and support you have given and continue to give me. To my mother Kathryn, while you may not know it you are my hero. I think about all of the sacrifices you’ve made, the challenges you face(d), the dreams you put on hold to make sure that we were provided for, and it moves my heart. At a young age, like most kids, I remember thinking that I wanted to be as different from my parents as was possible. However, these days, I find myself increasingly realizing that so much of who you are is who I am and I’m grateful. Thank you for being the strongest person I know. vii My committee chair Dr. Kimberly Nalder, thank you for your time, guidance, and patience. I remember taking your course during my second semester of graduate school and being terrified. Your course was incredibly challenging for me. At some point during almost every class session I wondered to myself, “why am I here, I should not be here. The other students in this room are much smarter than I am and there is no way I can do this.” The worst part was knowing that I would have to lead a three hour discussion at some point during the semester. As challenging and terrifying as that experience was, I am better off having lived through it. Dr. James Cox, while I only had the opportunity to take one course with you, much of the content you introduced continues to inform my understanding of the political structure within the U.S. Thank you for your encouragement and willingness to join my committee at such a late stage in the game. Dr. Stephen Routh, I’m appreciative for our early discussions about this project. As an undergraduate, I always knew you to be charismatic and inspirational, and your courses were fun and engaging. To a large extent, I owe my aspiration to continue into graduate school to you. You planted the seed, and everyone mentioned above, as well as countless others helped see it to fruition. Thank you. viii TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Acknowledgments.................................................................................................................. vii List of Tables ............................................................................................................................ x Chapter 1. INTRODUCTION……………....……………………………………………………….. 1 Statement of the Problem ............................................................................................. 3 Purpose of the Study ................................................................................................... 4 Significance of the Study ............................................................................................. 4 Hypotheses. .................................................................................................................. 5 Limitations of Study .................................................................................................... 5 Definition of Terms ..................................................................................................... 6 2. REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE .................................................................................... 9 Historical Antecedents ................................................................................................. 9 Direct Democracy in the Progressive Era. ................................................................. 11 Direct Democracy in Contemporary Research .......................................................... 14 3. METHODOLOGY ........................................................................................................... 23 Independent Variables ............................................................................................... 24 Dependent Variable. .................................................................................................. 30 Data Collection and Coding ....................................................................................... 31 Method of Data Analysis ........................................................................................... 38 Summary……………………………………………………………………………. 38 4. ANALYSIS OF THE DATA ............................................................................................ 39 Results of Data Analysis ............................................................................................ 40 Interpretation.............................................................................................................. 48 Individual Variable Interpretation............................................................................... 50 Hypothesis Tests ........................................................................................................ 53 5. CONCLUSION ................................................................................................................. 56 References ............................................................................................................................... 61 ix LIST OF TABLES Page 1. Table 1 Voter Awareness of Ballot Propositions in California, 1956-2008…..... 41 2. Table 2 Governor and Los Angeles Times Endorsement of Ballot Propositions in California, 1956-2008………..……..………………………………….…...... 44 3. Table 3 OLS and Robust Regression of Voter Awareness of California Ballot Propositions, 1956-2008……………………………………….……………….. 47 x 1 Chapter 1 INTRODUCTION Direct democracy relies on participation from individual citizens to make choices on proposals that are likely to impact the larger population. The influence of direct democracy, specifically the initiative process, extends well beyond any individual or group, which makes this form of law making the subject of a great deal of controversy. Much criticism of direct democracy present today can be traced back to arguments originating from the Progressive Era. During the Progressive Era, the process of direct democracy was formally introduced as a democratic institution within many states with the United States (Magleby, 1984). Leading up to the progressive era, many individuals believed their elected representatives were more responsive to special interests than their own constituents. To address the limited role of the public in the governing process, advocates of direct democracy argue for mechanisms to enhance citizen’s political leverage by institutionalizing a place for their voice within the pluralistic lawmaking arena. Further, advocates of direct democracy believe that citizens should have a larger role, a more direct role, in their government, rather then being limited to representational decisionmaking. Opponents of this viewpoint argue that citizen involvement in the policy making process does more harm than good, because ordinary citizens lack the necessary knowledge and insight to understand the intricate details involved within the governing process. 2 There is a growing body of literature that has empirically examined the validity of these contrasting viewpoints. Research has focused on questions such as whether citizens feel more connected to their government because of direct democracy and whether the process itself promotes more responsive representatives; other counterevidence suggests that citizens may not desire a more active role in their government (Hibbing & TheissMorse, 2002). While Hibbing and Thiess-Morse’s (2002) findings are not specifically focused on direct democracy, they are helpful for understanding how citizens use the process democracy and what they want from their government. Hibbing and TheissMorse’s (2002) findings are important to consider because they challenge arguments made by advocates of direct democracy that citizens want a more active role in the policy making process. Whether individual citizens are able to navigate the complex political arena and make informed decisions about public policy has been questioned and empirically tested (Bowler & Donovan 1998; Cronin 1989; Gerber & Lupia 1995; Magleby 1984). Much of the existing literature about direct democracy examines individual knowledge of ballot propositions. However, surprisingly, little attention has been directed toward understanding general levels of individual awareness of ballot propositions during direct democracy elections. Nicholson (2003) argues that before individuals are able to acquire information about a specific ballot initiative, they at the very least, must have heard about it. Assessing awareness is an important piece of the puzzle to understanding how individual’s become informed and ultimately make decisions about direct democracy proposals. Investigations into the understanding of 3 individual knowledge of ballot propositions focus on endogenous factors such as the individual’s level of education, personal income, age, and partisanship; whereas examining the level of individual awareness of these issues is focuses on exogenous factors—something Nicholson (2003) describes as the political environment. The distinction between internal and external factors is important because the link between individuals and their environment may have more of an impact on knowledge of issues then is typically given credit. To be sure, Delli-Carpini and Keeter (1996) provide evidence of a link between an individual’s personal environment and the type of information that is available to them. Statement of the Problem Direct democracy relies on participation from individual citizens to make choices on proposals that will have an impact on a larger population. Because direct democracy has such an extensive impact that extends beyond any individual or group, it is essential to understand how voters become informed, their level of knowledge of an issue, and ultimately how they make their policy decisions. One step toward this goal is to assess individual awareness of direct democratic proposals. It may be expected that levels of awareness are lower during direct democratic elections because propositions do not contain partisan labels that are characteristic of candidate-centered elections. The lack of partisan labeling in ballot elections raises the question of whether voters are able to identify policy proposals that may be opposing or inline with their own partisan preferences. Previous research has shown that elite endorsements may act as a guide for 4 voters when partisan labels are absent. This analysis attempts to evaluate these claims by measuring the impact of elite endorsements on ballot proposition elections. Purpose of the Study The purpose of this study is to increase understanding of how individuals become aware of ballot propositions during direct democratic elections. Previous research has found that environmental factors are important for assessing levels of voter awareness (Nicholson, 2003). This analysis will test the validity of environmental factors, and determine whether there is a significant relationship between elite endorsement of ballot propositions and voter awareness. Significance of the Study Much of the literature about direct democracy examines individual knowledge of ballot propositions. Minimal attention has been directed toward understanding general levels of individual voter awareness of ballot propositions during direct democratic elections. Previous research has found that the political environment, along with individual-level factors, is important in assessing voter awareness of ballot propositions. This analysis takes the assessment of voter awareness one step further. First, by re-testing the importance of the political environment during proposition elections. Second, by measuring the effect of elite endorsements on voter awareness of specific ballot propositions. Both of these are important for the advancement of understanding how voters become informed of ballot propositions. 5 Research Question Do endorsements from political elites increase voter awareness of ballot propositions? Hypotheses Hypothesis 1: The political environment can increase or decrease voter awareness of ballot propositions. Hypothesis 2: An endorsement from a major newspaper within California will increase voter awareness of a ballot proposition. Hypothesis 3: An endorsement from the Governor of California will increase voter awareness of a ballot proposition. Limitations of the Study There are several limitations to this study: first, the use of aggregate public opinion data; second, the ballot propositions that are considered for this analysis; and finally, the political elites considered are limited to governor and newspaper endorsements. The usefulness of public opinion data can be questioned on the grounds that opinion polling is only a snapshot at a particular time. In addition, differences in question wording across opinion polls may lead to different results. Some individuals may answer questions that they have no knowledge about, and they may misrepresent their actual opinions. All of these criticisms impact the validity of public opinion polling. This study will attempt to over come such potential problems; first, by expanding the 6 scope from a single election cycle to include all ballot elections from 1956-2008. Next, to account for the differences in question wording, the polling data used for this analysis will be examined for the specific content of the questions asked. Finally, because this analysis only attempts to understand voter awareness, voter responses are less likely to be subject to social desirability bias by misrepresenting their opinion of the ballot proposition in question. Another limitation of this analysis is the scope of the ballot initiatives considered. The Field Poll does not ask awareness questions about all propositions placed on the ballot for voters to make decisions on. This introduces the question of whether the Field Poll only inquires about higher salient initiatives (Bowler and Donovan, 1998). While this potential objection may limit the extent to which inferences can be made about all ballot propositions, the purpose of this study is to focus on more salient propositions, and to assess the effects of elite endorsement on voter awareness of an initiative. Lastly, the narrow focus of elite endorsement cannot represent the potential influence that other political elites may have on voter awareness. This analysis focuses on proposition endorsements made by the Governor of California and by the Los Angeles Times during the election cycle the initiative is placed on the ballot. Definitions of Terms Campaign spending. The amount of money spent for or against a proposition during a ballot election cycle. 7 Cues. Cues are messages, from a variety of sources, which may help individuals toward making decisions without having complete information. Direct Democracy. Direct democracy is the process whereby individual citizens make choices on policy proposals that are likely to impact the larger population. This stands in contrast to representative democracy where elected officials make policy decisions. The most common forms of direct democracy the initiative process, recall elections, and referendums. Election Cycle. The time between the ending of one election and the next election actually taking place. Heuristics. Heuristics are simplification devises used by individuals to make decisions in situations, such as voting for candidates or propositions, where they are not fully informed. Initiative. Initiatives are proposals submitted to citizens for a vote. When initiatives receive a majority vote they are enacted as law. When initiatives are enacted, they carry the same weight as law created through the legislative process. Political Elite. A political elite is typically defined as any individual or group that is devoted fulltime to some aspect of political activity (Zaller, 1992). Since Zaller's (1992) definition is overly broad, this analysis focuses on two highly visible political elites within California: the governor, and a major news source for politics, The Los Angeles Times. 8 Referendum. The Referendum is a direct democratic procedure, which allows voters to make decisions on whether to keep or overturn laws that have been enacted by the legislature. Recall. Recall elections allow voters to decide whether or not to remove an elected office from office before the end of their term. Likelihood of Voting. Likelihood of voting, or voter fatigue as other have defined it, maybe defined in terms of voting behavior such as an individual’s propensity to complete their ballots when at the polls when there are many propositions, or vote at all when there are too many elections in a year (Walker 1966). Summary This Study focuses understanding how individuals become aware of ballot propositions during direct democratic elections. Previous research has found that environmental factors are important for assessing levels of voter awareness (Nicholson, 2003). The validity of the importance of environmental factors for assessing voter awareness is tested. In addition to environmental factors, this study focuses on the effects of elite endorsement on voter awareness of ballot propositions. Chapter II provides a review of literature. This chapter includes literature regarding voting behavior and direct democracy. Chapter III is a description of the methodology, ballot proposition selection, and survey instruments used for this study. Chapter IV is a discussion of the results of the analysis of data. Chapter V provides the conclusion of the study based on the analysis of data, and recommendations for future research. 9 Chapter 2 REVIEW OF THE LITERATURE This chapter provides a review of literature in the area of direct democracy in the United States, as well as how voters become informed and receive political information. Beginning with a historical overview of direct democracy in the U.S., and moving into contemporary discourse, this analysis questions whether there is a relationship between an elite endorsement of a ballot initiative and voter awareness of that issue. Historical Antecedents During the founding years of the United States, architects of the constitution disagreed about the most equitable forms of democracy. An ardent supporter of a republican form of government, Federalist James Madison argued that a pure form of democracy was dangerous because individuals could become susceptible to a particular mood at any given time. If the public mood became strong enough, Madison warned, the consequence could be disastrous for democracy, as the rights of minority groups might be overlooked or ignored all together. …A pure democracy… can admit no cure for the mischiefs of faction. A common passion or interest will, in almost every case, be felt by a majority of the whole; …and there is nothing to check the inducements to sacrifice the weaker party. Hence it is, that such democracies… have ever been found incompatible with personal security or the rights of property; and have, in general, been as short 10 in their lives as they have been violent in their deaths. (Madison, Jay, & Hamilton, 1788, p. 53) Believing that self-governance would be the ideal form of rule if individuals were capable, Alexander Hamilton ultimately viewed direct democracy as a “disease and a poison” (Stourzh, 1970, p. 40). Consider Hamilton’s speech during the Federal Ratification Convention in New York: It has been observed, by an honorable gentleman, that a pure democracy, if it were practicable, would be the most perfect government. Experience has proved that no position is more false than this. The ancient democracies in which the people themselves deliberated never possessed one good feature of government. Their very character was tyranny their figure deformity. When they assembled, the field presented an ungovernable mob, not only incapable of deliberation, but prepared for every enormity. (Moore, 1857, p. 192) Arguing the merits of a republican, representative form of government in a letter to Edmund Pendleton, George Washington wrote, “Republicanism is not the phantom of a deluded imagination. On the contrary, under no form of government will laws be better supported, liberty and property better secured, or happiness more effectually dispensed to mankind” (Morrison, 2009, p. 104). In a letter to John Taylor speaking about direct democracy, John Adams argues …that democracy never lasts long. It soon wastes, exhausts, and murders itself. There never was a democracy yet that did not commit suicide. It is in vain to 11 say that democracy is less vain, less selfish, less ambitious or less avaricious than aristocracy or monarchy. (Adams, 1851, p. 484) Thomas Jefferson took a more idealistic position toward the capacity of individual self-government. Coupling this position with a suspicion attitude toward representative democracy, Jefferson believed that direct democracy was more equitable because it offered a powerful check on the government. Jefferson’s view is represented well in a correspondence with a friend, "We both consider the people as our children, and love them with parental affection. But you love them as infants whom you are afraid to trust without nurses; and I as adults whom I freely leave to self-government" (Yarbrough, 2006, p. 230). Thomas Jefferson was not the only political elite that favored a larger role for citizens within the legislative process, but his position was in the minority. In the final compromise, the arguments for a representative democracy prevailed as the institutional framework for the federal government. Although individual states were free to adopt direct forms of democracy for interstate governance, this style of legislation did not enter the political landscape until early in the 20th century. Direct Democracy in the Progressive Era During the time that direct democracy became realized as a political institution within the United States, opponents and supporters shared many of the same sentiments that were expressed over a century earlier. Advocates of direct democracy were generally critical of representative forms of legislative action. Many supporters shared a 12 sanguine and hopeful attitude toward greater citizen involvement in the legislative process. Critics were apprehensive of lawmaking by citizen rule. Haynes (1907) presents an optimistic view in favor of direct democracy on the basis that it would stimulate interest and understanding of the political process within the voter. However, Haynes recognizes that a direct democratic system would not be possible if states do not do provide the public with the necessarily tools to navigate the political landscape: In time it will be recognized that faith in direct legislation rests on a very shaky foundation unless the state places before each voter, as its always has placed before each member of a legislature, the means of informing himself upon every question which he is to take part in deciding. (Haynes, 1907, p. 495) Haynes aspiration was as courageous as it was genuinely lofty; he himself recognized the great weight that would be placed upon the state to realize such an ambitious objective. Despite the burden his proposal would place upon the state, he thought that the productive benefits outweighed the initial costs. Cautioning against being overly elated for any institutional change, Lowrie (1911) indicates, “The advocates of the new system overflow with enthusiasm and optimistic convention” (p. 122). Lowrie (1911) acknowledged that “The initiative is intended to give free expression to the interests and ideas of small popular groups, which in the past have not been able to obtain a fair hearing” (p. 129). However, these groups “are not maintaining a responsible relation to the state administration or the whole body of state public opinion. They merely want to push their own ideas or advance their own interests” 13 (p. 129-130). According to Lowrie (1911), advocates of direct democracy may be doing more harm than good, while pursuing goals that are merely in their own self-interest. Recognizing the virtue as well as the weakness of direct democracy, Lowrie (1911) indicated that, “Direct legislation in any form is but a tool of government and will produce desirable laws only in case it is properly used” (p. 572). While a definition of the proper use of direct democracy would at the very least be problematic, Lowrie (1911) urged a calculated and measured approach where, “…lawmaking by the people must remain as an extraordinary channel”; otherwise it can quickly spiral into a populist web, where “faddists” are able to secure the “political nostrums” (p. 572). Eaton (1912) argued that direct democracy would allow well-organized groups with access to resources to circumvent the legislative process and appeal to voters directly. Bypassing the legislature would decrease the opportunity for a collective approach to solving issues. Thereby powerful groups would increase their power, while political parties would become weakened. The implications of this have the potential to reach disastrous outcomes. While political parties are not without their flaws, they are bound to a set of institutionalized rules that govern ethical and legal behavior. Groups that operate outside the political arena are under no such obligation, and therefore, have much more autonomy and less accountability. After all, interest groups are not elected by to serve by the public, so unethical behavior could not be checked unless it was clear that they broke a law. 14 Direct Democracy in Contemporary Research Magleby (1984) identified the major controversies over direct legislation within modern discourse. Magleby found seven arguments in favor of direct democracy: (1) Direct legislation will reduce the power of political parties and party bosses; (2) The process will reduce the power of special interests; (3) Direct democracy acts as a political safety valve; (4) Direct legislation will help educate voters and will allow them to develop civic virtue; (5) Citizens are better suited to decide public policy questions than are elected representatives; (6) Citizens want to decide issues directly, and permitting them to have full participation will decrease public apathy and popular dissatisfaction with government (political efficacy argument); (7) Direct legislation will strengthen democratic government. On the other side of the debate, Magleby (1984) found six arguments against direct democracy: (1) The true beneficiaries of direct democracy will not be the people but the special interests; (2) Direct Legislation will result in an unreasonably complex ballot and frivolous legislation; (3) Voters are ill equipped to understand complicated and unprepared to grapple with the confusing campaigns and appeals that are a part of the initiative process; (4) The legislative process is a much better way to make public policy; (5) Direct democracy will not educate the voters, and it will not increase interest in government; and (6) Direct legislation will endanger democracy and undermine representative government . Narrowing Magleby’s focus, Lupia and Matsusaka (2004) identified four key questions in the direct democracy debate: How does direct democracy affect policy? Who 15 does democracy benefit: the many or the few? What is the role of money? And are voters competent to make policy decisions that will affect the wider population? The following section examines recent scholarship within Lupia and Matsusaka’s (2004) issue areas. How Does Direct Democracy Affect Policy? Addressing the question of whether direct democracy leads to a more responsive government, Lascher Jr., Hagen, and Rochlin (1996) argued that the current practice of the initiative process does not “enhance the extent to which policies accord with public opinion” (p. 774). While Lacher Jr., Hagen, and Rochlin’s (1996) findings may not support a direct influence between direct democracy and responsive policy, with respect to public opinion, there may be evidence elsewhere to support the notion that special interest use the initiative process to influence policy makers in other ways. Indeed, Gerber (1998) did not find a direct relationship between the placement of an initiative on the ballot and the passage of favorable policy. Rather, Gerber (1998) found that special interest groups were able to indirectly influence policy by placing initiatives on the ballot that they never intended to pass. The purpose of placing the initiative on the ballot was not so much to win an election as it was to get the attention of policy makers. However, Gerber (1998) indicated that there are limitations to indirect influence; some groups would be more successful than others. Interest groups that tend to be more successful are those who have had prior access to the political arena, or those with greater access to resource mobilization, but even then this is often limited to certain issue areas. Gerber’s (1998) findings suggest that interest groups may have a powerful political tool at their disposal. Interest group influence should not be viewed as affecting 16 policy issues alone, rather organized interests may be able to place legislation that could help or harm a legislator’s electoral success during an election cycle. Nicholson (2005) demonstrated that salient political issues have the potential to frame an election cycle. These issues create a particular public mood, one in which legislators can increase or decease their electoral success depending upon how they address the issues that are present during an election cycle. Thus, if an interest group wanted to gain the attention of a candidate, increase or decrease the chances of electoral success, they can do so by strategically placing legislation on the ballot. Bali and Davis (2007) had different conclusions regarding the effectiveness of indirect influence. While they agree the threat of an initiative does have some influence, this may be decreasing over time as legislators and political parties “adapt” to the initiative process (Bali & Davis, 2007, p. 226). Tolbert (1998) finds that states that utilize the ballot initiative regularly are more likely to adopt governance policies that can have long-term consequences for state and local governments. Specifically, Tolbert (1998) finds a relationship between the frequency of the initiative process and the enactment of term limits for elected officials, supermajority tax rules, and state tax and expenditure limitations. In California’s political climate, all three have occurred. In 1978 voters enacted proposition 13, which limited the amount that the state could tax home and business owners. In 1993 voters adopted term limits as a response to limit the amount of time a legislature can remain in office. And in 1979 voters passed a two-thirds supermajority for budget and tax related issues. 17 Who does direct legislation benefit? Gamble (1997) addresses the question: “when citizens have the power to legislate civil rights issues directly, will the majority tyrannize the minority?” (p. 261). Using data from that spans three decades, Gamble concludes that the majority “repeatedly used direct democracy to put the rights of the political minority to a popular vote” (p. 261). Further, Gamble (1997) finds policies that undermine the civil rights of minority groups have a high rate of success when placed on the ballot for a decision. Disagreeing with Gamble’s (1997) position, Bowler and Donovan, and Tolbert (1998) argue that evidence supporting the claim that direct legislation results in policy that encroaches upon minority rights is weak. They indicate that the size of the jurisdiction where the policies are proposed must be taken into account when making this assessment—smaller jurisdictions may enact policies that are more repressive to minorities but his relationship weakens with larger populations. Bowler, Donovan, and Tolbert (1998) suggest that larger populations are more likely to support pro-gay legislation though direct democracy than through representative channels. Elsewhere, Bowler and Donovan (1998) support this assessment, arguing that much of the criticism waged against direct democracy, is unfounded. However, recent events in California, suggest these positions may need to reexamined. What roles does money play in ballot proposition elections? Campaign spending is a modest indicator of the success or failure of an initiative during ballot proposition elections. There is sufficient evidence, which suggests ballot campaigns which spend the most money are generally more successful, though the 18 opposition may have more of an advantage (Cronin, 1989, Magleby 1984; Shockly, 1980; Zisk 1987). Other research has examines the relationship between campaign spending voter and voter understanding of the issues. Bowler and Donovan (1998) and Lupia (1994) suggest that voters are primarily informed about ballot propositions through campaign advertising: and negative campaign spending seems to have the greatest impact in this regard. Contrarily, Stratmann (2006) finds evidence that suggests the claims that negative campaigning may be overstated. Further, Stratmann (2006) indicates that while both sides of the campaign influence the outcome of a policy issue, the positive campaign has a greater chance of making an impact on the voters. Supporting Bowler and Donovan (1998), Nicholson (2003) finds evidence from eighteen elections in California that indicate negative campaign spending has a much greater impact on voter awareness. These findings are important because, as Nicholson (2003) suggests, before voters can make a decision about an issue, they, at the very least, had to have heard about them. Voter Competency Smith (2002) suggested that political attitudes are influenced by the institutional structure of the political arena. Further, Smith (2002) argued that citizens who regularly utilize the institution of direct democracy will “gain in civil abilities” and over time “make for better citizens” (p. 892). Similarly, Bowler and Donovan (2002) maintained that participation in direct democracy “may encourage a greater sense of efficacy, and possibly, civic engagement” (p. 398). However, Bowler and Donovan (2002) do not 19 attribute augmented feelings of political efficacy to be a product of direct participation alone, other individual variables such as education seem to play a significant role. A similarly related question of whether voters are competent to voter in direct democratic elections is do they want to? There is mixed evidence from the based upon the turnout number from the ballot elections in California, there is mixed evidence to support this claim, because approximately half of the registered voters failed to cast a vote for or against a ballot proposition. Using data gathered from focus groups, Hibbing and Theiss-Morse (2003) found that many individuals do not want to participate more in the political arena. Although, their research did not specifically address direct democracy, the results are applicable because their respondents consistently indicated that they would rather have public officials they trust than to make policy decisions themselves. It is only when individuals do not have trust in their elected officials that they then want to become involved. Another strand of literature in the area of voter competency focuses on individual knowledge of ballot propositions. Two interesting questions within this area focuses on how much people know about issues, and how individual become informed on ballot proposition elections? How individuals become informed about particular propositions is interesting, because ballot elections do not have the partisan labels that are present in candidate-centered elections. While propositions lack partisan labeling there is evidence that partisanship is an indicator of individual-level voting behavior in ballot contests (Branton, 2003; Conover & Feldman, 2004). 20 Elite Endorsement of Ballot Propositions Individuals may utilize information disseminated from political elites to help organize their own preferences for political information (Converse, 1964). Key (1966) found that mass public opinion is influenced by elite discourse. This suggests that attitudes are not formulated in a vacuum, rather they are given contextualization from a variety of sources including: the mass media, political elites, organized interest groups, and political activists. Broadly, these sources will be referred to as political elites, which fits Zaller’s (1992) definition because these individuals or groups are devoted fulltime to some aspect of political activity. Since partisan labels are absent from direct democracy elections, voters may employ other means to assist them in making decisions about ballot initiatives. One way incomplete information maybe over come by voters is by using elite endorsements as a content cue (Karp, 1998). Political elites are able to influence voters in a variety of ways. One way that political elites attempt to influence voters is by breaking issues down into smaller, more easily digestible, symbolic representations. These representations act as a cue, signaling to voters what the nature of the subject matter of the issue is (Lupia, 1994). The effectiveness of cues as information shortcuts, or heuristics, has been explored (Sniderman, Brody, & Tetlock, 1991; Lupia, 1994; and Mondak, 1993) and challenged (Bartels, 1996; Kuklisniski, & Quirk, 2000; Lau, & Redlawski, 2000). The effectiveness of cues as participation facilitators has also been addressed (Lewkowicz, 2006). One area that has received little attention is how cues from political elites influence public awareness of an issue. 21 When elites openly support or oppose propositions, the public may interpret this act in accordance with a party position. Upon receiving these cues from elites, voters may choose to accept or reject without further information. There is evidence that voter behavior is consistent with partisan or ideological preferences across several ballot issue domains (Branton, 2003). Though mass media outlets may not be considered political elites in the same way as a political figure or group normally would, they do fit within Zaller’s (1992) definition. Media outlets engage in political discourse by transmitting messages from other political elites to the public. In this sense, the media is a vehicle for announcing elite cues to the public. It may be argued that transmitting these messages does not justify defining the media as a political elite, however, it should be recognized that some media outlets do operate in an agenda setting fashion in which they can influence the public (Behr & Iyengar, 1985; Mutz & Soss, 1997). There is evidence that decision makers pay close attention to media coverage, this places media outlets in a position to influence policy makers (Cook et al., 1983). In some instances the media pursue their own policy goals (Page and Shapiro, 1992). One such way this can be seen is when newspaper editorials endorse or oppose a specific ballot proposition. Another powerful function that media outlets have at their discretion is they decide what stories to report on, how often they report them, and how much individual attention each story receives. Perhaps one the most powerful ways that media outlets operate as political elites via their ability to frame issues and agendas (Hall-Jamison & Waldman, 2003). 22 There is a significant amount of opinion and commentary present in both the print and broadcast media. During an election cycle, the editorial staff at the Los Angeles Times (L. A. Times) routinely takes positions on ballot propositions. Editorial positions might be interpreted as an attempt to persuade readers to vote one way or another on a particular issue. Editors may be attempting to motivate voters, but their recommendations could also function as a mechanism for increasing awareness about an issue at hand. This is because the L. A. Times is an agenda setting news outlet. When the L. A. Times devotes attention to a particular issue, other media outlets may follow suit. Summary The findings of this chapter provide a representation of research in the area of direct democracy and political behavior within the United States. Beginning with the historical antecedents of direct democracy and moving into contemporary discourse, the majority of attention was directed toward the question of how voters receive information during direct democratic elections. While it is important to understand how individuals become informed during direct democratic elections in general, the step taken here is to determine whether political elites are able to influence voter awareness of ballot propositions. Chapter III is a description of the methodology used for this study. Chapter IV provides a discussion of the data collection and coding of all variables, the method of analysis, and the results of the hypothesis tests. Chapter V provides the conclusion of the study. 23 Chapter 3 METHODOLOGY This purpose of this analysis is two-fold: first, to determine whether the political environment surrounding an election affects voter awareness of ballot propositions; and second, whether endorsements made by political elites influences voter awareness of a ballot proposition. The Dependent variable is voter awareness of ballot propositions. Many of the independent variables (campaign spending, type of election, presidential election, special election, number of issues on a ballot, days to election, media coverage, and proposition passage) are established measures adapted from the political environment framework modeled by Nicholson (2003). To establish content validity and research reliability I will be utilizing several previously established measures; mainly from Nicholson (2003), who has adapted them from Magleby (1984), Bowler and Donovan (1992, 1998). The independent variables are: Elite Endorsement, Media Attention, Media Endorsement, Campaign Spending, Number of Propositions on the Ballot, Type of Election, Days to the Election, and the Content of the Ballot Proposition. Other aggregate voter information such as the number of registered voters, number of registered Republicans and Democrats, the total voter turnout for a given election are used as control measures. 24 Independent Variables Elite Endorsement Studies have shown that elite endorsement can have an impact on political behavior (Karp, 1998; Smith, 2002). Using Elite endorsement as an explanatory variable I test to see if they also raise general awareness about a proposition. To increase content validity, Zaller's (1992) broad definition of a political elite is narrowed to focuses specifically on media and gubernatorial elites. The governor’s office was selected to be a proxy for elite endorsement because it is the most visible statewide political position. When the governor takes a position on a particular issue, it is likely to be covered by the press statewide; where as an individual state senator, or state assembly member may only garner coverage within their district. The amount of press attention an elite draws, or lack thereof, introduces a problem of data availability. For less visible state senators, or assembly members, there may be no record of any endorsements made for or against a ballot proposition. While a record of gubernatorial endorsements was found for all years under the consideration of this study 1956-2008. Media Attention and Endorsement Media attention is perhaps one of the most important explanatory variables to consider—almost all information citizens have about politics is transmitted through the media. The L. A. Times has been noted as being one of the most important news sources within California. As an agenda setting newspaper, the L.A. Times may be a good barometer for the broad measurement of the political climate in California as Nicholson (2003) suggests. However, it might be difficult to capture the nuance of different 25 political environments that exist within California with a single source. Even when other news sources are running stories that have been put on the agenda by the L.A. Times, the amount of coverage or attention, type of attention, and location of the story can vary widely. Some differences can be based upon other stories of interest within the specific location of the media source. For example, a newspaper could choose to run an article about a proposition on page two when the L.A. Times gave it front page attention because there are other stories of higher interest to the specific location the same day, the opposite could also be true. The L.A. Times could run an article about a ballot proposition on a different page of the paper, while other papers might print it as frontpage news. All of these factors could lead to differing levels of awareness by location. It should also be recognized that newspapers are not the only source that individual’s utilize to become informed on political issues. Ideally, use of the media as an independent variable should not be confined to print sources alone, rather it would be helpful to account for broadcast sources as well. Despite the abovementioned limitations, the political climate will be measured using the same method Nicholson (2003) uses, by front-page coverage in the L. A. Times. There are two reasons for the decision to focus solely on the L. A. Times. First, California has over 3,700 newspapers, it would be an arduous task to examine each for paper for its individual coverage and compare it with L. A. Times coverage. Second, though it would be ideal to account for broadcast media coverage, analysis in this area is particularly problematic, because unlike print media, content from television and radio are not straightforwardly open to data analysis, and often data is unavailable. 26 Campaign spending Campaign spending has been shown to be a modest indicator of the success or failure of initiatives during a ballot proposition election (Bowler and Donovan, 1998; Hadwiger, 1992). There is sufficient evidence, which suggests campaigns that spend the most money are generally more successful, though this has been shown to have more truth on the opposition side of the campaign (Cronin, 1989, Magleby 1984; Shockly, 1980; Zisk 1987). Bowler & Donovan (1992) indicate that campaign spending for both sides of the proposition increases the chances that lower rates of voter drop-off will occur in ballot proposition elections—though they also found that more money spent on the negative campaign yielded an increase of more no votes. Based upon these findings it seems reasonable to infer that negative campaign spending is also likely to increase individual awareness of ballot propositions, even though it has a negative behavioral effect. This inference seems reasonable; if voters are marking no instead choosing to abstain from voting on certain issues at all, then it may give some indication that individuals recognize the initiative enough to know that they did not agree with what it proposed, or that they did not understand the issue: either case there seems to be a slight level of awareness. When an organized effort launches an attack against a ballot proposition, it forces the opposite campaign to assume a defensive posture. To overcome a negative perception from a public attack, the ballot proposition campaign must defend their agenda, which means they must reorder their spending preferences, i.e. spend money in a direction that perhaps they would have rather spent elsewhere. 27 Nonetheless, regardless of the direction of the money that is spent during a ballot contest, campaign spending in general has significant potential to raise public awareness of that issue. This can be observed on several different levels. First, spending more money typically translates to more commercials, which enables the campaign to disseminate messages to a widespread audience, and more frequently. Second, often media coverage of elections tends to focus on horse race coverage (Brady & Johnson, 1987; Broh 1977; Patterson, 1980) which the latest update on who is ahead in the polls is reported. Also, much media attention is focused on political ads; negative advertisements specifically (Ansolobehere & Iyengar, 1995; Freedman & Goldstein 1999). Voter fatigue and the Number of Issues on the Ballot Voter fatigue is traditionally defined in terms of voting behavior such as an individual’s propensity to complete their ballots when at the polls (Walker 1966). Bowler and Donovan (1992) define voter fatigue in a similar fashion by applying a conventional voter cost analysis originally developed by Downs (1957) to measure the amount of drop-off in ballot proposition elections. The voter cost analysis theory is generally used for explaining voter turnout in candidate-centered elections, however, the same individual costs exist in ballot proposition elections if not more so, as initiatives are not easily identified by a partisan label. Greatly simplified, the cost analysis theory asserts that when the costs to the individual voter, exceed benefits for participation, then the individual will abstain from participating in an election. Nicholson (2003) suggests the same logic applies equally to ballot proposition awareness. By doing so, Nicholson (2003) assumes that levels of awareness can be 28 measured the same way as drop-off, which implicitly suggests that lengthy ballots increase the potential for citizens to disengage from paying attention to new political information. This assumption seems reasonable as an increase in ballot propositions is likely to cause more confusion and will also increase the costs in terms of time to become more informed on all the ballot issues. In this sense, voter fatigue can be defined as a point at which an individual becomes apathetic to new political information. Bowler and Donovan (1992) list ten variables that contribute to an individual becoming fatigued during the ballot election: Total campaign spending; citizen initiated propositions; propositions that alter the state constitution; presidential election; long ballot; prolixity of proposition; large number of propositions on the ballot; length of the ballot; type of issue; and locations on the ballot. Of these variables, several were found to be statistically significant at the 0.05 level using a one-tailed test: length of the ballot, or number of questions on the ballot, amount of time to the election, and campaign spending. These variables were utilized in Nicholson’s (2003) political environment framework and are utilized in this analysis. Type of Election There are differences between different types of elections which might have an affect on voter awareness of ballot propositions. Differences have been measured in terms of turnout, media coverage, and levels of information present. During presidential and gubernatorial elections much attention from the media is devoted to the horserace competition between the candidates running for office (Broh, 1977). When this highlevel of competition between candidates occurs, other issues and contests receive less 29 attention then they normally might garner. Special elections and primary elections are important to consider, as these contests are generally less salient and have a lower rate of turnout; however, the 2005 California Special Election is an exception, as turnout and awareness were almost as high as general elections from previous years. Days to the Election As Election Day becomes closer, voter awareness of ballot initiatives is likely to increase. The foundation for this assumption is threefold. First, as campaigns continue, they spend more money. Typically, the majority of campaign expenditures are spent on advertising, whether it occurs in the form of print media, commercials through broadcast media sources, or any combination of the above. Campaign mailers are also methods election campaigns may utilize. Second, news sources in the print or broadcast media, may give attention to particular issues. An example of this takes place when news sources make comments on political advertising; this is especially true, when campaigns utilize negative advertising strategies. Third, individuals become more aware simply through repetition, as voters are more likely to report familiarity of an issue if they have encountered it on more then one occasion. As campaigns continue, and news sources report on ballot initiatives, voters have more opportunities to encounter information about a proposal, and in many cases they may have come across information on more then one occasion. Therefore, it seems worthy to conclude that the use of number of days to the election is important when evaluating levels individual awareness of ballot propositions. 30 Dependent Variable Voter Awareness of Ballot Propositions The dependent variable for this analysis is voter awareness of ballot propositions during ballot proposition elections from 1956-2008. Ballot proposition awareness is measured using data collected from the California Field Poll. The starting point of 1956 was selected for this analysis because it is the first year the Field Poll began asking and recording data about individual awareness of ballot propositions. The California Field Poll is a good resource assessing awareness, because they ask questions that specifically measure individual awareness of specific ballot propositions (Nicholson, 2003). While the Field Poll does measure awareness, there are limitations to the extent that one can make inferences for the use of such data. First, the Field Poll does not utilize the same wording when asking individuals about whether they are aware of a ballot proposition. The question the Field poll typically asks is, “have you seen, read, or heard anything about (Proposition #) a statewide ballot proposition having to do with (content varies according to the proposition being asked about) that will appear on the next election ballot?” To account for this potential threat to reliability, each ballot proposition question is evaluated for differences in wording. Of the 24-ballot elections considered in this analysis, only two cycles were found to contain differences in the way questions were asked by the Field Poll. In all, nine proposition questions did not contain the same wording as the other 103. For ballot propositions 14, 17, 18, 19, 20, 21, and 22 from 1972; 13 and 14 from 1976, respondents were asked whether they thought they knew 31 enough about a proposition to vote on it. Though the questions were worded differently, they are essentially asking the same question. Second, the Field Poll does not inquire about all propositions that are on a ballot during an election. Rather, the Field Poll typically asks awareness questions about more salient propositions. This poses a problem for assessing ballot proposition awareness because higher levels of awareness might by expected when respondents are asked about propositions that receive more attention. Despite this problem, even with the Field Poll inquiring about more salient ballot initiatives, the differences in levels of awareness of all ballot propositions considered in this analysis are quite large. Third, as it may be true with all polling data that is obtained via random calling methods, the California Field Poll is no exception to questions of reliability and validity. The first, objection would be telephone sampling contains an inherent bias, because individuals who do not own phones, either by chance or by choice are not represented in the sample. Conversely, however, it may be argued that these underrepresented individuals typically do not vote, therefore, they may not be as in-tune with political information as the average voter. There are strengths of using this method, such as sampling is completely randomized. Data Collection and Coding Days to the Election This variable for days to the election is the total number of days from the last day of the time period respondents were asked by the Field Poll about a particular ballot issue 32 during the election cycle. For example, when the Field Poll asked respondents about Proposition 140 during the 1990 general election, the poll took place between October 27th-30th and the election took place on November 6th, so the total number of days to the election is coded as (7). Type of Election The type of election indicates whether an election was a primary or a general election. The type of ballot proposition will be determined using data gathered from the voter handbook distributed by the California Secretary of State during each election cycle. Coding for this variable is (0) for a primary election and (1) for a general election. Campaign Spending Total campaign spending for ballot propositions from 2000-2008 was collected from the California Secretary of State (CSoS). Prior to 2000 the Fair Political Practices Commission collected campaign finance data. Depending upon the year of the ballot election, records were obtained from the Fair Political Practices Commission (FPPC) and the California Historical Archives (CHA). Prior to 1990 campaign expenditures for a ballot proposition were not calculated to provide a total expenditure amount. For these propositions, individual committees expenditures were added together for both the support and against campaigns. The support and against campaigns were then added together to obtain the total expenditure for a ballot proposition. The coding for campaign expenditures is straightforward with the number being reported are the actual expenditures made in U.S Dollars. Since this analysis examines ballot propositions from 33 1956-2008, all campaign expenditures were adjusted for inflation using the Implicit Gross Domestic Product (GDP) to U.S. Dollars in 2008. The variable for campaign expenditure was collected from the CSoS, the California FPPC, and the CHA. Coding for ballot campaign expenditures uses the total United States Dollar amount as reported by each ballot committee to the agency responsible for recording such data at the time. The reported amount includes individual totals for supporting and opposing committees for a ballot proposition from January 1 to the day of an election during an election cycle. In addition, total campaign expenditures are reported which includes supporting and opposing committees. The total amount was obtained simply by adding the amount of expenditures for the supporting committees and the final amount spent by opposing committees. For many ballot measures several committees are listed as supporting or opposing the proposed legislation. When a ballot measure has more then one committee, either supporting or opposing, the total campaign expenditure for each group is reported as a total sum for the position taken on the proposition. Several propositions did not have a committee: a) that supported the measure; b) that opposed the measure; or c) both. If a measure did not have a, b, or c then zero is reported as the total campaign expenditure. Many propositions had committees that supported or opposed a measure, but did not file a campaign report with the Secretary of State. When this occurred the campaign expenditures are assumed to be minimal and are reported as zero. With no data available, 34 it is not possible to make a determination of how much, if any, a group spent supporting or opposing a ballot measure. Since California law requires campaign committees to report all donations, and expenditures, it is unlikely that a group would violate election law by failing to report the mandated information to the Secretary of State because of the penalties for such action. Therefore, it seems reasonable to assume that if a committee that did not file a report with the Secretary of State, then the group either spent very little on the campaign, or did not spend anything at all: in either case it would not be likely that the committee monetary contributions to the ballot campaign yield much of an impact in either direction. However, there were instances in which committees supported or opposed more then one ballot measure. In these cases, if it was clear that a committee spent money on more than one measure, such as mailers, advertising, calling potential voters, etc., then the total campaign expenditures for that committee were used for each ballot measure they supported or opposed. This decision was made because the total campaign expenditures reported by each group are reported as one sum regardless of the number of ballot measures they support of oppose. Therefore, the data does not permit disaggregation of campaign expenditures for each ballot measure a committee supports or opposes when there is more then one. Newspaper Endorsement Newspaper endorsement was recorded using data from Los Angeles Times (L.A. Times) publications 1956-2008. The primary reason for using the Los Angeles Times, as a foundation for assessing newspaper endorsements, is the L.A. Times is a trendsetting 35 regional daily news source, and has the second largest circulation in California. In addition, the Times is the only regional newspaper that contains a searchable database that extends far enough to include all election years used for analysis. This is especially important, because of the limited resources for this analysis. The only other option would be to search the daily newspapers on microfiche. The data for this analysis was obtained using ProQuest Historical Database (PQHD)for the Los Angeles Times, licensed through California State University, Sacramento during the period of February 28th-March 1st. For publications prior to 1985, data was collected using the PQHD for the Los Angeles Times, licensed through the University of California, Davis, during the period of March 4th-6th. During an election cycle the editorial staff at the L. A. Times routinely takes a position on a ballot propositions. Editorial positions are often aimed to persuade readers to vote one way or another on a particular issue. Though their aim of printing their opinion about an issue is primarily to motivate voters, their recommendation can also serve as a mechanism for increasing awareness about an issue at hand. It may also be likely that other papers will follow suit and issue similar recommendations. This is important because when a newspaper takes a position on an issue is also likely that the paper will print more articles on the matter then it would if no recommendation was given. Quite simply, this can serve as a mechanism for increasing awareness, through repetition. The coding for newspaper endorsement is (0) if a newspaper takes a position against a ballot proposition, and (1) if the editors choose to support the issue. The 36 Endorsement encompasses whether a newspaper endorsed or opposes a ballot proposition during an election cycle. All ballot propositions used for this analysis were found to have a position reposted with the L. A. Times, so there were no issues of missing or incomplete data. Gubernatorial Endorsement The data for whether a Governor endorsed or opposed a ballot proposition was gathered from the L. A. Times. For reasons already stated the L. A. Times serves as an excellent record of California Politics, therefore if a governor has taken a position it will likely be reported in the Times. For propositions the governor opposed the coding is (1). For propositions the governor either supported or created, the coding is (2). In some instances it was reported that the governor did not take a position on a certain ballot issue, for these propositions the coding is (0). Voter Fatigue Using Bowler and Donovan’s (1992) framework to explain voter fatigue on proposition awareness, it is not necessary to utilize all of the indicators they used in explaining drop-off. The total length of the ballot, which includes many candidates running for office, and location of the issue on the ballot are not useful indicators as this analysis is aimed toward explaining individual awareness, not actual voting behavior. In addition, total campaign spending, type of election, and type of issue the proposition addresses will be used as individual variables to be isolated in the final analysis, and will not be used in the calculus of voter fatigue. Therefore, the indicators that are used to 37 calculate voter fatigue are the total number of propositions on the ballot, propositions that alter the state constitution, and prolixity of proposition. Media Coverage Data collection for media coverage was obtained from the media center at California State University, Sacramento (CSUS). Front-page newspapers articles printed in the L. A. Times for the years of 1956-2008 were viewed from the CSUS microfilm collection. If the L. A. Times featured a front-page article about a ballot proposition then it is coded (1); if there was no coverage that day then it is coded (0). Aggregate Voter Data All aggregate level data, such as voter turnout for an election, registered Democratic and Republican party was obtained from the California Secretary of State. Coding for these variables are the actual numbers reported by the California Secretary of State's office. Voter Awareness of Ballot Propositions The data for this analysis is collected from a variety of sources. For the dependent variable, ballot proposition awareness, is measured by using survey data from the California Field Poll, years 1956-2008. Reasoning for the use of the Field Poll and the years selected is addressed in greater length above. Coding for ballot proposition awareness is the actual percentage of awareness reported by the Field Poll. 38 Method of Data Analysis The analysis of data will be performed using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression and robust regression techniques. This method of data analysis will be utilized in this because it has been found to be a successful tool by researchers conducting similar investigations. Using robust regression acts as a check on the reliability of the OLS regression analysis. In addition, robust regression can be used as an alternative technique to OLS regression, when the assumptions the method are unable to be fulfilled. Robust regression is an option when the distribution of the residuals is not evenly distributed, or there are influential cases, which skew the data. Hamilton (1998) notes, “a robust estimator performs well even when there are small violations of assumptions about the underlying population” (p. 189). Summary This chapter provided a description of the method of analysis, the independent variables, the dependent variable, and the survey instruments used for this study. In addition, this chapter reviewed the relevant indicators for measuring voting behavior and knowledge of political issues while justifying their use for assessing voter awareness of ballot propositions. The explanation for the use of each indicator as an independent variable to measure the effect on ballot proposition awareness is provided. Chapter IV provides a discussion of the data collection and coding of all variables, the method of analysis, and the results of the hypothesis tests. Chapter V provides the conclusion of the study based on the analysis of data, and recommendations for future research. 39 Chapter 4 ANALYSIS OF THE DATA The primary question of this analysis is to determine whether endorsements from political elites increase voter awareness of ballot propositions. To determine whether elite endorsement increase voter awareness three hypotheses will be tested: Hypothesis 1: The political environment can increase or decrease voter awareness of ballot propositions. Hypothesis 2: An endorsement from a major newspaper within California will increase voter awareness of a ballot proposition. Hypothesis 3: An endorsement from the Governor of California will increase voter awareness of a ballot proposition. All three hypothesis are tested using two separate models: one model utilizes total campaign spending as an independent variable, while the other analyzes positive and negative campaign spending separately. Both models are tested using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression and robust regression statistical analysis. Hypothesis 1: tests the effects of the political environment on ballot proposition awareness by utilizing established measures from previous research. Hypothesis 2 tests whether an endorsement from the Los Angeles Times increases ballot proposition awareness by isolating the effects from other variables with the political environment model. Hypothesis 3 tests whether an endorsement from the governor of California increases ballot proposition awareness by holding the effects of other variables with the political environment model constant. 40 Results of Data Analysis The analysis of data is performed using two regression techniques: Ordinary Least Squares (OLS), and robust regression. OLS regression is primary statistical analysis used because OLS tests the effects of the political environment and political elite independent variables on the voter awareness of ballot propositions. Robust regression is uses to verify the reliability of the OLS analysis. Two separate models are included in this analysis to compare the effect of the political environment on voter awareness of ballot propositions. The two models are set up to detect differences between positive and negative campaign spending in Model 1, and total campaign spending in Model 2. 41 Table 1 Voter Awareness of Ballot Propositions in California, 1956-2008 Year Prop. Ballot Title Awareness 2008 93 Legislative Term Limits 80% 94 Referendum on Indian gaming Compact 84% 95 Referendum on Indian gaming Compact 84% 96 Referendum on Indian gaming Compact 84% 97 Referendum on Indian gaming Compact 84% 2006 83 Sex Offenders Punishment 78% 85 Parental Notification of Teenage Abortion 49% 86 Tax on Cigarettes 56% 87 Alternative Energy Tax on California Oil 53% 90 Regulation of Private Property 53% 82 Tax increase for Public Preschool Education 49% 2005 74 Tenure for Public School Teachers 45% 75 Consent of Union Due for Political Contributions 55% 76 School Funding State Spending 22% 77 Reapportionment. 42% 78 Prescription Drug Discounts 34% 79 Prescription Drug Discounts 36% 80 Electric Service Regulation 44% 2004 60 Election Rights of Political Parties 46% 61 Children’s Hospital Grant Projects 57% 62 Primary Elections 40% 63 Tax for Mental Health Services 58% 64 Limitations on Unfair Business Competition Laws 49% 66 Three Strikes 75% 67 Surcharge for Emergency and Medical Services 38% 68 Tribal Gaming Compact Renegotiation 94% 70 Exclusive Rights for Tribal Gaming Compact 94% 71 Stem Cell Research Funding 58% 72 Health Care Coverage Requirements. 42% 2003 54 Racial and Ethnic Classification 81% University Public Education Facilities Bond Act of 2002 47 2002 63% 49 Before and After School Programs 66% 50 Water Quality, Supply and Safe Drinking Water 46% 52 Election Day Voter Registration 53% 34 Campaign Contributions and Spending Limits 58% 36 Drug Probation and Treatment 57% 38 School Vouchers for Private and Religious Education 88% 39 School Facilities 64% 1998 3 Partisan Presidential Primary Elections 34% 5 Tribal-State Gaming Compacts 94% 8 Public Schools 49% 42 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 9 10 207 209 211 215 218 184 186 187 188 161 163 164 165 166 167 126 128 129 130 131 133 134 135 136 138 139 140 100 101 103 104 106 61 62 63 64 64 36 37 38 39 40 Electric Utility Bonds Tax on Tobacco for Childhood Development Programs Attorneys Fees Regulation Prohibition against Discrimination Attorney-Client Fee Arrangements Medical Use of Marijuana Voter Approval for Local Government Taxes Increased Sentences. Repeat Offenders (3 Strikes) Health Services Taxes Illegal Aliens Ineligibility for Public Services Smoking and Tobacco Products Physician Assisted Death Ends Taxation of Certain Food Products Congressional Term Limits Budget Process for Welfare Basic Health Coverage State Taxes Taxes for Alcoholic Beverages Environment Drug Enforcement, Prevention and Treatment Timber Harvesting Practices Limits Elected Offices Campaign Financing and Ethics Drug Enforcement and Prevention Alcohol Surtax Pesticide Regulation State, Local, Taxation Timber Harvesting Practices Tax credit for Prison Inmate Labor Limits on Terms of Office Legislators Retirement Insurance Rates and Regulation Automobile Accident Claims and Insurance Rates Insurance Rates and Regulation Automobile and Other Insurance Attorney Fees Limit for Tort Claims Compensation of Public Officials Taxation of Local Government and Districts Official State Language Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndrome (quarantine) Restrictions on Toxic Discharges into Drinking Water Taxation State Lottery Voting Materials in English Only Reapportionment Campaign Contributions 71% 72% 56% 86% 82% 84% 26% 92% 86% 91% 73% 66% 54% 68% 56% 58% 39% 73% 78% 39% 56% 65% 28% 79% 62% 35% 66% 39% 67% 54% 38% 57% 48% 17% 77% 47% 85% 76% 78% 83% 93% 72% 65% 48% 43 41 9 11 12 13 14 14 8 10 5 6 7 13 14 14 17 18 19 20 21 22 18 1A 3 9 14 4 Public Aid Medical Assistance Programs 1982 School Textbooks for Nonpublic Schools Beverage Containers Nuclear Weapons Water Resources Reapportionment Handgun Registration 1980 Water Resources Smoking and Non-Smoking Sections 1978 Regulation of Smoking School Employees Homosexuality Murder Penalty 1976 Grey Hound Dog Racing Initiative Statute Agricultural Labor Relations 1972 Property Tax Limitations Death Penalty Obscenity Legislation Marijuana Removal of penalty for Personal Use Coastal Zone Conservation Act Assignment of Students to Schools Agriculture Labor Relations 1970 Motor Vehicle Taxation and Revenues 1968 Homeowners Property Tax Exemption Education Bonds Limitation on Property Tax Rate 1964 Regulation of Residential Real Property 1956 Aid to Need Aged Mean Average Standard Deviation Sources: California Field Polls 1956-2008 61% 63% 95% 91% 76% 58% 97% 69% 93% 95% 84% 55% 66% 59% 37% 84% 60% 79% 53% 59% 48% 55% 45% 38% 46% 66% 39% 62% 19% 44 Table 2 Governor and Los Angeles Times Endorsement of Ballot Propositions in California, 1956-2008 Election Prop. N.P. Gov. Year # Passed End End Governor in Office Political Party 2008 93 No Yes Yes A. Schwarzenegger Republican 94 Yes No Yes 95 Yes No Yes 96 Yes No Yes 97 Yes No Yes 2006 83 Yes No Yes 85 No No Yes 86 No Yes Yes 87 No No Yes 90 No No Yes 82 No No Yes 2005 74 No No Yes 75 No Yes Yes 76 No No Yes 77 No Yes Yes 78 No No Yes 79 No No No 80 No No No 2004 60 Yes No No 61 Yes No 62 No Yes No 63 Yes No No 64 Yes Yes Yes 66 No Yes No 67 No No No 68 No No No 70 No No No 71 Yes Yes Yes 72 No No No 2003 54 No No No 2002 47 Yes No Yes J. G. Davis Democratic 49 Yes No 50 Yes Yes 52 No No 34 Yes No Yes 36 Yes No No 38 No No No 39 Yes Yes Yes 1998 3 No Yes No P. Wilson Republican 45 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 5 8 9 10 207 209 211 215 218 184 186 187 188 161 163 164 165 166 167 126 128 129 130 131 133 134 135 136 138 139 140 100 101 103 104 106 61 62 63 64 64 36 37 Yes No No Yes No Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No Yes Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes No No Yes No No No Yes Yes No Yes No No Yes No No Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No Yes Yes No Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No No No No No No No Yes No No No No No P. Wilson Republican P. Wilson Republican P. Wilson Republican G. Deukmejian Republican G. Deukmejian Republican G. Deukmejian Republican G. Deukmejian Republican 46 38 Yes No 39 No No Yes 40 No No No 41 No No No 1982 9 No No No 11 No Yes 12 Yes Yes 13 No Yes 14 No No 14 No Yes 1980 8 Yes Yes Yes 10 No No 1978 5 No Yes 6 No No No 7 Yes No No 1976 13 No No No 14 No No Yes 1972 14 No No No 17 Yes No 18 No No No 19 No No 20 Yes Yes Yes 21 Yes No 22 Yes No 1970 18 No Yes Yes 1968 1A Yes Yes Yes 3 No Yes 9 No No No 1964 14 Yes Yes No 1956 4 No Yes No Total 112 41 29 34 Sources: Los Angeles Times, 1956-2008 E. G. Brown, Jr. Democratic E. G. Brown, Jr. Democratic E. G. Brown, Jr. Democratic J. Brown Democratic R. Reagan Republican R. Reagan R. Reagan Republican Republican E. G. Brown, Sr. G. J. Knight Democratic Republican 47 Table 3 OLS and Robust Regression of Voter Awareness of California Ballot Propositions, 1956-2008 Model Model 1 2 OLS Robust ** * 0.129 Robust General Election 0.135 Pres. Election -0.046 -0.052 -0.054 -0.055 Number of Ballot Measures -0.005 -0.006 -0.005 -0.005 Days to the Election - 0.048 ** -0.050 ** -0.050 ** -0.052 0.123 *** 0.118 *** 0.117 *** 0.134 OLS * 0.123 Media Coverage 0.115 N.P Endorsement -0.029 -0.023 -0.033 -0.030 Gov. Endorsement -0.002 -0.010 0.002 -0.002 Budget and Tax - 0.046 -0.053 -0.046 -0.047 Civil Rights 0.171 0.168 0.173 0.174 Education 0.003 0.005 -0.003 -0.002 Gov. Structure -0.006 -0.013 -0.001 -0.005 Indian Gaming 0.224 Law, Bus., & Ins. Reg. 0.066 0.074 0.074 0.076 Law Enforcement 0.056 0.004 0.070 0.055 *** 0.238 ** 0.211 ** 0.213 48 Water & Environment 0.019 0.018 ___ ___ Total Spending Pro Spending -0.066 0.021 0.020 0.121 0.139 ___ ___ ___ ___ -0.087 Negative Spending 0.226 ** 0.248 ** Constant 0.625 *** 0.637 *** N 107 R2 0.482 0.459 Adjusted R2 0.384 0.363 F-Test 4.88 107 *** 4.59 0.630 *** 107 *** 4.78 0.640 107 *** 4.14 *Significant at the .05 level;**significant at the .01 level;***significant at the .001 level Number of Measures, Days to an Election, and Campaign Spending coefficients are standardized. Presidential Election, General Election, Newspaper Endorsement, and Governor Endorsement are coded as dummy variables (1 = yes, 0 = no). Interpretation Table 1 indicates that the average aggregate voter awareness of ballot propositions in California from 1956 to 2008 is 62 percent with a standard deviation of 19 percent. Table 2 illustrates whether a ballot proposition was endorsed by the L. A. Times, and, or the acting governor. Of the 112 ballot propositions considered for this analysis, 29 were endorsed by the L. A. Times, 34 received a gubernatorial endorsement, and 41 were enacted by voters. 49 Table 3 reports the results from the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) and robust regression results for both models. The total of cases utilized in this analysis is (N= 107); five cases were dropped for missing or incomplete data. According to the OLS results from Model 1, the political environment explains 48 percent of the variation in ballot awareness using a one-tailed test (p < .05). This verifies the importance of the political environment reported by Nicholson’s (2003) analysis. However, contrary to Nicholson (2003), one of the independent variables used in the model original model was not found to be statistically significant predictors of voter awareness of a ballot proposition—this was the number of ballot measures. On average, voter awareness of ballot propositions is 14 percent higher in general elections than primary elections. The OLS results do not provide evidence that there is a difference in voter awareness between presidential and mid-term elections. Similarly, the results do not verify that the number of ballot measures during an election cycle have an effect, positively or negatively, on aggregate levels of voter awareness. The days to the election have an effect on voter awareness of ballot propositions; on average each day closer to an election, voter awareness increases by half of one percent. The amount of media coverage a ballot proposition receives is a strong indicator of how well a proposition will be known to voters. Propositions that receive front-page coverage in the L. A. Times, on average, have a 12 percent higher rate of voter awareness. Contrary to expectation, an endorsement from the L. A. Times, or the governor in office at the time of an election was not found to have any influence on voter awareness. The content of a ballot proposition does have an effect on voter awareness. Model 2 50 indicates that ballot propositions that address civil rights issues have a 17 percent higher level of voter awareness on average. Both models indicate that Indian gaming propositions have a 22 percent higher level of voter awareness. The results from model 2 indicate that a higher level of total campaign spending increases voter awareness by 12 percent. Model 2, verifies that campaign spending increases voter awareness; however, positive spending does not have much effect. Negative campaign spending is the strongest predictor of voter awareness of a ballot proposition. Individual Variable Interpretation During a general election there is an average 0.14 increase in voter awareness of a ballot proposition when compared to a regularly scheduled election cycle, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = 2.58, p = 0.01. During a presidential election there is an average 0.05 decrease in voter awareness of a ballot proposition when compared to a regularly scheduled election cycle, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = -1.48, p = 0.14. For every one standard deviation decrease in the number of ballot measures during an election cycle, there is an average 0.05 reduction in voter awareness of a ballot proposition, holding constant the effects on y of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = -1.84, p = 0.07. 51 For every one standard deviation decrease in the number of days away from an election, there is an average 0.05 reduction in voter awareness of a ballot proposition, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = -2.70, p = 0.01. Ballot propositions that receive front page news coverage from the L. A. Times the day after an election have an average 0.12 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that do not receive front page attention, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = 3.64, p < 0.01. Ballot propositions that receive an endorsement from the L. A. Times have an average -0.03 reduction in voter awareness when compared to a ballot proposition that does not receive an endorsement, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = -0.82, p = 0.41. Ballot propositions that receive a gubernatorial endorsement have an average -0.002 reduction in voter awareness when compared to a ballot proposition that does not receive an endorsement, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = -0.07, p = 0.99. Ballot propositions that address civil rights issues have an average 0.17 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = 1.85, p = 0.07. 52 Ballot propositions that address education have an average 0.002 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = 0.05, p = 0.96. Ballot propositions that address budget and taxes have an average 0.05 lower rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = -1.02, p = 0.31. Ballot propositions that address law enforcement have an average 0.05 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = 0.94, p = 0.35. Ballot propositions that address Law, Business, and Insurance Regulation have an average 0.06 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is not statistically significant t = 1.00, p = 0.32. Ballot propositions that address Government Structure have an average 0.01 lower rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = -0.12, p = 0.91. Ballot propositions that address Water and Environmental issues have an average 0.01 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding 53 constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = 0.29, p = 0.77. Ballot propositions that address Indian gaming have an average 0.22 higher rate of voter awareness than propositions that address other issues, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = 3.36, p < 0.01. For every one standard deviation change in the amount of positive campaign spending for a ballot initiative, there is an average 0.07 decrease of voter awareness of a ballot proposition, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = -0.07, p = 0.44. For every one standard deviation change in the amount of negative campaign spending against a ballot initiative, there is an average 0.22 increase in voter awareness of a ballot proposition, holding constant the effects on awareness of the other variables; this is statistically significant t = 3.08, p < 0.01. Hypothesis Tests Hypothesis 1 An OLS regression analysis predicting ballot proposition awareness scores from the political environment model produced a coefficient of 0.63 with an R2 = 0.48, using a one-tailed test (p < 0.05). This means that the hypothesis test fails to reject that the political environment in which an election takes place has an effect on ballot proposition awareness. 54 Hypothesis 2 An OLS regression analysis, predicting ballot proposition awareness scores from a gubernatorial endorsement was not statistically significant; coefficient = -0.002, t = 0.07, using a one-tailed test (p = 0.94). The variable for Governor Endorsement has a p value larger than 0.05; therefore the null hypothesis cannot be rejected and the alternative hypothesis must be accepted. This means that voter awareness of a ballot proposition does not increase when acting governor of the State of California endorses the direct policy proposal. Hypothesis 3 An OLS regression analysis, predicting ballot proposition awareness scores from an endorsement made by the L. A. Times was not statistically significant; coefficient = 0.03, t = - 0.82, using a one-tailed test (p = 0.41). The variable for L.A. Times endorsement has a p-value larger than 0.05, therefore the hypothesis cannot be accepted and the alternative hypothesis that an endorsement by the L.A. Times does not increase voter awareness of a ballot proposition. This analysis finds evidence to support Nicholson’s (2003) original results, which show that the political environment during an election cycle does have an influence on individual awareness of ballot proposition awareness. However, the analysis yields insufficient evidence to suggest that an endorsement from the governor, or the L. A. Times increases voter awareness of ballot propositions. 55 Summary This chapter discussed the data collection, coding of the dependent and independent variables, and the results of the OLS and robust regression analysis. The most significant finding of this chapter is that there is strong evidence for the importance of the political environment originally proposed by Nicholson (2003) for ballot proposition elections. Endorsements made by the L. A. Times and the Governor of California were not found to have significant influence on voter awareness of ballot propositions. The final chapter provides the conclusion of the study based on the aforementioned analysis of data, and recommendations for future research. 56 Chapter 5 CONCLUSION Direct democracy is a form of political participation in which individual citizens are able to make decisions about policy that will have an impact on the larger population. Direct democratic elections place a great deal of power and responsibility within the hands of voters, because the process bypasses the institutional lawmaking arena. Research on direct democracy has focused on whether individual citizens have the capacity assume such power and responsibility. The majority of research in this area typically focuses on individual level measures, such as: demographic and background data; level of knowledge about an issue; how voters make policy decisions; and how voters become informed. Until recently, external factors which frame a political election cycle and levels of voter awareness about ballot propositions have not been taken into account. Addressing this gap in the literature, Nicholson (2003) examined whether the political environment affects voter awareness of ballot propositions. Nicholson found the political environment plays a significant role in voter awareness of ballot propositions. This analysis extends the assessment of voter awareness. First, by re-testing the importance of the political environment during proposition elections. Second, by measuring the effect of elite endorsements on voter awareness of specific ballot propositions. Assessing the influence of elite endorsements is an important move, because ballot proposition elections do not have the partisan labeling that are characteristic of candidate-centered elections. The lack of partisan labeling in ballot elections raises the question of whether voters are able to identify policy proposals and 57 compare them with their own partisan preferences. Previous research has shown that elite endorsements may act as a guide for voters when partisan labels are not present. This analysis assessed these claims by measuring the impact elite endorsements have on voter awareness of ballot proposition elections. The findings of this analysis substantiate the importance of the political environment during an election, confirming the results initially reported by Nicholson (2003). The political environment provides an important context to an election cycle; therefore, it should be considered along with individual-level measures when assessing voter awareness of political issues, as well as attempts to predict voter behavior during an election. Alongside confirming the importance of the political environment during ballot elections, this analysis had several other significant findings. First, voter awareness was found to be higher during midterm elections. This finding complements Donovan, Tolbert, and Smith’s (2009) results which predict that states with a direct democratic process will generally have higher rates of voter turnout during a midterm election. Second, negative spending had a significant impact on ballot proposition awareness. This supports similar research findings on campaign spending during ballot initiative elections (Bowler & Donovan, 2003; Cronin, 1989; Magleby 1984; Nicholon, 2003; Shockly, 1980; Zisk 1987). While total campaign spending was found to have a significant effect on ballot proposition awareness, positive spending did not. This contradicts what one would expect to find according to Stratman (2006) who argues, 58 “The campaigning of supporting interest groups is at least as productive as that of opposing interest groups” (p. 788). Third, of all ballot propositions topics, Indian gaming initiatives were found to be the most salient. On average, voter awareness of an Indian gaming initiative ballot was 23 percent higher than other initiatives. This is an interesting finding and more research should be directed toward understanding how and why the content of a ballot proposition affects voter awareness. While this analysis confirms the impact of the political environment, there is insufficient evidence to support the argument that political elites increase ballot proposition awareness during an election cycle. This finding seems counterintuitive to what might be expected, given the findings of previous research on elite influence (Karp 1998, Smith, 2002), and the fact that the California Governor, and the L. A. Times have a considerable platform to reach a mass audience. It is curious why endorsements made by highly visible political elites did not increase the salience of ballot propositions. If gubernatorial and newspaper endorsements were found to increase ballot proposition awareness, this would have strengthened the argument that voting cues take the place of partisan labels during direct democratic elections. Given the confirmation that media coverage and negative campaign spending have a strong influence on voter awareness, one would have to question whether voting cues from political elites are enough to compete with the news and campaign advertising in terms of gaining voter attention—the results of this analysis indicate that they are not. However, further research, which takes 59 a more expansive view of the elite influence of voter awareness of ballot propositions, is needed. Although voter behavior was not the focus of this analysis, an attempt was made to determine whether an endorsement from a political elite has an effect on the success or failure of a ballot proposition. While there is insufficient evidence to support the argument that an elite endorsement increases voter awareness of a ballot proposition, there is evidence that a gubernatorial endorsement strengthens the chances of ballot proposition success. This finding indicates that political elites do influence voters, and is consistent with Karp (1998) and Smith (2002). However, further research is needed which focuses specifically on how elite endorsements may increase ballot proposition success while failing to increasing voter awareness. This analysis does not suggest that endorsements from other political elites, such as other statewide office holders, will not increase awareness of ballot propositions. Further analysis, which expands upon this analysis of political elite endorsements, both in terms of voter awareness and voter behavior in ballot proposition elections is necessary. Finally, the results of this research contribute to the larger debates over direct democracy. Many observers of the direct democratic process question the competence and ability of voters to make decisions in direct democratic elections; however, the majority of this criticism only accounts for individual-level variables. The political environment extends well beyond individual-level variables by creating the context in which political information is transmitted and received. The political environment plays a significant role in the: if, when, where, why, and how voters receive political 60 information. The assessment of the environmental variables that contribute to higher levels of voter awareness does not mean that these voters will be better informed about an issue, but they are a good place to start, as voters can only gain higher levels of information about political issues to the extent that they are aware of them. 61 REFERENCES Adams, C. F. (1851). The works of John Adams, second President of the United States: With a life story of the author, notes and illustrations (Vol. 5). Boston: Little and Brown. Ansolobehere, S., & Iyengar, S. (1995). Going negative: How political advertisements shrink and polarize the electorate. New York: Free Press. Bali, V. A., & Davis, B. C. (2007). One more piece to make us puzzle: The initiative process and legislators’ reelection chances. Political Research Quarterly, 60(2), 215-229. Bartels, L. (1996). Uniformed votes: Information effects in Presidential Elections. American Journal of Political Science, 40, 194-230. Behr, R. L., & Iyengar, S. (1985). Television news, real-world cues, and changes in the public agenda. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 49, 38-57. Bowler, S. T., & Donovan, T. (2002). Democracy, institutions and attitudes about citizen government. British Journal of Political Science, 32(2). Bowler, S. T., & Donovan, T. (1998). Demanding choices: opinion, voting, and direct democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Bowler, S, T., Donovan, T., & Happ, T. (1992). Ballot propositions and information costs: Direct democracy and the fatigued voter. Western Political Quarterly 45, 559-568. Bowler, S. T., Donovan, T., & Tolbert, C. J. (1998). Citizens as legislators: Direct democracy in the United States. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press. 62 Brady, H. E., & Johnson, R. (1987). What’s the primary message: Horse race or issue journalism? In G.R. Orren, & N.W. Polsby (Eds.), Media and momentum (pp. 127-186). Chatham, NJ: Chatham House. Branton, R. (2003). Examining individual-level voting behavior on state ballot propositions. Political Research Quarterly, 56(3), 367-377. Broh, A. C. (1977). Horse race journalism: Reporting the polls in the 1976 presidential election. Public Opinion Quarterly, 41, 514-529. Converse, P. (1964). The nature and belief systems in mass publics. In D. E. Apter (Ed.), Ideology and discontent (pp. 206-261). New York: Free Press. Conover, P. J.; Feldman, S. (1981). The origins and meaning of Liberal/Conservative self-identification. American Journal of Political Science, 25, 617-645. Cook, F. L., Tyler, T. R., Goetz, E. G., Gordon, M. T., Protess, D., Leff, D. R., & Molotch, H. L. (1983). Media and agenda setting: Effects on the public, interest group leaders, policy makers, and policy. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 47, 1635. Cronin, T. (1989). Direct democracy: The politics of initiative, referendum, and recall. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Delli-Carpini, M. X., & Keeter, S. (1996). What Americans know about politics and why it matters. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper and Row. Donovan, T.; Tolbert, C. J.; Smith, . (2009). Political engagement, mobilization, and direct democracy. Public Opinion Quarterly, 73(1), 98–118. 63 Eaton, A. H. (1912). Oregon system: The story of direct legislation in Oregon. Chicago: A.C. McClurg & Co. Freedman, P.; & Goldstien, K. (1999). Campaign advertising and voter turnout: new evidence for a stimulation effect. The Journal of Politics, 64, 721-740. Gafke, R., & Leuthold, D. (1979). The effect on voters of misleading, confusing and difficult ballot titles. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 43, 394-401. Gamble, B. S. (1997). Putting civil rights to a popular vote. American Journal of Political Science, 41(1), 245-269. Gerber, E. R. (1998). Pressuring legislatures through the use of initiatives: Two forms of indirect influence. In S. Bowler, T. Donovan, & C. Tolbert (Eds.), Citizens as legislators: Direct democracy in the United States (pp. 191-208). Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press. Gerber, E. R.; & Lupia, A. (1995). Campaign competition and policy responsiveness in direct legislation elections. Political Behavior, 17(3), 287-306. Goldstein, K., & Freedman, P. (1999). Measuring media exposure and the effects of negative campaign ads. American Journal of Political Science, 43, 1189-1208. Hadwiger, D. (1992). Money, turnout and ballot measure success in California cities. Western Political Quarterly 45, 539-547. Hamilton, A.; Jay, J.; & Madison, J. (1788). Federalist on the new constitution writing in 1788. Philadelphia, PA: Philip Warner. 64 Hall-Jamison, K., & Waldman, P. (2003). The Press Effect: Politicians, Journalists, and the Stories That Shape the Political World. New York: Cambridge University Press. Haynes, G. H. (1907). The education of voters. Political Science Quarterly, 22(3), 484497. Hibbing, J.; Theiss-Morse, E. (2002). Stealth democracy: American’s beliefs about how democracy should work. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press. Karp, J. (1998). Influence of elite endorsements in ballot initiative campaigns. In S. Bowler, T. Donovan, & C. J. Tolbert (Eds.), Citizens as legislators: Direct democracy in the United States (pp. 149-165). Columbus, OH: Ohio State University Press. Key, V. O. (1966). The responsible electorate: Rationality in presidential voting 19361960. New York. Vintage. Kuklinski, J. H., & Quirk, P. (2000). Reconsidering the rational public: Heuristics, cognition, and mass opinion. In A. Lupia, M. McCubbins & S. Popkin (Eds.), Elements of reason: Understanding and expanding the limits of political rationality (pp.153-182). New York: Cambridge Press University. Lascher, Jr. E. L., Hagen, M. G., & Rochlin, S. A. (1996). The gun behind the door? Ballot initiatives state policies and public opinion. The Journal of Politics 58(3), 760-775. Lau, R., & Redlawski, D. (2000). Advantages and disadvantages of cognitive heuristics in political decision making. American Journal of Political Science, 45, 951-971. 65 Lewkowicz, M. A. (2006). The effectiveness of elite cues as heuristics in proposition elections. American Politics Research, 34, 51-68. Lowrie, S. G. (1911). New forms of the initiative and referendum. The American Political Science Review, 5(4), 566-572. Lupia, A. (1994). Shortcuts versus encyclopedias: Information and voting behavior in California insurance reform elections. The American Political Science Review, 88, 63-76. Lupia, A.; Matsusaka, J. G. (2004). Direct democracy: new approaches to old questions. Annual Review of Political Science, 7, 463-482. Magleby, D. (1984). Direct legislation: Voting on ballot propositions in the United States. Baltimore: John Hopkins University Press. Mauser, G. A.; Margolis, M. (1990). Manipulating Public Opinion: essays on public opinion as a dependent variable (pp.95-115). Pacific Grove, CA: Brooks/ Cole Mondak, J. (1993). Public opinion and heuristic processing of source cues. Political Behavior, 15, 167-192. Moore, F. (1857). American eloquence: a collection of speeches and addresses by the most eminent orators of America. New York, NY: Appleton and Company. Morrison, J. H. (2009). The political philosophy of George Washington. Maryland: John Hopkins Press. Mutz, D. C., & Soss J. (1997). Reading public opinion: The influence of news coverage on perceptions of public Sentiment. The Public Opinion Quarterly, 61, 431-451. 66 Nicholson, S. P. (2003). The political environment and ballot proposition awareness. American Journal of Political Science, 47, 403-410. Nicholson, S. P. (2005). Voting the agenda: candidates, elections, and ballot propositions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Padover, S. K. (Ed.). (1939). Democracy. New York: Greenwood Press. Page, S., & Shapiro, R. (1992). The rational public. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Patterson, T. E. (1980). The mass media election. New York: Praeger. Sniderman, P. M., Brody, R., & Tetlock, P. (1991). Reasoning and choice: Explorations in political psychology. New York: Cambridge University Press. Shockley, J. S. (1980). The initiative process in Colorado politics: An assessment. Boulder, CO: University of Colorado, Boulder Bureau of Governmental Research and Service. Smith, M. (2002). Ballot initiatives and the democratic citizen. The Journal of Politics, 64, 892-903. Stourzh, G. (1970). Alexander Hamilton and the idea of Republican Government. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Stratmann, T. (2006). Is spending more potent for or against a proposition? Evidence from ballot measures. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3), 788–801. 67 Tolbert, C. (1998). Changing Rules for State Legislators: Direct Democracy and governance Policies. In S. Bowler, T. Donovan and C. Tolbert (Eds.), Citizens as legislators: direct democracy in the United States. Columbus, OH: Ohio State University. Walker, J. L. (1966). Ballot forms and voter fatigue: An analysis of the office block and party column ballots. Midwest Journal of Political Science, 10(4), 448-463. Yarbrough, J. M. (2006). The essential Jefferson. Indianapolis, IN: Hackett Zaller, J. R. (1992). The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. New York: Cambridge University Press. Zisk, B. H. (1987). Money, media, and the grass roots: State ballot issues and the electoral process. Newbury Park, CA: Sage.