LIBA L O N D O N I N V E S TM E N T B AN K I N G A S S O C I A T I O N 6 Frederick's Place, London, EC2R 8BT T el: 0 2 0 7 7 9 6 3 6 0 6 F a x: 0 2 0 7 7 9 6 4 3 4 5 e-mail: liba@liba.org.uk website: www.liba.org.uk COMMISSION CONSULTATION ON THE REVISION OF THE INVESMENT SERVICES DIRECTIVE A RESPONSE BY THE LONDON INVESTMENT BANKING ASSOCIATION (LIBA) Summary of key issues Introduction Relationship between the ISD review and the Lamfalussy process Proposed regulatory classification Proposed adjustments to scope Definitions Proposed investment firm regime High-level principles for regulated markets Clearing and settlement Paragraphs 1-4 Paragraphs 5-14 Paragraphs 15-27 Paragraphs 28-36 Paragraphs 37-39 Paragraphs 40-56 Paragraphs 57-59 Paragraph 60 Annexes: List of Members of LIBA Extract from LIBA’s response to the Commission’s November 2000 Communication: obstacles to cross-border business _____________________________________________________________________ SUMMARY OF KEY ISSUES The review of the ISD is central to the Financial Services Action Plan. It is a vital opportunity to use the Lamfalussy approach to maximise the quality of the legislative and regulatory framework for European investment services, in order to encourage the development of efficient European markets, minimise cost of capital for businesses, and provide investors with rates of return which reflect the risks taken (paragraphs 5 – 14 below). In most respects the existing ISD has worked well. It has provided a framework within which European capital markets have been able to expand and innovate. It will be vital for the revised ISD to enable continuation of this expansion and development, which has hugely benefited investors, businesses, and European prosperity. A global perspective is essential, to ensure that these benefits remain in the EU, and markets are not driven elsewhere (paragraph 7). Where the existing ISD has not worked well, the review should focus on targeted amendments and effective enforcement. We welcome the proposals to address shortcomings in the internal market, especially: mutual recognition of country of origin requirements for all types of business, limiting the ability of Member States to impose their own conduct of 1 business and marketing rules on incoming cross-border business (paragraph 47): but this should not be contingent on prior harmonisation, especially in relation to wholesale business; appropriate definition of and limited rules regime for professional investors (paragraphs 38, 39, and 45): but the definition needs to be broader and more flexible, removal of barriers to cross-border business, especially the abolition of the connection requirement for foreign exchange business, and of the ability of Member States to impose ‘concentration requirements’ (paragraphs 19, 34, 51): but the proposals on reporting of OTC trades could be even more harmful than existing concentration rules. But a number of the proposals would impose too interventionist and inflexible a framework on European markets, especially on inter-professional transactions. Such contentious and fundamental changes would risk delay in achieving more urgent, realistic and beneficial improvements. The concerns which give rise to them should be dealt with in a much more targeted and proportionate way (paragraphs 15 – 27). Particular concerns are: the proposed restructuring of regulatory classifications of EU markets and exchanges is too interventionist and would damage European markets; the proposed mandatory reporting and immediate publication of OTC trades in securities traded on ‘regulated markets’ would cut across the existing balance between transparency and liquidity, and would seriously harm European OTC markets. The Lamfalussy approach should be applied as follows: Level 1 framework directive: to define the scope and key concepts, and to establish principles to govern the flexible use, but also to limit the misuse, of implementing measures Level 2 implementing measures to enable the adaptation of Level 1 definitions in the light of changing circumstances, and to enable the flexible application of Level 1 principles to the different characteristics and dynamics of different markets Level 3 cooperation to develop more detailed regulatory standards, where necessary and appropriate, with improved coordination between the Commission’s and CESR’s policy development Level 4: effective and consistent enforcement of the directive full and responsive consultation with interested parties at all levels as the review develops, so that the revised ISD framework is fully adapted to EU markets and their users, and so commands the support of all (paragraph 14). 2 Introduction 1. LIBA represents the major European and international investment banks and securities houses which base their European operations in London. Our Members are major participants in European capital markets, and major providers of investment services to European investors and businesses. A list of our Members is attached as an Annex. 2. LIBA welcomes the opportunity to contribute expert opinions and advice whilst the Commission’s proposals are still at a formative stage. This response is consistent with our comments on the following consultations which have preceded or are running alongside it: the Commission’s November 2000 Communications on Upgrading the ISD and the Application of Article 11 of the ISD. FESCO/CESR 2000/2001 consultations on customer categorisation, harmonised standards and rules for conduct of business, and the regulation of ATSs. The 2001 Report of the Lamfalussy Committee of Wise Men, the conclusions of which we strongly supported Other Directives and proposals, including the 2000 Electronic Commerce Directive and the 2001 Proposals on Market Abuse, Prospectuses, and Transparency for issuers. 3. This response starts with a summary of the most important general principles which we think should guide the Commission’s further development of the proposed new ISD (see above). It then considers how the review should be brought into line with the Lamfalussy approach (paragraphs 5 to 14), proposes an alternative approach to the issues which surround the Commission’s proposals on regulatory classification and transparency (paragraphs 15 to 27) and concludes with a detailed analysis of the Commission’s proposals and draft amendments following the order of the consultation paper (paragraphs 28 to 60). 4. We have had the opportunity to see the responses of a number of other associations, and we particularly support the general approach of the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, the International Securities Market Association, and The Bond Market Association. The ISD review in the context of the Lamfalussy process 5. The efficient application of the ‘Lamfalussy approach’ to the review of the ISD involves basing legislation on fundamental public policy objectives and expert, market-aware analysis of the issues involved and the effect of legislative and regulatory intervention. This approach should in turn enable efficient and effective adoption and implementation of the revised ISD as one of the most important elements of the Financial Services Action Plan. 6. The Lamfalussy Report recommended that European policy development should be guided by fundamental public policy objectives. We suggest that in the case of the ISD review, these objectives should be: 3 to encourage the development of efficient European markets, to minimise the cost of capital for businesses in European markets, to provide returns for investors in European markets which reflect the risk taken. 7. It is particularly important to legislate for European capital markets with a global perspective. The existing ISD has been successful in enabling the expansion of existing European markets, the establishment of new markets and new trading mechanisms, the exploitation of new technologies, and the development of new instruments and new delivery mechanisms. These developments have enormously benefited investors and businesses in Europe, and rendered European markets highly competitive globally, by: giving access to a wide choice of innovative means of investing and raising capital and managing risk, and promoting competition, thereby minimising the cost of capital and maximising rates of return The revised ISD must maintain innovative and dynamic European markets. It should be noted that Europe’s most important competitor, the United States, is currently liberalising its markets (partly because of competition from Europe and other financial centres). It is therefore particularly important for Europe to avoid any legislative or regulatory restrictions which would render European markets uncompetitive internationally. If regulation is excessive or inefficient, markets will be driven outside the EU. It is much more difficult to regain a market that has been lost than it is to retain it in the first place. 8. The Commission’s July 2001 consultation on the amendment of the ISD can be divided into two main elements: Targeted liberalising amendments to resolve ambiguities, remove restrictions, and entrench the internal market and mutual recognition basis of the directive – broadly, and subject to a number of specific concerns detailed in paragraphs 28 to 60, these amendments command industry support, and are also consistent with Lamfalussy’s identified priorities; Wide-ranging restructuring of the conceptual framework of the ISD, replacing a flexible framework based on choice between regulated market and investment firm status with a rigid framework of regulated markets, ‘nonregulated’ markets, and investment firms, based on particular criteria. We believe this restructuring is intended to tackle public policy concerns about the existing regulatory framework in certain markets (notably equities) because of the perceived effect of competition between trading platforms and internalisation of order flows by investment firms. However, the proposed restructuring has given rise to widespread concern about harmful side-effects (see our detailed comments in paragraphs 15 to 27 below). It will be 4 important to ensure that urgently needed targeted amendments to the current legislation are not delayed by more controversial restructuring proposals. 9. The priority for the review of the ISD should be the liberalisation of markets and the elimination of barriers. The review should avoid either creating new barriers or providing an opening for Member States to retain existing barriers or introduce new ones. It should focus on agreeing and putting in place correctly targeted amendments, and effective enforcement of the directive. This approach will be consistent with both the Financial Services Action Plan and the Lamfalussy Report, and will deal quickly and effectively with the priority issues, in particular: the need for a properly functioning internal market based on mutual recognition of country of origin requirements for all types of business (on-line and off-line, wholesale and retail), the need for appropriate definition of and a limited rules regime for professional investors, reflecting their greater expertise and lesser need for protection against malpractice, the removal of restrictions, ambiguities or loopholes that can be exploited by Member States to restrict the internal market. 10. The proposed changes to the regulatory classification are too far-reaching, and would have many harmful side-effects. They are not justified as a response to the particular issues in particular markets which we understand they are intended to address (see details in paragraphs 15 to 27). They are also too inflexible: the ‘Level 1’ directive should not impose a single unadaptable framework on all markets. It should allow market forces to determine the structure of markets and encourage innovation and choice. We suggest an approach as follows: Level 1: Retention of the existing ISD’s flexible framework, combined with high-level framework principles (reflecting public policy objectives) dealing with issues of competition, market integrity, transparency etc. Level 2 legislation and Level 3 regulatory cooperation: Thorough analysis of the technical, commercial, and regulatory issues, in full consultation and cooperation with market experts and market participants, resulting in development of targeted measures which focus on the public policy concerns which arise in each market. 11. More generally, we suggest that Level 1 legislation should cover the following: Reinforcement of treaty principles: freedom to offer services cross-border; mutual recognition; access to markets; removal of restrictions Definition of scope and key concepts (e.g. professional investor) 5 Risk-based principles to govern the application of Level 2 legislation or Level 3 regulatory cooperation relating to detailed prudential, conduct of business, and market conduct standards. Such principles should ensure that Level 2 and Level 3 adapt flexibly to cater for the specific characteristics and dynamics of different markets. They should also set appropriate limits on implementing legislation: for instance, they should establish the principle of light regulation of business with professionals. 12. We suggest that Level 2 measures should cover the following: Adaptation of Level 1 definitions to enable flexibility in the light of changing circumstances Flexible and market-oriented application of Level 1 principles to the different characteristics and dynamics of different markets, in consultation with market experts and participants. 13. Level 3 cooperation should develop more detailed standards for regulated markets and investment firms where necessary and appropriate. These should be appropriately differentiated for different markets, developed in consultation with market experts and participants, and with improved coordination between CESR’s policy development and the work of the Commission and the European Securities Committee at Levels 1 and 2. 14. Consultation is a central plank of the Lamfalussy approach. We welcome the consultative approach which the Commission has adopted to the ISD review, complemented and supported by CESR’s consultations on conduct of business standards and the regulation of ATSs. The public hearing in Brussels on 18th and 19th September 2001 was a welcome opportunity for constructive discussion of the issues, although it also showed the difficulty of attaining agreed solutions, and demonstrated how important thorough analysis of the issues and fully responsive consultation are, both now and going forward, to ensure that the resulting legislation in this highly complex and technical area has the highest possible degree of effectiveness, proportionality, relevance, and adaptability. The Commission’s proposals on regulatory classification and trade reporting as presented raise considerable concerns that they would harm European markets and give rise to avoidable costs. The Commission should not proceed with these aspects in their current form. Depending on how the Commission proposes to proceed, it may well be the case that further consultation will be appropriate in these areas. In any event, the Commission should justify any new obligations or far-reaching changes to the structure of the ISD by means of a thorough analysis of the existing problems and how its proposals are designed to solve them. We are keen to continue to help the Commission to develop a measure which addresses threats to public policy objectives in a proportionate way, but also does not damage European markets. 6 Proposed regulatory classification; definition of organised and regulated markets (Definitions 13 and 14); reporting of off-market trades to enable integration in realtime price feeds (Article 18) 15. Our understanding is that, through the proposed new regulatory classification, the Commission intends to tackle certain specific risks which arise in certain markets, in particular the equities market. In the Commission’s view, these arise because of: the emergence of entities which, while they are regulated as investment firms, have certain exchange-like characteristics, and the internalisation of order flow by investment firms. 16. We understand that a particular concern is a possible ‘deterioration of the efficiency of price-formation’ because substantial volumes of transactions are not made available ‘to the market as a whole’. Clarity of definition of terms is particularly important in this context, given the current wide variation across Europe in trade reporting requirements. For example, members of the London Stock Exchange are generally required to trade report to the Exchange all trades in listed securities, even if they are transacted ‘off exchange’; this level of transparency is not replicated by other European regulated markets. Not all European exchanges currently mandate immediate trade reporting. The result is a wide variation between different markets in the way information on OTC transactions is made available to other market participants. 17. The approach to transparency needs to be informed by due regard for the other elements of efficient markets, in particular liquidity and the avoidance of excessive volatility. While information about an OTC transaction might help a third party in determining the price of a security, the possibility not to disclose a transaction to the market might be an essential condition for a market participant to take on risk and enter into the transaction in the first place. This dichotomy defines the widely recognised fact that the benefits of increased transparency must be weighed against possible negative effects on liquidity. There is also a need to recognise the different characteristics of different markets, and the fact that the ‘market price’ is not necessarily the same for wholesale and retail business. In non-equity markets (e.g. bonds and derivatives) immediate trade reports could be much less meaningful than they are in equity markets: in some instrument they would serve little price-information purpose, and could reduce liquidity. In OTC derivatives markets, where transactions are not standardised and there is no centralised marketplace, and also in the case of structured transactions, price publication could be positively misleading. In complex markets with many participants, the location of the reference price can change when the liquidity changes. For example, even in liquid and transparent equity markets, price formation is affected by markets outside the EU, and can take place outside Europe altogether, in US ADR markets, after European markets have closed. In bond markets, the recent arrival of ATSs has improved the liquidity, transparency, competition, and efficiency of the market as a whole, and the complexity of ATSs’ interaction with the continuing OTC markets means that the equity-marketbased model cannot be efficiently applied. Many corporate bonds and most 7 government bonds are admitted to trading on regulated exchanges, often because admission to trading is a necessary requirement if funds are to invest in them. However, for many bonds trading takes place rarely on regulated exchanges, and almost exclusively in OTC markets, and the reference price is not determined by on-exchange trading. 18. It has not been demonstrated that the existing ISD structure has prevented the development of diverse and innovative capital markets in the EU. In fact the reverse is true. Under the existing structure, innovation, driven by competition and technological development, has enabled markets to respond to demand for new products, new trading mechanisms, and new risk-management methodologies in a way which has increased the efficiency of markets and benefited both investors and raisers of capital. 19. We believe that the radical change to the regulatory classification which the Commission proposes, combined with the proposed obligations for trade reporting and the strict demarcation of instruments between regulated and non-regulated markets, is not an appropriate or proportionate response to any risks which may currently exist. It is difficult to predict all of its consequences, but it is reasonably clear that the Commission’s proposal would have harmful side-effects which are very likely to outweigh substantially any potential benefits. It could: harm the liquidity of the OTC markets in exchange-traded instruments deter investment firms from using their own balance sheets to execute large trades impose substantial cost burdens on investment firms which would need to adapt systems to be able to identify when they might have to report transactions to exchanges, and to create the necessary links to be able to make those reports (apart from the charges that exchanges would impose for receiving the reports) constrain the market’s freedom of operation (for instance, an investment firm would need to monitor or constrain improvements to its order-matching service if it risked becoming an organised market and thereby either losing its passport or becoming liable to become a regulated market), restrain innovation (for instance, innovation in derivatives markets depends on the continual development of new products, only a small proportion of which attract liquidity and become successful; this source of new products could dry up if they were vulnerable to ‘takeover’ by regulated markets.); confer unfair competitive advantage on incumbent traditional exchanges (for instance because of their preferential access to valuable trade information, their better positioning to adapt to the proposed new standards, and their ability to undermine non-regulated markets by admitting new instruments or products to trading); 8 fail to take due account of the varying characteristics of different markets (for instance, by applying a model which we believe has principally been designed to cater for certain perceived issues in equity markets - partly because of their significant retail participation – to other markets which are mainly professional in character and to which very different market dynamics and regulatory considerations apply); risk making European markets uncompetitive globally, and driving business outside the EU (for instance, by reducing the ability of the market as a whole to adapt continuously to users’ needs); give scope for manipulation of market structures by enabling regulated markets to force other entities to change their regulatory classification, or even to ‘take over’ the market in products which have been developed by nonregulated competitors, by admitting instruments to trading on the regulated markets, and thereby prevent their being traded on non-regulated markets (this problem could be particularly acute in derivative markets, given the ambiguity of the concept of a ‘proper market’); effectively represent a reimposition, by other means, of concentration requirements, which the Commission has elsewhere recognised are an impediment to the internal market. However, whereas concentration requirements are optional under the existing ISD, the channelling of trading under the Commission’s proposals would be mandatory. 20. The interdependence of the proposed definition of regulated markets and of the instruments traded on them (quite apart from the serious concerns which the industry has expressed elsewhere about the Proposal for a Prospectuses Directive), combined with the proposed prohibition on trading of regulated market instruments on a non-regulated market, is likely to give rise to further rigidities, and to slow down the responsiveness of markets to the commercial needs of their users. 21. In practice we think that the uncertainty associated with non-regulated organised market status would be likely to be such that the status would be commercially unsustainable. The effect of the Commission’s proposals would thus be that trading platforms would be either regulated markets or investment firms (as at present), but without the flexibility in the system which at present allows and encourages development of new systems, innovation, and competition. This would be particularly problematic for investment firms which have closely integrated systems which would be defined as ‘organised markets’ into their operations, or which might want to do so in future. 22. In summary, we do not think that the ISD should introduce a rigid definition of regulated markets, nor define an ‘organised, non-regulated market’ to which the ISD passport would not apply, since this could introduce rigidity in market structures, prevent innovation, and distort competition. We think that a ‘bottom up’, graduated, targeted approach offers a better opportunity than a heavy-handed ‘top down’ approach to develop appropriate policy for 9 multiple and diverse trading platforms without distorting the overall European market framework. 23. CESR has already initiated a debate on how to approach transparency issues in evolving market conditions in its 2001 consultation on the regulation of alternative trading systems. This initiative is consistent with the commitment in CESR’s Charter to ‘observe and assess the evolution of financial markets and the global tendencies in securities regulation and their impact on the regulation of the Single Market for financial services’. The industry has commented widely on the need to narrow down and target CESR’s proposed standards, in particular to ensure that they: are justified by an identified public policy need which cannot be met otherwise do not duplicate other existing requirements take account of the discipline imposed by market forces distinguish effectively between markets where there is retail participation and markets which are exclusively professional are tailored to the specific characteristics of each market 24. We think that the appropriate way forward on the transparency and priceformation issue is to retain the ISD’s existing flexible regulatory classification, and to develop tailored and targeted measures only where it is shown that the market has failed to deliver an appropriate level of transparency. Before supplementing the market-driven level of transparency in any given market, the Commission and CESR, in consultation with market participants, market operators, and market users, should: conduct a detailed analysis of the public policy need and market dynamic in the different markets (taking account of the need to strike an appropriate balance in each market between transparency, liquidity, and avoidance of excessive volatility, and also of the extent to which voluntary arrangements – such as sale of trading data, membership of exchanges and other execution venues, and other private law agreements – already maintain an appropriate level of transparency), develop, at Lamfalussy Level 2 or 3, tailored additional standards for each market, but only where the analysis has clearly shown a need for regulatory intervention, and introduce at Level 1 high-level principles which would require the detailed standards to take account of all the elements of an efficient market. 10 25. The advantages of this approach over the Commission’s proposals on regulatory classification include: it would enable the retention of the existing flexible structure, and thus avoid the undesirable consequences of forcing entities to structure their services on the basis of regulatory rather than commercial criteria. it would enable effective and targeted regulation of ‘off-exchange’ trading by entities which would, because of their characteristics, fall into the proposed ‘non-regulated organised market’ category, without constraining their ability to structure their services on the basis of commercial criteria. it would enable effective and targeted regulation of transparency and priceformation, taking account of the specific characteristics of different markets. it would lend itself to effective development and update, in an ongoing consultative process with market participants, at Level 3 or Level 2 of the Lamfalussy structure. 26. We strongly oppose the Commission’s proposal under Article 18 not to allow deferred reporting of ‘off-regulated exchange’ very large trades which give rise to market exposure. Deferred reporting is vital if firms are to be prepared to take on the risk of a substantial exposed position when the market may move against them. It should be noted that for on-exchange trade reporting Article 21 of the ISD currently allows for block trade exemptions. Large trades are often undertaken by pension funds or UCITS which manage funds on behalf of private individuals, on whom the harm of adverse price movements would therefore fall. In practice, without deferred reporting such transactions would either not be undertaken at all because of their high market-impact costs, or might migrate outside the EU to a jurisdiction where anonymity could be preserved. Liquidity is likely to follow, so that EU markets would end up less liquid and less transparent. 27. We agree with the Commission’s reservations about its proposal under Article 18 to require trade reporting to the ‘leading regulated market’, and we strongly oppose this proposal. It would give rise to a severe danger of market distortion and the establishment of a legislative monopoly on price formation. We are not aware of shortcomings in the existing market-driven arrangements for aggregating trading data from different markets which would justify such a rule. The approach to this issue needs to be graduated and take full account of both variations between markets, and solutions provided by the market itself. In bond markets, for instance, the ‘regulated market’ is a late-comer, and the market with the longest tradition of trading is the OTC market. Regulated exchanges have developed in order to fulfil a market need to provide greater liquidity and transparency; the development of alternative trading systems has been prompted to fulfil the same need. There is no need for the position of regulated exchanges to be artificially reinforced, indeed requiring all OTC trades to be reported to them could be highly damaging to the market as a whole. In derivatives markets, regulated exchanges have also developed only recently, and substantial liquidity (which could often not be provided otherwise) remains with OTC markets. In both bond and derivative markets it is only very rarely that the OTC market 11 influences the price formation process on regulated exchanges. The competitive effect of requiring investment firms to report valuable, time-sensitive trade data immediately and free of charge to competitor exchanges could also be highly damaging. The Commission should also consider the cost implications for firms of the multiple price feeds which they would need to establish to a range of regulated markets if the proposals were to go ahead. Proposed adjustments to scope 28. Some of the proposed adjustments are helpful clarifications of provisions in the existing ISD where ambiguities may have been exploited by Member States to restrict the internal market. However, amendments to the text should not be a substitute for ensuring that investment firms are able to take advantage of the passport. Going forward, in the context of both the existing and the new ISD, the Commission should actively enforce passporting rights. We also assume that the Commission plans to review the scope of the Banking Consolidation Directive to ensure the necessary degree of consistency with the ISD. 29. Arranging/facilitating (Definition 1): We think that the proposed clarification that the passport applies to order-routing, bulletin boards, and introducing brokers is likely to be helpful to regulated firms. We welcome the proposal to provide for variation of conduct of business requirements to reflect the reduced risk: the detail of this should be dealt with at Level 3. It would be important to ensure however that the extension of scope was structured so that it did not bring into the ISD internet portals. 30. Order-matching (Definition 2): We welcome the proposed clarification that the passport for brokerage includes automated order-matching and execution-only business. The definition should not be restricted to firms acting as agent, but should include riskless principal business. It should also not be restricted to transmission of orders to ‘appropriate execution venues’. 31. Underwriting and placement (Definition 4): We welcome the extension to include support and placement services which do not involve a guarantee to take up unsubscribed capital. 32. Investment advice (Definition 6): Under the Commission’s proposal firms would obtain a passport only for personalised, separately remunerated advice. However it will be essential to ensure that investment advice is retained as a non-core service within section C of the Annex as well so that investment firms can continue to provide cross-border advisory services in association with their core services. 33. Securities lending and borrowing, repos, reverse repos (Definition 8): We support the proposal to make clear that the passport applies to these, although we would argue that they are already covered by paragraph 2 of section A of the Annex of the ISD. However we are concerned that its usefulness should not be limited by a requirement for the ‘express consent’ of clients. It will be important to ensure that the wording does not imply that consent is required for each and every transaction. 12 34. Foreign exchange services (Definition 9): We support the Commission’s proposal to remove the requirement that foreign exchange services be linked to provision of core investment services. 35. Granting credits or loans (Definition 10): We oppose the restriction of the passport to circumstances where the firm acts in a fiduciary capacity. We favour the retention of the existing paragraph 3 of section C of the Annex. 36. Commodity derivatives (Definition 12): Any directive-level provisions on commodity derivatives should clearly target the removal of barriers to such business. No case has been made for imposing licensing requirements on wholesale commodities-related business. Preferably the directive should require both home and host Member States to remove licensing requirements on wholesale commodity business, although we recognise that this may be difficult to achieve, at least in the short term. But if Member States are able to continue to impose licensing requirements, it would be important for the directive to recognise that host State licensing requirements are legitimate only for firms which are not properly regulated in their home State (in accordance with the 1986 insurance judgements) – a recital to this effect would be necessary to make the position clear. If the removal of licensing requirements for wholesale business is not feasible, there are two possibilities for including commodity derivatives in the directive: as a non-core service in section C of the Annex (which we would prefer), or as a core service in Section A of the Annex. In either event, inclusion of commodities business within the scope of the ISD would reinforce the importance of other issues with respect to the structure of the ISD which are discussed elsewhere in this response: The directive would need to make clear that Member States could not apply their licensing requirements to derivatives transactions entered into by an entity for its own account with, or through the agency of, an authorised firm. An entity which conducts business in this way should not be regarded as dealing for third parties. Conduct of business rules would need to be appropriate to the nature of commodity derivatives business, and above all the directive must require a light and flexible conduct of business regime for business conducted with professional investors. The directive would need to include a broad and flexible definition of professional investors which allowed corporate investors to be treated as professionals. Of the two options indicated above, we would prefer commodity derivatives (and other commodity-related services including physical business – to cover the case where Member States extend their licensing requirements that far) to be included as a non-core service in section C of the Annex. This would avoid requiring Member States to impose licensing requirements (which would involve a need to check through the directive to ensure that provisions relating to investment firms 13 were appropriate to commodities business), while extending the benefit of the passport, but only to investment firms. Member States would retain the flexibility to ensure that some regulatory oversight is applied to such business. If, nevertheless, commodity derivatives are included in section A of the Annex as a core service, Member States would be required to impose licensing requirements, and it would be essential to ensure that the directive made provision for the following in addition to the three general bullet points set out above: an exemption under the current ISD’s Article 2 for firms which solely trade with other professional investors; at the very least, Member States having the ability to modify the regulatory capital regime for commodity firms, especially in the case where they trade only with other professional investors (thus recognising the special nature of commodities business and, in particular, the importance of the liquidity which specialised firms provide to the market). This could be done by including a provision to this effect at the end of proposed Article 3. the inclusion of services related to physical commodity transactions in section C of the Annex as non-core services, to address barriers to business in countries which persist in applying licensing requirements to physically settled transactions; If commodities business were brought within the ISD on an inappropriate basis, without regard for such points, we believe that the damage to the European commodities markets, their users, and those sectors of the economy that depend on them, could be significant. (See also our comments in paragraphs 19 and 27 above on the harm which could be done to the commodity markets as a result of the Commission’s proposed regulatory classification and trade reporting requirements.) Definitions 37. Organised markets, Regulated markets (Definitions 13, 14): See our comments on the proposed regulatory classification in paragraphs 15 to 27 above. 38. Professional investor (Definition 18): We welcome the Commission’s acceptance of the general principle that the definition of professional investors needs to be tailored to recognise the extent to which all participants in wholesale markets are sophisticated, and there is not in wholesale markets any inequality of market power which means that one party needs to be ‘protected’. We also welcome the proposal to include large and sophisticated corporates among ‘professionals’. However, a number of specific adjustments are still needed, and similar modifications are required to bring CESR’s October 2001 proposed definition into line. ‘Professional investors’ should be defined so that the following are also included: non-EU listed corporates; 14 members of groups which include large or listed companies; non-publicly-offered listed companies local and public authorities, and national and central banks sophisticated small corporate and individual investors whom the firm has assessed as expert, and who have agreed to be treated as professionals. 39. We also welcome the proposed provision enabling non-professionals to agree to be treated as professionals. It will be important to ensure that both parties can rely on such agreement, and that any provision for it to be ‘overridden by the initial public law categorisation’ does not provide scope for the parties to renege with the benefit of hindsight. It will also be important to word the Level 1 definition, and develop Level 2 legislation or Level 3 standards, so that the parties can agree the disapplication of protections in a targeted way if they so wish. Proposed investment firm regime 40. Vetting and approval of business operations (Article 2): It will be important to ensure that firms are given the opportunity to manage conflicts of interest, and are not required simply to limit them. In many circumstances (particularly with large integrated houses), conflicts of interest are unavoidable but are managed through Chinese walls or other internal independence policies, and/or are disclosed to customers. 41. The Commission’s proposals do not appear to replicate the current ISD requirement (Article 3.5) that supervisors inform applicants within six months whether or not authorisation has been granted. We believe that this deadline is a valuable discipline for regulators, and should be retained. An additional point which is being raised by our Members concerns the way in which the regulators calculate the fees that they charge firms which undertake business outside their home State. There is growing concern that the fee tariffs which are used in such cases do not reflect the extent to which the supervisory work of the home State regulator significantly reduces the amount of work which the host State regulator has to undertake (as compared with the latter State’s activity in respect of firms of a similar size and business profile for which it acts as the home State regulator. As a result, firms undertaking business outside their home State are charged more than they should be. Where a host State has no regulatory responsibility for the business of a firm authorised in another Member State, it should not charge the firm a supervisory fee; to the extent that host States retain regulatory responsibilities under the ISD, the directive should be amended to include provisions requiring competent authorities to take into account their reduced responsibilities when fees are set for firms authorised in other Member States. Paragraph (d) of Annex II to the Investor Compensation Schemes Directive provides an example of this sort of approach. 42. Organisational requirements (Article 12): The Commission proposes new organisational requirements relating to: systems resilience and contingency 15 arrangements to cope with fluctuations in demand or usage or to provide back-up facilities; prior approval of a number of aspects of order-matching facilities; and prior approval of ‘important’ outsourcing arrangements. Whilst these may be areas of legitimate regulatory interest, it will be important to structure the provisions to prevent regulators from ‘micro-managing’ firms’ IT systems and outsourcing arrangements, and to limit regulators’ ability to use ‘prior approval’ to override firms’ commercial judgement. Similarly, it will be important to limit the definition of ‘important’ outsourced services. 43. In many circumstances it is not appropriate to require a market to have systems which are robust enough to contend with large fluctuations in demand. Usually it will be possible for professional customers to have access to alternative means of trading. Only if the system is the only or only significant trading mechanism for the relevant instrument, or in relation to retail customers, should such a requirement apply. 44. The Commission suggests that record-keeping, client money and assets identification, and conflict of interest control (but not the ‘system-related’ matters discussed in paragraph 42 above) might need to be subject to country of origin control because they are ‘investor-facing’ in nature. We support a country of origin approach in these circumstances. The ‘country of origin’ should be as defined in the Electronic Commerce Directive. This would mean that when the relevant function was provided in connection with a service provided by the branch but not by the head office, the country of origin would be the country of the branch. If however the relevant function was part of a centralised service provided by the group as a whole, the country of origin would be where the centre of the activities was, and would equate to the home State. 45. Conduct of business and dealing requirements (Article 13): We welcome the specific provision in Article 13 requiring implementing measures to take account of the nature of the service offered, and of the capacity of professional investors to make informed or expert judgements. However, we think that the Directive should go further, and explicitly state that certain types of service (e.g. executiononly) and the professionalism of the investor imply a lesser need for conduct of business protection and therefore a lighter conduct of business regime (this would accord with the statement on page 18 of the consultation paper: ‘the Directive should reaffirm the principle that the full weight of conduct of business protections does not need to be brought to bear in the case of services provided to professional clients’). The lighter regime for professionals should encompass the exclusion from the proposed conduct of business obligations of certain of the detailed provisions as detailed at the end of this paragraph. Some of these concerns continue to apply also to CESR’s proposed standards and rules for conduct of business, in spite of the revisions to CESR’s proposals in its October 2001 consultation paper. It will be important for the provisions of implementing legislation under the ISD and CESR’s final standards to be consistent and to take account of these issues. The statement that a firm should act ‘in accordance with the best interest of its clients’ is not appropriate to inter-professional markets, the nature of which is such that firms cannot be expected always to know or act on their clients’ best 16 interests; the equality of market power between professionals makes a fiduciary relationship inappropriate; Some of the proposed requirements are relevant only to non-professional customers, in particular: details of compensation scheme (2); suitability obligation (3); operation in the best interests of the investor (6); risk warnings and guidance (7); information about instruments, investments and execution venues (8); best execution (9) 46. We welcome the exclusion from conduct of business protection of principal to principal business (but see also our comments on look-through provisions in paragraph 50 below). 47. We strongly support the Commission’s proposal to apply the country of origin approach (home State control for services provided from head office, supplemented by branch State control for services provided from branches, with a prohibition of host State requirements on incoming cross-border services) to all investment services, whether the service is provided on- or off-line, and whether the client or counterparty is wholesale or retail. However the Commission proposes that the country of origin approach shall apply only after the implementing measures are in place. We do not think that such a delay is justified, in principle or in practice. We attach as an Annex an extract from our response to the Commission’s November 2000 Communication on the Upgrade of the ISD which describes why the broad application of the country of origin approach is so urgent. The progress of CESR towards agreeing conduct of business standards at Level 3, together with the progress towards agreement of the proposal for a Directive on the Distance Marketing of Financial Services and the imminent implementation of the Electronic Commerce Directive removes any justification for retaining detailed harmonisation as a pre-condition for the full adoption of a country of origin approach. Acceptance of the country of origin principle will in itself provide an incentive for rapid convergence of Member States’ conduct of business standards at an appropriate level, and it is therefore appropriate for the Commission to give its backing to it, not only without preconditions in the revised ISD, but also immediately in the context of the enforcement of the existing ISD. The implementation of the Electronic Commerce Directive in January 2002 will apply the country of origin approach to conduct of business requirements for services provided electronically; the regime for off-line business should be brought into line in order to avoid competitive distortions between services according to how they are delivered, and to enable the effective and well-regulated provision of services which are delivered using both on-line and off-line media. Any deficiencies in Member States’ detailed conduct of business rules should be dealt with directly, rather than being allowed to impede the single market. Furthermore, there is a risk that if the country of origin approach is made conditional on the implementation of harmonised standards, the internal market could be delayed by Member States which are slow to put in place the implementing measures. 48. We support the inclusion of advertising and marketing rules with conduct of business rules and the application of the country of origin regime to them. 17 49. These principles of country of origin control and a lighter regime where appropriate to the type of business or customers’ reduced need for protection should be established unequivocally at Level 1. Provisions on the detailed content of conduct of business provisions are not necessary at Level 1, and detailed conduct of business standards should be dealt with (subject to full transparency and consultation) via the continuing CESR consultation process at Level 3. 50. Look-through provisions (Article 13): The proposed provision appears to have widened the circumstances in which an investment firm has fiduciary responsibility for another firm’s client. The current Article 11.3 applies only when the immediate customer receives or transmits orders, whereas the proposed provision applies when the other investment firm has ‘mediated or interposed itself’. In spite of the exception for a customer which does not disclose that it is acting on behalf of a third party, the Article is likely to impose too great a level of fiduciary responsibility on firms. It is similarly particularly important that CESR’s proposed regime for market counterparties should apply to agency dealing as well as principal dealing between authorised firms. 51. Obligation to disclose order-routing practices (Article 15): We welcome the proposed abolition of concentration rules. However we are concerned that the Commission’s proposed regulatory classification would have the effect of reintroducing concentration requirements in a mandatory context (see paragraph 19 above). We think that the proposed quarterly reporting to competent authorities on execution venues will be a less effective means of policing best execution than a requirement to report to clients on which markets the firm has access to, supplemented by appropriate conduct of business rules on best execution. This disclosure to clients would be an important element of the solution to the transparency and price formation issue which we propose in paragraphs 22 to 27 above, since it would enable clients to make a proper assessment of the relative costs and benefits of investment firms’ services. Client reporting should be dealt with as a conduct of business rules matter at Level 3. 52. Obligations of investment firms to the market (Article 16): The Commission has published a separate Proposal for a Market Abuse Directive, on which LIBA and other associations are commenting separately. It will be important not only that the industry’s concerns about the Proposal are resolved satisfactorily, but also that the ISD does not duplicate that Directive or impose additional obligations. Whilst it is clearly important for investment firms to be prepared to assist the authorities to detect or prevent abusive behaviour, it is not clear that there is a need for this issue to be dealt with in the ISD at all. Any provision in this area in the ISD should make clear that control is by the Home State; cross-border issues should be dealt with by cooperation between regulators via existing mechanisms. Any provision in the ISD should also not single out order-matching systems for more onerous requirements than other dealing methods. 53. Reporting of transactions to competent authority (Article 17): The implementation of the proposal to extend reporting obligations to all transactions which take place on a regulated market is likely to be complex and would impose on firms the additional cost of establishing the necessary data feeds. Particular problems are 18 likely to be caused by the proposed requirement to provide data on the identity and professional or retail status of the customer. 54. Reporting of transactions in instruments admitted to trading on regulated markets which are performed outside the rules of a regulated market (Article 18): See our comments on this issue in the discussion of the proposed regulatory classification in paragraphs 16 to 27 above. 55. Counterparties to public authorities (Article 21): We think that the ability of Member States to restrict access to primary dealing should be removed. Whilst we welcome the proposed tightening of the exception for counterparties to public authorities in Article 21, so that any restrictions on branch or cross-border provision of these services would need to be based on ‘objective, proportionate and transparent’ requirements, we think that this leaves too much scope for ambiguity and protectionist exploitation. At the very least, the Commission must rigorously police the proportionality of restrictions at Level 4. 56. Access to regulated markets and clearing and settlement (Articles 22-23): We welcome the Commission’s proposals for non-discriminatory access to regulated markets and clearing and settlement facilities. High-level principles for regulated markets 57. (See also our comments on the proposed regulatory classification in paragraphs 15 to 27 above.) Our attitude to the proposed high-level principles for regulated markets depends very much on whether the Commission persists with its proposal to make regulated market status compulsory if the relevant criteria are satisfied, or whether it is decided to continue (as we think essential) with the present structure under which regulated market status is a matter of choice. Certain of the proposed standards (for instance operation of strict controls on instruments admitted to trading, immediate post-trade transparency) would be likely to give rise to considerable additional cost to platforms currently regulated as an investment firm which decided or was obliged to become a regulated market. Such costs would be likely to be a material factor in such entities’ decision-making, and are therefore likely to distort the ‘regulated market’ sector in a way which would discourage new entrants, discourage innovation, and favour incumbents. 58. Provided that platforms retain the flexibility to choose between regulated market and investment firm status, and subject to our detailed comments below, in general the proposed principles appear to be a reasonable statement of what should be expected of exchanges. There should be high-level principles only at Level 1, with details worked out adaptively and consultatively at Levels 2/3, building on the existing FESCO standards for regulated markets. 59. We have the following comments on particular aspects of the proposed principles: Financial resources (Article 28): The Commission asks for comments on possible methodologies for establishing a financial resources requirement. The Commission’s proposed principle is stated generally: ‘sufficient financial resources to contend with the risks to which the system may be exposed…and 19 to allow for orderly closure. In order to avoid competitive distortion, financial resource requirements for regulated exchanges should broadly correspond to the requirements which investment firms are subject to under CAD. Controls on instruments admitted to trading (Article 29): See our comments in paragraph 19 above on the constraints to which the market would be subject as a result of allowing only instruments which meet the specified criteria to be admitted to trading. Market integrity and investor protection are sufficiently served by the FESCO standards’ approach of requiring disclosure of the basis on which instruments are admitted to trading. It will be important to make unambiguously clear that the principle that regulated markets must operate strict controls on the instruments admitted to trading does not imply that a regulated market is required to have a contractual relationship with the issuer of the instrument, and does not enable issuers to restrict the markets on which the instrument is traded. The requirement for there to be a ‘proper market’ in derivatives based on commodities, rates, or indices could prevent market operators from introducing new contracts in situations where it is not certain that liquidity will be forthcoming, and thereby inhibit innovation. Arrangements to promote transparency (Article 33): See our serious concerns in paragraphs 16 to 27 above on the proposed obligation for investment firms to report off-market transactions in relevant instruments to the ‘leading regulated market’: the Commission should not continue with this proposal. See also our concerns in paragraph 26 above about the proposed absence of a block trade exemption in Article 18. The proposal in Article 33 for ‘as instantaneous as possible’ publication of trades, without any provision for delay for block trades, fails to recognise the market distortion and the damaging effect on market liquidity and competitiveness which such a requirement would cause. The function of delayed reporting is to enable market participants which take on large exposures to take steps to manage their risk before the trade becomes public. Immediate publication of such trades would enable other participants to move the price against the holder of the exposed position (typically pension funds or UCITS which manage funds on behalf of private individuals, on whom the harm of adverse price movements would therefore fall), so that the price would be artificially distorted. Article 21 of the current ISD recognises the function which block trade exemptions serve, and the revised ISD should do so as well. In practice, the absence of block trade exemptions would result in the withdrawal of the liquidity which they provide from European markets altogether. Clearing and settlement 60. We welcome the Commission’s proposals on liberalisation of access by investment firms and regulated markets to clearing and settlement systems. It is however important that the limits and qualifications to these rights cannot be 20 exploited to restrict competition or market access. The wording of the revised ISD needs to strike the appropriate balance between: not mandating links, and encouraging interoperability. London Investment Banking Association 2nd November 2001 TMMB/Oct24/COM77A 21 MEMBERS OF THE LONDON INVESTMENT BANKING ASSOCIATION Ansbacher & Co Limited ABN AMRO Bank N.V. Arbuthnot Latham & Co., Limited BNP Paribas Barclays Capital Bear, Stearns International Limited Beeson Gregory Limited CIBC World Markets Plc Cazenove & Co. The Chase Manhattan Bank Close Brothers Corporate Finance Ltd Collins Stewart Limited Commerzbank AG Credit Suisse First Boston International Daiwa Securities SMBC Europe Limited Dawnay, Day & Co., Limited Deutsche Bank AG London Dresdner Kleinwort Wasserstein Goldman Sachs International Granville Baird Ltd. Hawkpoint Partners Limited HSBC Investment Bank plc ING Barings Insinger English Trust Instinet UK Ltd Investec Bank (UK) Limited Knight Securities International Ltd Lazard Lehman Brothers Merrill Lynch Europe PLC Mizuho International plc Morgan Stanley International Ltd Nomura International plc Old Mutual Securities Ltd Peel Hunt plc N M Rothschild & Sons Limited Schroder Salomon Smith Barney Singer & Friedlander Holdings Limited Société Générale 3i Group plc The Toronto Dominion Bank UBS Warburg Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale sd E/memnam July 16, 2016 22 ANNEX: Extract from LIBA’s response to the European Commission’s November 2000 consultative Communication on the Upgrade of the Investment Services Directive 1. The imposition of country of destination rules in addition to country of origin rules imposes a major barrier to cross-border business, not just for SMEs, but for major financial institutions as well. We outline below some of the main difficulties. It is important to emphasise that overlapping and conflicting rules, coupled with insufficient recognition of investor sophistication, uncertainty of application, and the possibility of unenforceability of contracts, gives rise to unnecessary risk which affects the willingness of all affected financial institutions to enter into transactions. 2. Both the direct cost and the indirect cost associated with managing the risks are likely to be reflected in the costs charged to customers. Overlapping requirements thus make financial products in Europe (including retail products, since product providers lay off their risk in the wholesale markets) more costly than they should be. The risk involved may also be such that the firm decides not to enter into the transaction: overlapping requirements can thus restrict the choice of products available across borders in Europe. 3. The risks involved for a firm which wishes to deal across a range of countries are many-layered. Aspects of this include the duplicative application of both the country of destination and country of origin rules, the differences and potential contradictions between them (and the cost of establishing what the local requirements are), the fact that country of destination rules may be disproportionate to the needs of the investor, and the risk that the contract may be unenforceable if country of destination rules are not complied with. This complexity in itself increases the level of risk. 4. The development of electronic commerce and consequent expansion of demand for cross-border trading has given new prominence to the obstacles, and made it all the more urgent that they be removed. 5. Specific obstacles include the following: Member States use different criteria to determine the Member State 'in which' a service is provided, including the 'characteristic performance' test (which is consistent with the country of origin principle, and is supported by the Commission's interpretation of the Second Banking Directive), solicitation tests, and tests based on the country of residence of the investor. Article 11 requires Member States to impose conduct of business rules on investment firms (including banks conducting investment business). However, the way in which Member States do this differs substantially. Some Member States have very detailed conduct of business rules. Some have only high-level general principles. Some distinguish sharply between the rules that apply to business with a defined class of professional investor. Others do not distinguish so sharply e.g. by imposing duties that vary according to a subjective assessment of the level of expertise of the investor. Some classify corporates as non-professionals unless 23 they opt to be treated as professionals, whereas others classify them as professionals; some do not allow corporates to opt to be treated as professionals, while others do not distinguish at all between professional and retail customers. Furthermore, many Member States do not recognise the concept of 'expert' private individuals who may opt to waive some of the protections available to less experienced private customers. Restrictions remain on the ability of firms to use the passport for trading in various Member States. Even when companies or banks are granted a passport, implying that they have met the local licensing requirements, they may still be denied access to local markets. In some Member States a broker or dealer is entitled to operate an electronic trading platform to provide services to its customers. In others the provision of services in that way is regarded as the operation of an ‘exchange’, and the passport is deemed insufficient. Despite the passport provisions of the ISD, not all Member States permit EU securities firms to access exchanges and clearing services without requiring that the EU firm offers services from a branch or subsidiary located in the Member State. Some Member States do not allow remote access to stock exchanges. Some Member States apply concentration rules under Article 14(3), but most do not (see our separate comments on this issue) To the extent that the Upgrade of the ISD continues to restrict the application of the country of origin principle to particular categories of investors, such restrictions on the effectiveness of the single market are likely to remain. Clear and agreed definition of the boundaries of categories and approximation of detailed conduct of business requirements could help to reduce obstacles, but only the extension of the country of origin principle to all business will eliminate them. 24