LIBA L O N D O N I N V E S TM E N T B AN K I N G A S S O C I A T I O N 6 Frederick's Place, London, EC2R 8BT T el: 0 2 0 7 7 9 6 3 6 0 6 F a x: 0 2 0 7 7 9 6 4 3 4 5 e-mail: liba@liba.org.uk website: www.liba.org.uk Proposed CESR standards for alternative trading systems: January 2002 consultation A response by the London Investment Banking Association (LIBA) _____________________________________________________________________ SUMMARY OF KEY POINTS INTRODUCTION Paragraphs 1-4 GENERAL ISSUES Risks and regulatory objectives Paragraphs 5-12 Discretionary differentiation or disapplication of standards Paragraphs 13-14 Interaction with the Commission’s review of the ISD Paragraph 15 Country of origin application of the standards Paragraph 16-17 Definition of ‘qualifying systems’ Paragraphs 18-20 DETAILED COMMENTS ON THE STANDARDS Introductory paragraph Paragraph 21 Standards 1-7 Paragraph 22 Standard 1: Registration and notifications Paragraph 23 Standard 2: Fair and orderly trading Paragraph 24 Standard 3: Publication of trading information Paragraphs 25-29 Standard 4: Monitoring Paragraph 30 Standard 5: Arrangements with Regulators Facilitating Market Integrity and Investor Protection Paragraphs 31-34 Standard 6: Systems Paragraph 35 Standard 7: Clearing and Settlement Paragraph 36 Reclassification of user-facing standards as guidance on conduct of business rules Paragraps 37-39 FEEDBACK STATEMENT: Comments on summary of key issues _____________________________________________________________________ SUMMARY OF KEY POINTS We welcome the fact that CESR has made some helpful amendments to its earlier proposals. However, CESR’s analysis of risks is still hypothetical and is not well-defined. CESR’s regulatory objectives are correspondingly unclear. CESR’s lack of definition of risks and objectives has particularly serious consequences in the case of Standard 3 (Publication of trading information). CESR should not proceed with Standard 3 before a thorough analysis of risks and impacts, which both CESR and the Commission are about to launch. CESR’s narrowing of the definition of ‘qualifying systems’ is welcome, but it needs to be better defined. CESR should also consider excluding systems whose share of the overall market falls below a de minimis level. CESR’s lack of definition of risks and objectives makes quantitative discussion of costs and benefits difficult. Nevertheless, CESR must not underestimate the serious consequences in many markets of mandated transparency that has not been well considered and explained. CESR’s recognition of the need to differentiate or disapply the standards in appropriate circumstances is welcome, but should be more definitely stated. CESR’s recognition of the need for country of origin regulation is welcome, but should be reinforced and properly enforced. CESR’s redefinition of user-facing standards as guidance on conduct of business rules is welcome, but the proposals should be scaled back for professional systems, and not apply to inter-dealer systems. INTRODUCTION 1. As CESR is aware, the London Investment Banking Association (LIBA) represents the major European and international investment banks which base their European activities in London. LIBA Members connect to clients and each other in a range of markets through a range of systems, including both ‘qualifying systems’ as redefined in the second consultation paper, and the ‘bilateral systems’ in respect of which CESR proposes further work, as well as through regulated exchanges. LIBA Members also operate systems which would fall within either ‘qualifying’ or ‘bilateral’ categories. A list of our Members is attached as Annex 1. 2. Given the major concerns which we and other commentators expressed about FESCO’s initial proposals for standards for ATS regulation, we welcome the fact that CESR has decided to consult again on revised standards. This is consistent with CESR’s Statement of Consultation Practices. We are keen to help CESR to develop a regulatory regime for ATSs and for market transparency which appropriately and proportionately addresses identified risks. In this context a group of European associations, including LIBA, are proposing to brief CESR in detail about the commercial and technical context of market transparency. We have had the opportunity to consider the responses of several other associations to CESR’s consultation, including those of the International Swaps and Derivatives Association, the International Securities Market Association, and The Bond Market Association, and we generally support their comments. 3. We welcome the fact that CESR has recognised the need for changes to its original proposals. In particular, we welcome: the willingness to narrow the definition of qualifying systems, the recognition of the need to eliminate duplicative regulation by specifying that it is the country of origin of the system which is responsible for applying the standards, the recognition that minimal or no standards need be applied to many systems in professional markets, and the recognition that conduct of business matters should be clearly differentiated. 4. In spite of these helpful developments, we think that CESR’s revised proposals do not go far enough to remove the serious concerns we expressed in our response to FESCO’s 2001 consultation. We continue to have serious concerns about both the absence of specific evidence of risks arising and the consequent vague regulatory objectives, and the detail of the text of the standards. We think that the standards can and should be considerably improved by making the changes we suggest in this response. We believe that many of the changes we suggest are implicit in CESR’s consultation paper and feedback statement, but need to be more positively brought out. Unless the standards can be improved as we suggest, we fear that hasty implementation would carry severe risks to the quality of European markets. Particularly in the area of market transparency, we think that these risks deserve a more measured approach: building CESR’s work on ATSs, and its proposed work on ‘bilateral’ systems and market transparency, into a wider and more thoroughly researched analysis of market quality and its regulatory implications, which would provide a sound basis for European regulation of this area and eventually feed into the Lamfalussy Level 2 and 3 work on the new ISD. We are eager to contribute positively to this analysis. (It is worth noting that the US system of ATS regulation was based on a thorough and publicly debated analysis of actual problems and risks, and resulted in a regime which gives a much clearer picture than does CESR’s latest draft document of circumstances in which regulatory requirements do or do not apply, and the reasons why.) GENERAL ISSUES Risks and regulatory objectives 5. The standards still appear to be based on a general concern that ATSs may pose risk (paragraphs 4, 9 and 10). CESR does not set out in detail the evidence of the reality of the risks which the standards are intended to forestall, nor the extent to which the market mechanism and existing requirements which are imposed on market participants will reduce or eliminate many risks. Indeed, in paragraph 5 of the Cost and Benefits Framework (paragraph II.5 of the Feedback Statement), CESR acknowledges explicitly that no specific risks have materialised: ‘The European marketplace has not developed in the way it was anticipated when CESR began to consider the need for a regulatory treatment of ATSs. While ATSs have made a considerable impact in wholesale bond markets, their role in equity trading in Europe is not yet significant. However, CESR considers that the risks posed by the potential penetration of the retail market by ATSs still remain’. Similarly, in paragraph II.7 of the Feedback Statement CESR makes an unsupported assertion that there would be ‘benefit’ in establishing a ‘proportionate regulatory approach’ for new systems in bond and derivative markets: provided such an approach is genuinely ‘proportionate’, it may not be particularly harmful, but no regulation is proportionate unless there is an identified need for it. 6. As we explained in our response to FESCO’s 2001 consultation, ATSs enhance the liquidity of the overall market by increasing competition. ATSs also bring business to regulated markets by laying off risks in them. ATSs innovate to provide services which are absent from existing market mechanisms, or to exploit new technologies, although their growth in Europe has been less than in the US because European exchanges have been more responsive to user needs. Thus even when ATSs do assume a more important role in the overall market, their impact is more likely to be beneficial than negative. It is important not to stifle these beneficial effects, especially since technological solutions and market forces are likely to limit any tendency to fragment markets or dilute transparency. 7. CESR’s concerns about ‘bilateral systems’ appear to be similarly general (paragraphs 15, 23), and the lack of any identified need for additional regulation of them would appear to belie CESR’s concern. For both ‘bilateral’ and ‘multilateral’ systems, effective and proportionate regulation will depend on clear identification and analysis of the risk to be tackled, and taking account of the effect of the discipline of the market mechanism in particular markets. It is not apparent how such an approach can be compatible with a rush to impose precautionary standards, with unpredictable and possibly harmful consequences, in response to hypothetical and generalised ‘risk’. 8. Apart from generalised statements about the need for market integrity, market efficiency, and investor protection, the objectives and purpose of the proposed standards are also still not clearly articulated. CESR’s focus appears to remain on transparency as an end in itself, rather than as one of a range of tools to achieve efficient and liquid markets. We welcome the greater recognition that increasing transparency may harm liquidity and the other elements which together contribute to the quality of markets, but this recognition comes across as incidental to the standards: for instance, the recognition of the need to allow deferred trade reporting in certain circumstances in order to preserve liquidity is hidden away in paragraph II.18 of the Feedback Statement, whereas it should be included in the standards paper itself. The articulation of objectives of regulatory standards for ATSs needs to be linked to the articulation of risks. 9. We do not object to the content of the proposed standards where they would require operators of ATSs to do things which it is appropriate to require of them. Many of the standards propose requirements which effectively already exist in many Member States. Provided that ‘qualifying systems’ are appropriately and narrowly defined, that their application is appropriately differentiated, and that standards are applied on a country of origin basis without country of destination overlap, most of the standards are unexceptionable (though we do have some detailed concerns which are set out in paragraphs 21-36 of this response). 10. However, this is not the case for Standard 3 on transparency. Market transparency is an important but complex issue which deserves thorough analysis in the context of both the ISD review and CESR’s planned work. Transparency standards for ATSs cannot sensibly or legitimately be introduced in isolation from a more general review of the role of transparency in the broader market, including how transparency interacts in different ways in different markets with other factors to maintain the overall quality of those markets. There is a grave danger that mandating transparency standards for ATSs now - before a comprehensive review has revealed whatever evidence of market failure there may be - would severely damage other important elements of market quality, in particular liquidity and competition. Furthermore, the lack of consistent reporting systems raises questions regarding the practicality of the means by which wide-ranging transparency can be achieved. 11. It is also very important that CESR avoids distorting markets by inappropriately reinforcing the competitive position of certain participants in them. For example, Euronext’s recent position paper on the internalisation of order flow raises important issues, but we believe that its conclusions, which are broadly consistent with CESR’s proposed Standard 3, are flawed. In an area as important to the quality and efficiency of Europe’s markets as transparency, CESR needs to consider very carefully all the arguments and all the evidence. The benefits foreseen from CESR’s proposed transparency standards for ATSs could prove illusory, and the rushed implementation of inappropriate standards could even harm the liquidity of both the overall market and regulated exchanges. 12. The absence of detailed evidential analysis of risks, the lack of clearly articulated objectives, and the consequent difficulty of conducting a meaningful cost/benefit analysis, underlines the importance of ensuring, if CESR does decide to rush through standards on ATSs, that the standards: Adopt a tightly circumscribed and narrowly defined definition of ‘qualifying systems, including a thorough analysis of systems which are and are not included (see paragraph 18 of this response); Introduce rigorous provisions on differentiation and disapplication in appropriate circumstances (see paragraph 13 of this response); Strictly apply country of origin control (which should apply to the conduct of business guidance as well), and do not allow Member States to derogate from the country of origin approach at will (see paragraphs 16-17 of this response); Defer the imposition of new transparency obligations until the broader review of the role of transparency in the markets as a whole has been completed (see paragraphs 10-11 and 25-29 of this response). Discretionary differentiation or disapplication of ‘standards’ 13. CESR’s proposals are formulated as ‘standards’ or ‘requirements’, whilst the provisions which would limit their application in certain markets are described as ‘commentary’, ‘guidance’, or ‘matters to be taken into account’. CESR appears to recognise that the market mechanism must be allowed to operate freely to serve users’ needs. We welcome CESR’s recognition of the need for differentiation or disapplication of the standards in relevant markets, and its recognition that, in particular for systems which provide services to professional markets, there is likely to be little or no need for them. However, leaving such differentiation to the discretion of national regulators risks inconsistent or inappropriate application of the ‘standards’ in different Member States. In order to avoid the risk of inappropriate, disproportionate, or damaging regulation, the standards should specify more definitely the circumstances in which regulators should not apply the standards. 14. In some cases where the ‘standards’ and their relationship to the ‘guidance’ which supports them is open to different interpretations, the Feedback Statement, in particular sections I and II, contains a much clearer, and in many cases helpful, statement of CESR’s intentions. CESR should make greater use of wording from the feedback statement to reduce or remove ambiguities, inconsistencies, or inappropriate application in the text of the ‘standards’ themselves. Interaction with the Commission’s review of the ISD 15. CESR stresses that its proposals are intended to be consistent with the Commission’s ISD revision proposals. But Paragraph 9 states that ‘the standards take into account the Commission’s preliminary proposals for revision of the ISD’. We and other commentators expressed serious concern about the Commission’s proposals in the 2001 consultation on reclassifying regulated markets and investment firms, with a new category of ‘non-regulated organised markets’ to which the ISD would not apply. It is by no means clear at present whether or not the Commission will persist with or amend (and if so how) its 2001 proposals. A further consultation by the Commission is expected shortly. We question whether CESR’s proposed June 2002 finalisation timetable is consistent with its stated intention to ensure consistency with the ISD, especially since the agreed shape of the new ISD cannot be clear by then. We also question CESR’s assertion in paragraph 22 that ‘systems will be subjected to similar market integrity/efficiency disciplines under a revised ISD regardless of whether they are ultimately classified as investment firms or organised or regulated markets’ – the relative obligations of investment firms and regulated markets, in particular the trade reporting obligations of the former, remain highly contentious unresolved issues in the Commission’s 2001 proposals. Country of origin application of the ‘standards’ 16. We welcome CESR’s support for the avoidance of overlapping application of ATS standards by different Member States. The statement in Paragraph I.8 of the Feedback Statement that regulatory responsibility lies solely with the country of origin of the investment firm which operates the system is welcome, and should be included in the standards paper itself, where only Standards 1, 5, and 6 specify which regulator’s rules apply. Furthermore, Standards 1, 5, and 6 allocate responsibility to the home country regulatory authority. It would be inappropriate and impractical for a system operated by a branch to be regulated anywhere else but the country of origin, except to the extent that the home State authoriser has a prudential responsibility under the directives. The standards should state explicitly that for cross-border services the country where system users or their clients are located has no role in the regulation of the system. 17. As things stand, however, we fear that the usefulness of the mere statement of country of origin control will be limited because regulatory authorities in some Member States do not have the authority to apply the standards on this basis (Paragraph 25), or are unwilling to accept it (Footnote 9). It is particularly disappointing that CESR has not rejected Footnote 9: the mutual recognition which is essential if the country of origin approach is to yield benefits to European markets and investors will be undermined if Member States are at liberty to ignore it whenever they wish. Paragraph I.8 of the Feedback Statement also implies that Member States may continue to interpret Article 11 of the ISD to impose country of destination conduct of business rules: such an overlay on country of origin control of ‘market integrity standards’ would give too much scope for interference with the country of origin regulation of the system’s market-facing conduct, and is inconsistent with both the Electronic Commerce Directive and what we know of the proposed revision of the ISD. ATSs (as defined by CESR) could well decide not to offer their services on a cross-border basis if required to face multiple requirements across different jurisdictions. Definition of ‘qualifying systems’ (CESR’s Question 1) 18. Despite the welcome restriction to ‘multilaterality’, the boundary of the definition of ‘qualifying systems’ is still not well-defined. In the absence of specified exclusions, this lack of definition gives too much scope for the imposition of the standards in inappropriate circumstances. The specific exclusion in Paragraph 14 of firms which act as a single counterparty to all transactions is helpful. However, CESR should limit the definition further to ensure that the ‘standards’ cannot be applied to systems which do not have regulated-market-like characteristics. In particular, a ‘qualifying system’ should be defined in terms of the system itself, not the ‘entity’ which operates it, and should exclude order-routing systems, systems where the ‘non-discretionary rules’ are a matter of internal procedure rather than publicly-offered service, systems which are not automated, and systems where the operating firm takes trading risk or commits its capital. Furthermore, CESR should define terms. For example, ‘buying and selling interests’ should be restricted to firm orders, not indications of interest; ‘or results in a contract’ should exclude the circumstance where a transaction is subsequently agreed outside the system: so that the definition is restricted to systems which are capable of automatically forming binding contracts as a result of the input of orders. CESR should also provide comprehensive analysis of what types of systems would or would not be included in the definition. The lack of definition in the boundary of ‘qualifying systems’ reflects the absence of thorough analysis of risks and objectives. We believe that if CESR were to perform such an analysis, it would point to an appropriate and unambiguous definition. 19. In order to avoid imposing burdensome requirements on systems which do not have a large enough share of the overall market to give rise to regulatory concern, CESR should consider applying a de minimis limit, below which the standards would not apply. The limit should be defined as a percentage of the overall volume (off- and on-exchange) for a product in the European time zone. The US applies a limit of 5% of the overall market, below which regulatory requirements do not apply. We therefore suggest that CESR could initially set a limit of 5% of the overall market. CESR should ascertain how many systems in different markets would be captured by a 5% de minimis limit, and publish the results: this information would in itself, perhaps accompanied by a comparison with the number of systems which would be captured by a 10% limit, provide very helpful evidence of the impact and risks of ATSs in Europe, and therefore help to determine whether incremental regulation of European ATSs is justified. There should also be a de minimis limit to exclude systems where products are infrequently traded in the overall market: in these circumstances, even a larger market share than 5% should not give rise to the regulatory concerns that underlie the standards. 20. We note CESR’s concern about the potential ‘risks’ of ‘bilateral systems’, and its intention to undertake a broader review of them and of market transparency. As noted in paragraph 2 of this response, we and colleagues in other associations are very keen to assist CESR with expert advice on this important issue. It will be important for CESR to ground this work in a thorough analysis of existing market dynamics and transparency arrangements, identification of specific risks to market quality, and clear specification of regulatory objectives. Indeed, as noted in paragraphs 10-11 and 25-28 of this response, we think that CESR should carry forward its current work on ATS transparency - even as applied to multilateral ‘qualifying systems’ - in the context of the wider review of market transparency, including analysis of how transparency interacts with other features of market quality, rather than to rush through ATS transparency standards at this stage. DETAILED COMMENTS ON THE STANDARDS (CESR’s Question 2) Introductory paragraph 21. The introductory paragraph (2 on page 7) states that the ‘standards set out the requirements that authorities…should impose’, whilst the commentary ‘covers the circumstances in which requirements may be differentially imposed’. Differential application and disapplication of the standards in relevant circumstances should not be discretionary, but obligatory in the same way as the ‘imposition’ of the standards itself (see paragraph 13 of this response). Standards 1-7 22. All standards should state explicitly that they are to be applied only by the country of origin regulator, and may not be applied by the country of the user or the user’s customer where this differs from the country of origin regulator. Generally, application of the standards by the home country regulator to a system operated by a branch in another Member State would be inappropriate (subject to legitimate home country prudential supervision under the directives) - see paragraphs 16-17 of this response. Standard 1: Registration and notifications 23. Standard 1 now requires firms to ‘register/authorise’ the establishment of a ‘qualifying system’. It is not evident precisely what such a requirement is intended to mean, but it would not be appropriate for regulators to impose a separate licensing requirement as a prerequisite for an already licensed firm to offer an ATS service. A ‘standard’ about the provision of information to regulators should be worded exclusively in terms of ‘notification’. Standard 2: Fair and orderly trading 24. We welcome the recognition in the third paragraph of the commentary that regulators ‘should not need to intervene in properly operating commercial disciplines between purely professional players’. Given the degree of regulatory control which the standard envisages over the detail of the mechanism of the system/user relationship, and in order to limit the scope for disproportionate regulatory intervention, this statement should be strengthened to specify that the standard should not be applied to professional-only ATSs unless exceptional circumstances, such as the ATS exerting a dominant role in price formation, threaten the integrity of the wider market. Standard 3: Publication of trading information 25. This standard mandates an absolute level of transparency which is wholly new by comparison with FESCO’s previous proposals, especially where pre-trade transparency is concerned, and which would elevate transparency above all the other factors of market quality in a way which could reduce liquidity, discourage innovation, distort competition, and diminish the competitiveness of European markets and their ability to respond to users’ demand. CESR is about to launch a wide-ranging review of transparency in the market as a whole. The Commission is about to consult again on the ISD review, where its original market transparency proposals were controversial and heavily criticised. A wide-ranging imposition of mandatory transparency on one particular sector of the market, before there has been a thorough analysis of where the problems are or what the impact on the market as a whole would be, would pre-judge the outcome of both CESR’s and the Commission’s further work. 26. Our stress on the need for a thorough and well-informed analysis and debate before additional transparency requirements are imposed does not mean that we are opposed to an appropriate level of price transparency in all markets. On the contrary, transparency is such an important element of the quality of markets that it is vital to get the regulatory approach to it right. But CESR’s analysis in the proposed standards and guidance does not take account of the importance and complexity of the issues. The proposed standard appears still to be designed purely according to the traditional model of the listed equity markets, where regulated markets occupy a dominant role: liquidity is provided primarily by investors rather than intermediaries, and transparency has long been recognised as a key factor in the quality of that market. Even in equity markets, however, regulatory intervention would be justified only if it could be demonstrated that fragmentation was significantly harming price formation, or that retail transactions were being conducted on ATSs at worse prices than those obtainable on regulated markets. The standard does not discuss, for example, the various ways of defining and enforcing pre-trade transparency. It does not discuss the impact of changes to commercial judgements intermediaries might make about charging commission as opposed to retaining the spread. 27. Non-equity markets in turn have evolved different balances between transparency and other factors of market quality, reflecting the relatively lesser importance of price transparency to the price-formation process. In particular, in fixed interest and OTC derivatives, regulated markets do not play a dominant role, most instruments are infrequently traded or tailor-made, offered and traded prices provide little information about supply and demand (except in benchmark government bonds), and the development of systems for pre-trade transparency and reporting of completed trades would be enormously costly without substantial corresponding benefit. The current level of transparency in these markets has not inhibited significant growth and diversification. 28. The absence in CESR’s proposed standard of any differentiation between types of market, or any apparent discretion or obligation for regulators to vary the transparency requirement to take account of specific market features, is very disturbing in view of the way in which commercial incentives tend to maintain an appropriate balance between transparency and other market-quality factors, particularly in the debt and derivative markets: the final paragraph of the commentary acknowledges the value of market-induced levels of transparency, but effectively negates it by providing for it to be superseded at regulators’ discretion. If it is to be retained, this standard requires extensive revision to limit mandatory transparency obligations to circumstances where their absence would either imperil the integrity of the wider market, or disadvantage vulnerable market users, and also to require regulators to consider the differing role of transparency in different markets as one of a number of factors which together contribute to market quality. As explained in paragraphs 10-11 and 26 of this response, we believe that the necessary revision can best be achieved as part of the imminent broader reviews of transparency issues in the market as a whole. 29. Paragraph II.18 of the Feedback Statement contains provisions about ensuring ‘pragmatic transparency obligations when providing delayed reporting for risk positions’. Given the important role which delayed publication of risk positions fulfils in maintaining market liquidity, such a provision should be included in the ‘standard’ itself. Standard 4: Monitoring 30. As we said in our response to FESCO’s 2001 consultation, a regulatory requirement to monitor compliance with system rules would be appropriate only in order to protect the interests of vulnerable market users. Even for such users, conduct of business obligations should be sufficient to protect their interests in most circumstances. CESR acknowledges in the second paragraph of the commentary that for professional users and where the system does not play an important role monitoring will be less important: CESR should specify that the standard should not be applied in these circumstances unless, exceptionally, for instance because the ATS has a dominant role in price formation, the integrity of the wider market or the interests of vulnerable users are threatened. Standard 5: Arrangements with Regulators Facilitating Market Integrity and Investor Protection 31. It is reasonable for regulators to expect operators of ATSs to be able to cooperate with regulators to facilitate monitoring of trading to prevent market abuse. However the active role for the system operator which the final paragraph of the commentary envisages is likely to be both costly and, especially in fixed interest and derivative markets given their particular characteristics, difficult or impossible to perform. CESR should specify that the standard should not apply in circumstances where monitoring by the system operator would be either disproportionately costly or yield no benefit given the characteristics of the market. 32. The use of the term ‘client abuse’ is not appropriate, especially since user-facing issues are now to be dealt with via conduct of business rules, and it should be deleted. Conduct of business obligations should be avoided in market integrity standards. 33. CESR should ensure consistency in this area with the proposed Market Abuse Directive. Standards in this area should not be finalised before the final shape of the Market Abuse standards is apparent. 34. Before implementing Standard 4 and Standard 5, CESR should explain and justify its position as to why the normal processes of regulation of investment firms are inadequate. Standard 6: Systems 35. Under existing regulation, investment firms will already be subject to prudential requirements to exercise proper management and controls over their systems. The standard should state that additional requirements should not be imposed where these other requirements already provide sufficient regulatory control. The comments in the final paragraph of the commentary about the need for less regulatory obligations where sophisticated users are involved should be strengthened to provide that the standard should not apply to such systems unless, exceptionally, the integrity of the broader market was threatened. This should be the case, contrary to the final sentence, even if the ATS is a monopoly provider: sometimes systems will have a monopoly because the volumes in the market will not support more than one platform; sophisticated users will always find new ways of forming a market if one is needed. Similarly, in the second paragraph of the commentary, CESR should state explicitly that standby trading facilities should not be required except in circumstances of exceptional threat to overall market integrity, for example where the ATS has a dominant role in price formation. Standard 7: Clearing and Settlement 36. We repeat our previous comment that in non-retail markets clarity of responsibilities for clearing and settlement should not be a matter for regulation. Reclassification of user-facing standards as guidance on conduct of business rules (CESR’s Question 3) 37. This reclassification helpfully reduces overlap between ATS ‘standards’ and conduct of business ‘standards’. In line with our comments on CESR’s conduct of business standard proposals, and with CESR’s policy in the ATS ‘standards’ and the Commission’s policy on the ISD review, CESR should reduce overlap further by specifying the application of the country of origin principle here also. 38. CESR refers in the second paragraph of section 2.2 to the requirement in ISD Article 11(1) to take account of the professional nature of customers. CESR should build on the differentiation principles in the ATS standards to exclude these conduct of business principles for relationships with professional users of systems. Item c) in particular implies a level of obligation to ensure professional users have access to information about types of instruments traded which is unnecessary for users of that level of sophistication. 39. It will be important to ensure that CESR’s standards on classification of investors and conduct of business rules draw the boundaries appropriately between counterparties, professional investors, and retail investors, and apply appropriately light requirements to business with professionals, and none at all for counterparty business. Similarly, any additional guidance on conduct of business rules for operators of qualifying systems should not apply at all to inter-dealer systems. FEEDBACK STATEMENT Comments on summary of key issues 1 – We do not think that CESR has resolved all of the issues surrounding the relationship with the ISD revision - see paragraph 15 of this response. 2 – We have continuing concerns about the definition and the extent to which it needs further modification to avoid impediments to competition - see paragraphs 18-19 of this response. See paragraph 20 of this response on the proposed wider review of ‘bilateral’ systems. 3 – We welcome CESR’s moves towards differentiating the standards (though we think that the status of ‘differentiation’ should be equivalent to the status of the ‘standards’ themselves - see paragraph 13 above). We also welcome the clearer statement of where regulatory responsibility lies. However, concerns about differing implementation by national authorities remain – see paragraph 17 of this response. 4 - We welcome CESR’s moves towards differentiating the standards (though we think that the status of ‘differentiation’ should be equivalent to the status of the ‘standards’ themselves - see paragraph 13 of this response). 5 – We welcome the separation of conduct of business guidance, though we have some continuing concerns - see paragraphs 37-39 of this response. 6 - We welcome CESR’s moves towards differentiating the standards (though we think that the status of ‘differentiation’ should be equivalent to the status of the ‘standards’ themselves - see paragraph 13 of this response). Whilst it may not be appropriate to exclude inter-professional trading networks altogether, the ‘standards’ should go further to specify that they should apply to such networks only in exceptional circumstances. The relationship between users and underlying retail clients should be governed by conduct of business rules. 7 – We welcome CESR’s statement that its aim is to balance risks against benefits of ATSs. We think that this will be possible to do only with a clearer articulation of risks and regulatory objectives, which is particularly critical for Standard 3 – see paragraphs 5-12 and 25-28 of this response. 8 – We welcome CESR’s strong endorsement of the country of origin approach, but we have identified in paragraphs 16-17 of this response a number of respects in which CESR should consolidate it. 9 and II (Costs and Benefits Framework) – We welcome CESR’s commitment to cost/benefit analysis. We also welcome the thoroughness with which CESR has identified the breadth of possible impacts in the Costs and Benefits Framework in section II: as we have noted above, this contains much material which should be incorporated into the text of the ‘standards’ themselves: the extent to which possible impacts are mitigable depends to a very large extent on whether CESR modifies the standards as we have proposed in this response, and how well CESR thereby controls its implementation by national authorities. Our difficulty in providing specific information about the magnitude of costs and benefits derives to a large extent from uncertainty about the practical effect of CESR’s standards, which is itself a function of the poor definition of objectives, risks, background analysis of existing market disciplines and requirements, and differentiation and disapplication of standards in different markets. If CESR ensures that implementation is well-controlled and proportionate, costs and ‘harm to the markets’ (i.e. ‘negative benefit’) will decrease, and the possibility of benefit without disproportionate cost will increase. The lack of certainty about the effect of Standard 3, and the enormous harm which could be caused by inappropriate or disproportionate imposition of transparency obligations, make the stakes so high that CESR should not carry it forward without significantly more thorough definition of objectives and analysis of risks, costs and benefits. The following cost/benefit factors can be identified Withdrawal of ATSs from the European markets because of market-insensitive regulatory requirements depriving them of market share and industry support, with consequent harm to innovation and competition in European markets. Withdrawal of ATSs from cross-border service provision because of overlapping and/or inappropriate regulation, with consequent reduction of competition in European markets Withdrawal of liquidity from and reduction of competition in European markets because of market-insensitive mandatory transparency (this represents a much greater ‘European market fragmentation’ threat than any development of competing platforms within Europe). Cost of system development to meet any pre-trade transparency requirements. Cost of system development to enable reporting of completed trades; this cost would be compounded by the complexity of different reporting mechanisms to different regulated markets. Cost of system development to meet any requirement to monitor market abuse. London Investment Banking Association 15th March 2002 TMMB/Mar14/COM77A MEMBERS OF THE LONDON INVESTMENT BANKING ASSOCIATION Ansbacher & Co Limited ABN AMRO Bank N.V. Arbuthnot Latham & Co., Limited BNP Paribas Bank Insinger de Beaufort plc Barclays Capital Bear, Stearns International Limited Beeson Gregory Limited CIBC World Markets Plc Cazenove & Co. Ltd Close Brothers Corporate Finance Ltd Collins Stewart Limited Commerzbank AG Credit Suisse First Boston International Daiwa Securities SMBC Europe Limited Dawnay, Day & Co., Limited Deutsche Bank AG London Dresdner Kleinwort Wasserstein Goldman Sachs International Greenhill & Co. International LLP Hawkpoint Partners Limited HSBC Investment Bank plc ING Barings Instinet UK Ltd Investec Bank (UK) Limited JPMorgan Chase Bank KBC Peel Hunt Knight Securities International Ltd Lazard Lehman Brothers Merrill Lynch Europe PLC Mizuho International plc Morgan Stanley International Ltd Nomura International plc N M Rothschild & Sons Limited Robert W. Baird Group Limited Schroder Salomon Smith Barney Singer & Friedlander Holdings Limited Société Générale 3i Group plc The Toronto Dominion Bank UBS Warburg Westdeutsche Landesbank Girozentrale