WORKERS COOPERATIVES 1. Introduction

advertisement
WORKERS COOPERATIVES
1. Introduction
A. The three main types of business operating in Canada are:
(a) sole proprietorship, where ownership of and responsibility for the
business rests with the individual proprietor; and profits and losses accrue to
the owner; the business is not a legal entity separate from the owner; there is
unlimited personal liability on the part of the owner; the sole proprietor may
hire employees and conduct business through agents.
(b) partnership, where ownership of and responsibility for the partnership
rest with two or more partners; profits and losses are shared by the partners;
there is unlimited personal liability, though the partnership agreement may
specify the extent of a partner’s share of liability; partnerships may be
created inadvertently by the conduct of the partners; the partnership is not a
separate legal entity from the individuals forming the partnership;
partnerships may hire employees and be represented by agents.
(c) corporation, which is a legal entity separate from the individual
members who make up the corporation; profits and losses accrue to the
corporation, not to the individual members; the corporation can hire
employees and act through agents; a corporation can be owned by an
individual or by two or more individuals; there can be limited personal
liability for the owners of the corporation for losses and debts of the
corporation.
Other forms of working together include the non-profit society, the
cooperative, the holding corporation (a corporation that holds shares in
other corporations), and the joint venture where several incorporated
corporations band together to undertake a major project. They may form a
separate corporation or a partnership.
A common feature of sole proprietorships, partnerships, and corporations is
that typically employees of the organizations have no ownership rights as
employees. Employees may be shareholders in the corporation that employs
them and so have the rights of shareholders. However, this does not give
employees managerial or directorial control of the business. They have no
effective ownership rights.
1
B. Difficulties for employees
If the labour market experiences a shortage of labour, employees can benefit
from relatively high wages. However, under capitalism, workers appear to
be under constant pressure from corporate and government policies designed
to reduce labour costs. Historically, a variety of devices have been used by
employers to reduce labour costs, including replacing labour with
automation, machinery, breaking down complex skilled work into lowskilled tasks, importation of low-skilled, low-wage labour, contracting out
work to companies that use low-skilled, cheap labour, moving business
operations to low-wage countries, increasing the intensity of work to
demand more output and effort for the same pay, and resisting the creation
of trade unions or, as in Argentina at present, workers cooperatives.
Today, western governments generally support low-wage policies by
facilitating the movement of labour and capital across national boundaries.
Increased “free trade” and the reduction or elimination of tariff barriers
allows low wage countries to sell their products at lower prices in western
countries, thus undermining the viability of domestic enterprises.
The difficulty for employees and their lack of rights of ownership of the
enterprise that employs them, is that they lack the power to decide or control
what level of profit is acceptable, the level of wages and benefits paid, the
technology used, whether the enterprise will cease operations or move to
another location, whether the enterprise will declare bankruptcy and so on.
By having no control over whether an enterprise will remain active in the
community in which they live, employees are also vulnerable to the risk or
hardship of the economic and social collapse of their community if their
employer is a major one, and decides to move its production or service
enterprises elsewhere, in the interest of higher profits.
The serious economic and social impact of the flight of major corporations
from communities is illustrated by General Motors’ flight from Flint,
Michigan in the 1990s. Workers were unable to resist the “downsizing” and
eventual closure of Buick plants. Indeed, the United Auto Workers (UAW)
tended to thwart workers’ resistance. The flight of capital and business from
Argentina in the 1990s also left workers in dire straits. Such flights of capital
are generally justified by appeal to efficiency, competitiveness, and
profitability. However, such measures only represent some of the indicators
2
of societal wellbeing and progress. If other measures of societal wellbeing
are used, profit and efficiency tell a highly distorted tale. For example, the
depletion of natural resources is not counted in the balance sheet of
corporations or in measures of gross domestic product (GDP). Pollution and
its negative impact on health, reduced leisure time, income distribution,
reduced lifespan of consumer durable products and so on are excluded from
corporate and government accounting, giving the illusion of greater
wellbeing and progress than is actually delivered by capitalism (see Halstead
and Cobb on Library Reserve for more realistic measures of wellbeing and
progress).
While cooperatives are not the most common form of business entity,
provincial legislation governs them in each Canadian province. In Alberta,
the legislation is the Cooperatives Act, R.S.A. Chapter C-28.1. The types of
cooperatives provided by the legislation are: (i) housing; (ii) employment;
(iii) multi-stakeholder; and (iv) new generation. In the modern era,
worker and consumer cooperatives began in Rochdale, England in the 19 th
Century.
They remain there and in Canada as agricultural producer co-ops, consumer
co-ops, credit unions, and workers’ co-ops, housing co-ops and others.
2. Mondragon
Robert Gilman in Mondragon: the Remarkable Achievement asks “what
is the Mondragón story, and why is it so important?” Its roots go back
at least into the Spanish Civil War, but we can begin in 1941 when a
young Basque priest, Father Jose Maria Arizmendiaretta (Arizmendi)
came to Mondragón. Arizmendi, like most Basques, had fought on the
losing republican side. He had been imprisoned as a POW and, after his
release, had entered the church. His bishop had sent him to Mondragón with
the charge of tending to the young, and he began his work by teaching in the
apprentice school of the Union Cerrajera, the main industrial company in
town. He soon found this too limiting, and by 1943 he had opened a
technical training school with the support of the townspeople. In this
school, he provided his students with not only a good technical
education, but also a sophisticated understanding of Catholic Social
Doctrine with its emphasis on cooperation and "the primacy of labour
among the factors of production".
3
After continuing their education, a number of his students tried, but without
success, to apply his teachings within the traditional companies where they
had found work. By 1954, five of his original 11 decided to form a new
company (ULGOR) where they could implement these teachings, and by
1956, after raising funds from local townspeople, they opened their factory
with 24 worker-members.
Twenty-six years later, in 1982, the Mondragón Cooperative Movement
had 20,000 worker-members, 85 industrial cooperatives (producing
everything from machine tools to refrigerators to electronic equipment),
6 agricultural cooperatives, 2 service cooperatives, 43 cooperative
schools, 14 housing cooperatives, a large consumer/worker cooperative
with over forty stores, plus four second level cooperatives that provide
services to the primary cooperatives. These four are a bank (Caja
Laboral Popular) with 120 branch offices, a technological research
institute (Ikerlan), the League of Education and Culture (including a
Polytechnical College, a Business School and a Professional College),
and a social security and medical cooperative (Lagun-Aro). During this
remarkable growth they have had only one failure - a fishing
cooperative. At the end of 2003, the Mondragon Cooperative had 68,260
employee members in 218 companies of which around half were
cooperatives. Combined assets of 16.3 billion euros, 3.3 billion profits
and total sales of 9.6 billion euros (2.5 billion international).
Around half of total employees are co-op members – mainly those in the
Basque Region. There are two reasons for this proportion. Some workers
are only temporary non-members, and in many countries into which
MCC has ventures, there is no cooperative legislation. The MCC is
currently reviewing policy on the issue of membership. This matter appears
to confirm the difficulties that attend rapid growth.
To appreciate these statistics, it helps to see them against the usual success
rates for both new small businesses and producer cooperatives in general,
neither of which has been very impressive. For example, in America 80 to
90 percent of new small businesses fail within 5 years. The situation with
producer-cooperatives, which have been tried in various forms since the
middle of the 19th century, is more complex, but basically most have either
failed through poor management or succeeded as businesses only to be
bought out after a short cooperative life.
4
What makes the Mondragón movement so effective? Gilman suggests three
key elements: (http://www.context.org/ICLIB/IC02/Gilman2.htm)
1) The cultural and economic condition of the Basque region;
2) The specific pattern of rights and responsibilities of workermembers;
3) The supporting institutions they have developed, particularly their
bank.
The Basques are a proud, industrious, thrifty, and socially cohesive people
with strong nationalist ambitions. The Spanish Civil War left their economy
devastated and left them politically under the control of a vengeful,
repressive and suspicious central government. These conditions seem to
have been a great help in focusing Basque energy into the Mondragón
movement since it provided a means of rebuilding their economy and
expressing the strength of their community in a way that was not seen as
politically threatening. Whether or not Mondragón type businesses could
function as well in a less socially cohesive setting is currently an
unanswered question.
The financial and organizational structure of these cooperatives is, in
significant details, different from many of the less successful British and
American attempts. The essential features of their system are as follows:
1) All employees and only employees are members, with a one person one vote control of the Board of Directors (all of whom must also be
worker-members).
2) The Board of Directors selects the top management, which then
functions in a more or less conventional way. However, the general
membership also independently elects a Watchdog Council to monitor
the financial performance of the cooperative and a Social Council which
deals with a wide range of personnel affairs and makes binding
decisions on safety, pay scale, and social welfare.
3) All new worker-members must contribute (over two years) around
$5000 to the capital of the cooperative. While this may seem like a large
sum, it is still only about 10% of the capital cost of creating the new job, and
5
it emphasizes the seriousness with which they take their role as owners as
well as workers. It can be paid in installments from wages.
4) To insure a sense of equality and solidarity among all the workermembers, they restrict the range of highest pay to lowest pay to an
effective ratio of 6 to 1. (Once 3 to 1). In practice this means that the
lowest paid earn more than comparable workers in ordinary companies,
while the executives earn less than their capitalist peers. Those managers
who have grown up within the system seem to appreciate the non-monetary
rewards, but this rule has so far prevented the establishment of a cooperative
hospital. (The doctors aren't willing to lower their pay scale.)
5) Only part of the cooperative's earnings are paid out as immediate
"wages", while the rest are retained in internal capital accounts that are
assigned to each worker but available to them only when they retire.
They have done this in a way that allows each worker to benefit from the
equity value of his or her ownership, but does not threaten the integrity of
the cooperative. Unlike ordinary corporate shares, these internal accounts
cannot be sold and they carry no voting rights. There is some criticism that
insufficient money is paid into personal capital accounts and too much into
reserves, which are collectively owned but not accessible by individual
members.
The second level cooperatives, for example the bank, have a slightly
different structure. As usual, all workers are members, but the other
cooperatives are also considered members. (Unlike credit unions and
mutual savings banks, depositors are not members.) The Board of Directors
is made up of representatives from the other cooperatives (2/3) as well as
worker- members of the bank (1/3). Aside from this broader definition of
membership, the internal structure of the second level cooperatives is similar
to that of the others.
The bank has two main divisions, the Banking Division and the
“Empresarial Division”. The Banking Division provides normal
banking service to its 1/2 million customers through 120 branch offices.
It also serves as a major source of new capital for the first level
cooperatives. The unique feature of the bank, however, is the
“Empresarial Division”, whose basic function is to aid in the creation of
new cooperatives and provide management assistance to the existing
6
ones, especially when they are making any major changes such as
entering a new market or launching a new product.
The following list of departments give some idea of the scope that the staffmembers of this division cover: Research, Library and Documentation
Center, Agricultural/Food, Industrial Products, Industrial Promotion and
Intervention, Export, Marketing, Productions, Personnel, AdministrativeFinancial, Legal, Auditing, Information and Control, Urban Planning,
Industrial Building, and Housing.
The Bank also serves as the hub of the whole Mondragón Cooperative
Movement. Each cooperative runs itself through its own Board of Directors,
but they are all linked to the bank (and each other) through a "Contract of
Association". This contract grants the cooperative membership rights in the
bank, and spells out the basic principles the cooperative must follow to be
part of the Mondragón movement. There are also special relationships
worked out between cooperatives in related areas so that they can work
together like the divisions of a larger company.
The MCC attributes its success to six key points:
(See http://www.mondragon.mcc.es/ing/contacto/faqs.html#)
(a) the vision of its founder father Jose Maria Arizmediarreta, with
his emphasis on youth, education and training and the Catholic
doctrine of the primacy of labour over capital;
(b) the participation of workers in management, and in the investment
of capital, as motivation;
(c) planned, rigorous attention to efficiency, and profitability on the
part of management;
(d) reinvestment of practically all profits generated;
(e) co-operation among the different enterprises on matters of
finance and social welfare;
7
(f) education, training and lifelong learning within the cooperatives;
MCC has a university accessible to any student with the academic
admission qualifications.
The advantages of cooperative membership appear to be higher wages,
better pensions, and more secure employment for non-managerial
workers, than that available to comparable workers in the community.
Greater security arises from the lesser risk of redundancy due to flight
of capital as with regular corporations. Managers tend to be paid less
than their counterparts in the capitalist system.
MCC does not see cooperatives as an alternative to capitalism but
rather as a form of organization that benefits from modern theories of
management and motivation of employees. There are inevitable tradeoffs. In order to increase job security and long-term income security,
workers in the co-ops may have to sacrifice short-term earnings. While
worker participation in management carries benefits of an effective
voice, it requires action by individual workers. The co-ops’ attachment
to their respective communities encourages action by the co-op to
contribute to the economic and cultural health of the community. Such
contributions are not just monetary but the creation of educational,
social and cultural organizations within their communities.
The MCC also believes its form of organization resolves the industrial
conflict traditionally associate with collective and individual
employee/management relations.
8
Download