Antitrust, Regulation, and Deregulation The Government’s Role in Promoting Efficiency What is the role of government in promoting economic efficiency when there is market failure (the unregulated market is inefficient). Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-2 Why the Government Might Intervene Three main reasons why the government would intervene in a market: To promote productive efficiency Resources are employed at the lowest cost. To promote innovation Creation and application of new technology To promote allocative efficiency Resources are distributed in the way that society values most. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-3 Why the Government Might Intervene (cont’d) Most economists agree that the best way to achieve efficiency and promote innovation is through competition. However, competitive markets do not always arise naturally, and may even be undesirable in some cases. (market failure) Too few competitors / barriers to entry Externalities (costs/benefits not price in market) Assymetric information Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-4 Natural and Optimal Market Structures The natural structure of a market is the degree of competition that would occur in the absence of government intervention. The optimal structure of a market is the degree of competition that maximizes allocative efficiency. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-5 Natural and Optimal Market Structures (cont’d) The government will tend to intervene if the natural structure differs significantly from the optimal structure. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-6 The Perfect Competition Benchmark The efficiency of a market is measured by comparing the existing price and output to the price and output that would result from marginal cost pricing in a perfectly competitive market. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-7 Figure 13.1 Consumer and Producer Surplus With Competitive and Monopoly Pricing Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-8 3 Major Pieces of Legislation to address Anti-Competitive Markets Sherman Anti-trust Act (1890) Anti-competitive behavior, mergers Clayton Act (1914) Price discrimination (simple) Tie-in sales Robinson-Putman (1936) More detailed/complex definition of price discrimination Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-9 Sherman Anti-Trust Act Divided into three sections. Sec 1 delineates and prohibits specific means of anticompetitive conduct, (e.g., contracts/agreements) Sec 2 deals with end results that are anticompetitive in nature. (actual pricing tactics, or non-compete) Sec 3 simply extends the provisions of Section 1 to U.S. territories and the District of Columbia. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-10 Sherman Anti-Trust Act Section 1: "Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal."[13] Section 2: "Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony [. . . ]"[14 Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-11 The Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 (cont’d) Under the Sherman Act, courts may: Break monopolies up into smaller firms Divestiture – divest the company of its smaller firms 1980 – AT&T break-up Prohibit certain business practices Predatory pricing: P < min ATC to drive competitors out Supposedly Standard Oil in the 30’s Price fixing: setting P > MC and agreeing not to compete Eastern/American Airlines Not compete: geographic/product lines Impose fines on firms Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-12 The Clayton Act of 1914 The Clayton Act prohibits: Price discrimination that reduces competition Product tie-ins Required purchase of another more elastic good to be able to purchase monopoly good IBM and computer cards The purchase of stock issued by competing companies Serving on the board of directors of a competing company Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-13 The Clayton Act of 1914 (cont’d) Established treble damages Plaintiffs can recover three times the actual damage. Exempted labor unions from antitrust law Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-14 The Federal Trade Commission Act of 1914 Created the Federal Trade Commission (FTC), the agency that identifies and pursues antitrust cases Department of Justice (DOJ), agency for attorneys that prosecute the cases Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-15 The Robinson-Patman Act of 1936 Clarified the definition of price discrimination discrimination in price; on at least 2 consummated sales; from the same seller; to 2 different purchasers; of "commodities" of like grade and quality; the effect may be "substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any line of commerce." Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-16 Enforcement of Antitrust Policy The Department of Justice (DOJ) and the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) have the power to sue firms in order to: Force violators to stop anticompetitive practices Break up existing firms into smaller ones Prevent the formation of very large firms Impose fines on firms that violate antitrust legislation Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-17 Changes in Enforcement Since the Sherman Act of 1890, enforcement of antitrust legislation has become less stringent. Technological change and globalization have lead to increased competition. (contestable markets) Telecomm – wireless and landlines Music – record manufacturers and ITunes Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-18 Mergers In addition to enforcing antitrust laws, the FTC may try to block or alter a merger. A merger occurs when two firms combine to form a single firm. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-19 How do we tell? Market concentration refers to the size and distribution of firm market shares and the number of firms in the market. Economists use two measures of industry concentration: Four-firm Concentration Ratio The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index 20 Attempts to Measure Market Concentration four-firm concentration ratio is often utilized to characterize/determine whether a market is an oligopoly. market share of the four largest firms in an industry Herfindahl index, also known as Herfindahl-Hirschman Index or HHI, widely applied in competition law and antitrust. sum of the squares of the market shares of each individual firm. Decreases in the Herfindahl index generally indicate a loss of pricing power and an increase in competition, whereas increases imply the opposite. 21 Four-Firm Concentration Ratio The four-firm concentration ratio (CR4) measures market concentration by adding the market shares of the four largest firms in an industry. If CR4 > 60, then the market is likely to be oligopolistic. 22 Example Firm Nike Market Share 62% New Balance 15.5% Asics 10% Adidas 4.3% CR 4 = 62 15.5 10 4.3 91.8 23 Figure 12.11 Four-Firm Concentration Ratio (CR4) for Selected Industries in 1997 24 The Herfindahl-Hirschman Index The Herfindahl-Hirschman index (HHI) is found by summing the squares of the market shares of all firms in an industry. Advantages over the CR4 measure: Captures changes in market shares Uses data on all firms 25 Example Firm Market Share Nike 62% New Balance 15.5% Asics 10% Adidas 4.3% HHI 62 15.5 10 4.3 4,202.74 2 2 2 2 26 Example (cont’d) What happens if market shares are evenly distributed? Firm Market Share Nike 22.95% New Balance 22.95% Asics 22.95% Adidas 22.95% HHI 22.95 2 22.95 2 22.95 2 22.95 2 2,106.81 CR 4 91.8 27 Non-competitive Oligopolies Non-competitive/collusive behavior (cooperative oligopolies) Cartels: firms may collude to raise prices and restrict production in the same way as a monopoly. Where there is a formal agreement for such collusion, this is known as a cartel. Dominant Firm/Price Leader: collude in an attempt to stabilize unstable markets, so as to reduce the risks inherent in these markets for investment and product development. does not require formal agreement although for the act to be illegal there must be a real communication between companies for example, in some industries, there may be an acknowledged market leader which informally sets prices to which other producers respond, known as price leadership. Stackleberg price-leader model 28 Types of Mergers Conglomerate Merger Firms in unrelated industries merge. Vertical Merger A firm buys another firm that is either above it or below it in the supply chain. Horizontal Merger A combination of two firms that are in the same industry Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-29 The Government’s Position on Mergers The government’s position on mergers has changed over the years, from preventing the merger of relatively small firms to allowing the merger of large companies. Bush(43) – focused only on horizontal mergers Obama – returned to review both horizontal and vertical mergers (Ticketmaster) In general, a merger that results in a Herfindahl-Hirschman Index of less than 1800 will not be challenged. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-30 Deregulation The current trend is for the government to remove regulation and allow market forces to determine prices, output, profits, and industry structure. Factors favoring deregulation: Difficulty in determining a regulatory strategy Advances in technology that have lead to increased competition Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-31 Life Lessons Two wrongs don’t make a right. In the 1930s many states passed “Fair Trade” laws that effectively outlawed low prices. Fair trade – same price in each market Doesn’t reflect different supply/costs (or demand) As a result, consumers faced higher prices and retail stores were protected from bankruptcy. These laws were eliminated in 1975. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-32 Reasons For Deregulation In deciding to deregulate an industry, the government must be confident that private market outcomes will be more efficient than regulated outcomes. Will deregulation affect product safety or reliability? Will deregulation eliminate service for some customers? Will the benefits of deregulation accrue to only a few customers? Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-33 Application: Deregulation of the Airline Industry In 1978, the U.S. Airline Deregulation Act removed regulations on prices, the number of carriers and route assignments. (some) Passengers have benefited from the resulting price competition among air carriers. FAA set similar rates for flights of similar difference, regardless of destination (and demand in large/small cities) “legacy” losses and gains Smaller cities saw higher prices and fewer flight Larger cities: lower prices, more flights Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-34 Application: Deregulation of theTelecommunications In 1980, AT&T and the “Baby Bells” were broken up into 8 different companies AT&T could offer only long distance service and had to compete with MCI and Sprint (no longer a monopoly) Baby Bells’ customer could choose their LD provider Took several years for AT&T market share to drop below 80% Colbert video – “it’s all back together again” FCC missed that there were economies of scale – led to mergers to reduce costs 1996 Congress passed the Telecommunications Act Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-35 Application: Deregulation of theTelecommunications 1996 Congress passed the Telecommunications Act Required Baby Bells and GTE to open their local markets to all competitors Established prices that Bells could charge competitors for “renting” their lines and switching equipment Prices were set below incurred (or historical) costs Decreased incentive to maintain and update existing equipment Previously business line rates set higher than costs to subsidize residential phone service New entrants targeted business customers and high long distance usage customers (winners) Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-36 Strategy and Policy The Department of Justice takes on Cingular–AT&T Wireless merger In 2004, Cingular agree to buy AT&T Wireless, creating a company with an HHI of 8,000 in some markets. In 2005, the firm was required to divest the entire AT&T Wireless network in the 13 markets where concentration was highest. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-37 Summary The U.S. government may intervene in the private sector to promote productive efficiency, innovation, or allocative efficiency. U.S. antitrust policy is based on: The Sherman Act, which forbids monopolies The Clayton Act, which prohibits price discrimination The Federal Trade Commission Act, which established the FTC Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-38 Summary (cont’d) Some actions are per se illegal; simply engaging in them is enough to establish guilt. Conglomerate mergers are not usually challenged. Vertical and horizontal mergers may be challenged if they reduce competition. In the case of a natural monopoly, it may be preferable for the government to regulate the firm. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-39 Summary (cont’d) Deregulation of an industry may be appropriate because of changes in technology and globalization. Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-40 Table 13.1 Excerpts From Section 1 and 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-41 Table 13.2 Summary of Key U.S. Antitrust Legislation Copyright © 2006 Pearson Addison-Wesley. All rights reserved. 13-42