Status competition, inequality, and fertility Shenk, Kaplan & Hooper Electronic Supplementary Materials (ESM) Status competition, inequality, and fertility: Implications for the demographic transition Mary K. Shenk, Hillard S. Kaplan & Paul L. Hooper Contents ESM Section 1. Additional Model Details ESM Section 2. Additional Figure 2 4 1 Status competition, inequality, and fertility Shenk, Kaplan & Hooper ESM Section 1. Additional Model Details Fitness maximization Each parents attempts to maximize fitness with respect to two decision variables: a and s. The parent’s fertility f is implied by any given values of a and s. Isolating f in eq. (3) in the main text yields π = πVp ⁄(π + π ). Substituting this expression into eq. (2) in the main text yields the following fitness maximand: W(π, π ) = πVp A(π)R(π Μ ) π+π (E1) General simulation details The simulation was implemented in the R programming language (R Core Team 2015). Each run of the simulation consists of multiple generations that reproduce, invest in their offspring, and die. Ecological parameters are held constant within a run, but vary across runs. Each runs continues for an average of 50 generations, a length of time selected to allow the expression of a representative sample of the dynamics of a given ecology. In each generation, the decision variables a and s (and thus f) are optimized to maximize expected fitness (eq. (E1)) for each parent given the distribution of sΜ (i.e. post-shock status investments) observed in their own generation using the optim() function. To yield π Μ , the value of s chosen by a parent is then multiplied by the shock value π, sampled from a gamma distribution with mean 1 and shape parameter exp(Q) using the rgamma() function. Inequality in shocks is greater for smaller values of exp(Q). For ease of interpretation, inequality in shocks is reported in terms of their coefficient of variation, CV(π). As noted in the discussion, the simulation does not represent variation across parents in the payoffs to PI. As a result, the optimal investment is invariant across parents (i.e. a single scalar value within each generation), despite variation in budgets (Kaplan 1996). As a result, the multiplication of this value of s by a gamma distribution with a fixed shape parameter yields roughly equal degrees of inequality across generations, without a build-up of inequality. Simulation details underlying Fig. 1 Two populations were simulated with two different levels of inequality in shocks to social capital. For the low-inequality condition, exp(Q) was set to 5, resulting in CV(π) = 0.4 and gini(π)=0.24; in the high-inequality condition, exp(Q) was set to 1, resulting in CV(π) = 1.0 and gini(π) = 0.50. To illustrate the effects of changing the shape of the effect of social capital function, the fitness-investment relationship was plotted for five values of πΜ (0.25, 0.375, 0.5, 0.625, and 0.75) and relatively lower and higher values π (2.5 and 10). (Given the illustrative intent of this figure, the range of values it explores is narrower than that of Fig. 2, which reports a wider, more systematic exploration.) Simulation details underlying Fig. 2 and ESM Fig. E1 A total of 1400 runs were simulated. In each run, the inflection point for the effect of social capital function πΜ was sampled from the set (0.25, 0.375, 0.5, 0.625, 0.75). The slope parameter π was sampled from the set (0, 1.25, 2.5, 5, 10, 20). These parameter ranges produce reasonably wide variation in the intensity and steepness of the effect of social capital function. For each run, the value of Q determining the shape parameter for inequality in social capital was sampled from a uniform distribution ranging from ln(1) to ln(15). These shape values yield gini coefficients in the range 0.14—0.51, similar to the range observed for socioeconomic variables in small- and large-scale human societies (Borgerhoff Mulder et al. 2009). The inflection point πΜ and slope parameter πΌ for the effect of survival-and-productivity capital were held constant at 0.5 and 10, respectively. The growth constant g was held fixed at 12. The number of 2 Status competition, inequality, and fertility Shenk, Kaplan & Hooper generations in each run was determined stochastically as 1/T, with T sampled from a normal distribution with mean 1/50 and coefficient of variation 1/3. The size of the population in each run was held constant at a value sampled from a normal distribution with mean 500 and coefficient of variation 1/3. The mean value of π Μ in the first generation of each run was sampled from a normal distribution with mean 0.1 and coefficient of variation 1/3. To summarize the results, the loess() function was used with default settings to estimate local polynomial fits for fertility (Fig. 2) and social capital (ESM Fig. E1) as a function of CV(π) for each unique combination of πΜ and π. Simulation details underlying Fig. 3 One run was simulated for each of the following four conditions: (a) exp(Q) = 5 and πΜ = 0.25; (b) exp(Q) = 1 and πΜ = 0.25; (c) exp(Q) = 5 and πΜ = 0.75; (d) exp(Q) = 1 and πΜ = 0.75. π was held constant at 2.5 across conditions. The inflection point πΜ and slope parameter πΌ for the effect of survival-andproductivity capital were held constant at 0.5 and 10, respectively. The growth constant g was held fixed at 12. Each run consisted of 50 generations each with 500 individuals. The mean value of π Μ in the first generation of each run was sampled from a normal distribution with mean 0.1 and coefficient of variation 1/3. Simulation details underlying Fig. 4 A total of 60 runs were simulated. 20 runs sampled uniformly from a gradient in which πΜ varied linearly from 0.25 to 0.75. 20 runs sampled from a gradient in which πΜ varied across this range, and exp(Q) varied linearly from ln(1) to ln(15). 20 runs sampled from a gradient in which πΜ and exp(Q) varied, and πΜ also varied linearly from 0.25 to 0.75. The slope parameters π were πΌ were held constant at 2.5 and 10, respectively. The growth constant g was held fixed at 12. The number of generations in each run was determined stochastically as 1/T, with T sampled from a normal distribution with mean 1/50 and coefficient of variation 1/3. The size of the population in each run was held constant at a value sampled from a normal distribution with mean 500 and coefficient of variation 1/3. The mean value of π Μ in the first generation of each run was sampled from a normal distribution with mean 0.1 and coefficient of variation 1/3. The loess() function was used with smoothing parameter 0.9 to estimate local polynomial fits for fertility as a function of the ecological gradient for each of the three gradients. References Borgerhoff Mulder, Monique, et al. (2009) Intergenerational wealth transmission and the dynamics of inequality in small-scale societies. Science 326: 682-688. Kaplan, Hillard. (1996) A theory of fertility and parental investment in traditional and modern human societies. American Journal of Physical Anthropology 101: 91-135. R Core Team (2015) R: A Language and Environment for Statistical Computing. Vienna: R Foundation for Statistical Computing. 3 Status competition, inequality, and fertility Shenk, Kaplan & Hooper 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (a) r=0 ^r = 0.25 ^r = 0.375 ^r = 0.5 ^r = 0.625 ^r = 0.75 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 ESM Section 2. Additional Figure ESM Fig. E1. Mean optimal investment in social capital (s) as a function of inequality in the inputs to status (CV(π), varying across the horizontal axis) and the inflection point (πΜ , varying across the dashed and solid lines) and slope (π, varying across panels) of the effect of social capital function. The simulations underlying this figure are identical to those underlying Fig. 2 in the main text. Inequality (CV(e)) r = 1.25 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (b) 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Inequality (CV(e)) r = 2.5 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (c) 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Inequality (CV(e)) r=5 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (d) 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Inequality (CV(e)) r = 10 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (e) 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Inequality (CV(e)) r = 20 0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 Social capital (s× ) (f) 4 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 Inequality (CV(e))