Investment, risk and expectation in KwaZulu-Natal’s rural economy Elizabeth Hull London School of Economics Introduction 3864 hectares, most of which is divided into 10 hectare plots rented and managed by individual farmers, of which there are 314 altogether. The remaining land within the scheme is divided into 243 smaller ‘gardens’ of 0.02 hectares each. Beyond the scheme reside many ‘dry-land farmers’ and other residents, relying on small and intermittent rainfall, and various other limited sources of income. According to the deprivation index of the Health District Barometer of 2008/09, based on a range of demographic and socio-economic data, the district of Umkhanyakude is the 2nd most deprived of 52 provinces nationally (Day et al. 2010: 197).In a region characterised by high levels of unemployment and ill-health, 85.2 per cent of households within the local municipality of Jozini earn less than R1,500 per month (2001 census). This paper examines the financial strategies of people living in the Makhathini region of northern KwaZulu-Natal, and a recent attempt by the government to assist small-scale business enterprise in the area. Specifically, it looks at the formation of a ‘community bank’ called Simunye, accredited, funded and regulated by the South African MicroFinance Apex Fund (SAMAF), a branch of the Department of Trade and Industry. During the period of my research, the bank was still in its infancy and had not yet begun providing loans. One condition laid out by SAMAF was that the bank demonstrated its effective operation through regular inflows and outflows of cash, prior to paying out any loans. As such, members were encouraged to invest money in order to qualify for a loan at a later stage. The paper describes the factors that enhanced or inhibited the willingness of members to invest in the bank. Thus, rather than to assess the success or failure of micro-finance schemes, the purpose of the paper is to describe how new expectations for credit feature within a range of diverse financial strategies, in this particular context of rural KwaZulu-Natal. The research is based on interviews with 34 members of Simunye bank, and on information and observations from general and board meetings of Simunye. The micro-finance paradigm in South Africa With a growing realisation in recent years of the failure of the free-market to provide stability and financial security for a significant proportion of the world’s population, a global reconsideration of the role of the state has taken place. Under continued pressure to reduce deficits, cut spending and employ fiscal prudence, yet with the increasing acknowledgement of the necessity of state provision for those apparently excluded from the remit of free-market, new forms of government intervention are emerging. Many sectors are increasingly split between private services for the well-off, and cheap, mass role-out of government services for the poor. This is represented in health care, for example, by the split between private and primary health care. Outsourcing to the private sector is another widespread strategy employed by the government to reduce the public costs of service delivery. The movement towards micro finance, which has received considerable impetus in recent years, represents a further reinforcement of this trend, with the state offering an alternative to those whom the mainstream financial sector has been unable or The setting Makhathini is an area of around 13,000 hectares spread over the low-lying areas east of the southern Lebombo mountain range in northern KwaZuluNatal. An important region for agriculture, particularly for cotton but also for a variety of food crops, Makhathini has been the site of ongoing interventions under successive colonial and apartheid governments since 1903. One long-lasting development was the formation of the Makhathini Irrigation Scheme in 1982, served by the large Jozini Dam. Today, the scheme occupies an area of 1 unwilling to assist. This is conceptualised by its proponents as a strategy to aid and formalise what former president Thabo Mbeki coined ‘the second economy’. in an account held at ABSA, a large commercial bank with a branch in the nearby town of Jozini. The process took over three years to finally reach the point of official accreditation. On 4th May 2010, the certificate was formally handed to the chairperson of the newly formed community bank. The bank currently has about 1,150 members, both men and women, the majority of whom engage in some kind of farming, from subsistence to smallscale commercial production, alongside a range of other income generating activities. Others members are small business owners, such as vendors, tailors or hairdressers. Several programmes and organisations set up recently indicate a coherent strategy to meet this aim. The South African Micro-Finance Apex Fund (SAMAF) was founded in April 2002, a branch of the Department of Trade and Industry. Its goal is to ‘facilitate the provision of affordable access to finance by micro, small and survivalist business for the purpose of growing their own income and asset base’, which aims to be carried out via a ‘network of self-sufficient and sustainable micro-finance institutions’.1 One such ‘financial intermediary’ is Simunye bank in Makhathini. SAMAF has promised a loan to Simunye on the condition that the bank is seen to be in full operation. This will be determined by whether the bank has sufficient inflow and outflow to be deemed an active and functioning financial institution. Should Simunye collapse, the money members invested will be returned to them (with the exception of the initial R100 required for setting up the bank). Simunye Bank Simunye (‘we are one’) was founded by a small group of cotton farmers working in the Makhathini area of the Umkhanyakude district of northern KwaZulu-Natal. After several years of failed attempts at securing bank loans and government grants, and with the advice of a government representative, these farmers finally decided to set up their own financial institution. The chairperson of Simunye explained their motivations: A representative of SAMAF told members during a meeting in April 2010: If you invest in the bank monthly, then you will be in a favourable position to receive funding. If you are able to invest monthly, these records will be kept about you as a further indication that you are a person who is able to refund, that you are reliable… The government is here to help you, but it won’t help if there is no progress being witnessed.2 We realised that when we went to institutions to borrow money, we had problems. They used to ask for assets: “Do you have an asset? Do you own a house?” So that before they give you money you’ve got to qualify. So it was so hard for us. That is why we decided to see if we can make ourselves a banking institution. SAMAF advised that they must raise an initial 100,000 rand in order to qualify for the status of an ‘intermediary institution’ that would be eligible for funds. The group of farmers agreed to raise this 100,000 rand by recruiting new members and charging a 100 rand joining fee. They advertised the bank on a local radio station, Maputaland Radio, and quickly raised the necessary funds, storing these This statement implied that on the basis of the bank’s records, a person’s ‘reliability’ and ability to deal responsibly with money would be judged; and loans allocated accordingly. During a research interview, a board member expressed to me this notion of individual responsibility in terms of ‘commitment’ to the bank: ‘Members must start to save in order for us to see how many are committed to the bank. We won’t give money to those who aren’t committed’. This paper will show that, in addition to personal factors, individual 1 2 See the website: www.SAMAF.org.za 2 This is an approximate translation from Zulu. ‘commitment’ to the bank may also have to do with wider structural conditions to which people are bound to varying degrees. Case 1: Mr Nyawo3 Mr Nyawo has been renting a ten hectare plot inside the Makhathini Irrigation Scheme since the early 1990s. Currently, he is only farming six of these ten hectares because he lacks capital to plant the others. He also needs to replant the sugarcane he is growing because it is old and poor quality. The revenue he receives from selling his sugar cane to a nearby factory is depleted by ongoing debt repayments. He complained, therefore, that he is unable to be fully productive and to make progress. He has so far invested 50 rand in Simunye in addition to the initial 100 rand joining fee, and intends to continue investing each month. He explains: ‘I hope to invest in the bank every month, because I want to see my involvement pay off, to see whether it will provide. I won’t leave it half way as others have done… because this is our final option for obtaining credit.’ From conversations with individual members, it became apparent that a person’s intention to invest money in the bank depended upon two factors. The first was the perceived degree of risk entailed in investing in the bank. This had to do with the stability or vulnerability of individual livelihoods. The second factor was the expectations, positive or negative, about Simunye Bank itself. While I deal with these separately for now, it will become apparent that they are interdependent. Risk A SAMAF newsletter of April 2010 (Vol. 6) celebrates the ‘success story’ of one beneficiary. With the financial assistance of a SAMAF funded financial intermediary, Mrs Mushope of Thohoyandou transformed her struggling efforts to generate income from making Venda traditional clothes into a thriving business employing 4 people. Subsequently, she was able to extend her house and to send her children to tertiary education. Mrs Mushope represents the model ‘entrepreneur’ – what SAMAF literature refers to as the ‘enterprising poor’ – by earning a living from a single, successful business and investing in the future security and happiness of her immediate, nuclear family. Case 2: Jabulile Jabulile is doing a sewing course with the intention of starting a business after she completes it in December 2010. She is using the child grants she receives for her three children to cover her current expenditure and to buy the materials she needs for the course. She believes her business can be successful because in the area where she lives, there is no-one else with her skills. She will fund the startup of her business partly by selling the clothes that she has made during the sewing course. In addition, she’ll need to raise or borrow further capital, of which Simunye is one possible source. She has not re-invested in Simunye after the joining fee, because she is spending her money on the materials for the course, and it is her priority to finish this first, before thinking of the next step. Her approach to Simunye is rather ambivalent, for while she hopes it will succeed, she is not relying on it. What this paper will show in relation to Simunye Bank is that while a minority of members seem to conform quite closely to this model, others diverge considerably, both because they make use of multiple sources of income rather than aspiring towards a single business idea, and because they are involved in an extensive network of social relationships that influence financial income and spending in a manner obfuscated by the nuclear household model suggested in Mrs Mushope’s account. I begin, however, with two examples that do share similarities with Mrs Mushope’s account (see Case 1 & Case 2). Both Mr Nyawo and Jabulile encapsulate the ‘entrepreneur’ model and, like Mrs Mushope, seem to have the qualities that fit SAMAF’s notion of ‘the enterprising poor’. They are both working towards fulfilling a particular business ideal, and have the skills and the will – if not the capital – to achieve it. 3 I use pseudonyms to maintain the confidentiality of the data. 3 Like Mrs Mushope, prior to her borrowing the loan, the only serious obstacle they face is a lack of credit. In the case of Mr Nyawo, his previous experiences of indebtedness have spurred his hope in Simunye, which he sees as the ‘final option’. and regular income source such as a government grant. For her, the bank fits into this set of strategies as one of several possibilities. Her mention of the closure of the ginnery deserves brief explanation due to its impact on the unequal access to resources of farmers inside and outside the irrigation scheme. Where dry-land farmers were often compelled to continue producing cotton – due to cotton’s resilience to low rainfall – despite the increased costs incurred by the closure of the local ginnery, farmers within the scheme unanimously shifted to other types of crop production. Access to irrigated land, therefore, is a key factor in influencing the degree of vulnerability experienced by farmers and the choices available to them. For others, the picture is complicated by the fact that income is obtained from a variety of sources, as in the following example. Case 3: Mrs Dlamini Mrs Dlamini has been a cotton farmer in Makhathini since 1994. About three years ago, the cotton factory in Makhathini that had previously processed much of the cotton produced in the area was closed. Mrs Dlamini stopped farming because of the additional costs of transporting cotton for processing elsewhere. While describing herself as a cotton farmer, Mrs Dlamini currently earns most of her income from making and selling traditional straw mats called amacansi. Her son, who has a temporary job in Johannesburg, sometimes sends money and she also borrows small amounts from mashonisas (local money-lenders) when necessary. Until about three years ago, she was receiving 500 rand per month from the government for homebased care work. Since payments for this work ceased, she has continued this work voluntarily. She explains that cotton farmers are now in negotiation with the government to reopen the cotton ginnery in Makhathini, in which case she will continue farming. She explained why people needed Simunye. It is impossible to get a loan from normal banks if you do not have a job, she explained, because they ask to see your pay slip: ‘Even if I tell them I am selling these amacansi they do not believe me’. She hopes to start investing in Simunye from the money she makes from selling amacansi, but at the moment, she explains, she doesn’t have enough money to spare. Ideally, she hopes to continue all these activities, but in a way that is more financially fruitful. Case 4: Mrs Gumede Mrs Gumede has a 3 hectare plot inside the Makhathini Scheme that her niece lent to her at no cost. She is planting beans on two hectares and maize on the third. She also receives a pension from the government every month. She explained that she joined Simunye because she needs a loan to buy new irrigation facilities. She also wants to buy seeds to diversify her crops. The fact that her niece who lent her the land is also on the board of Simunye has meant that she feels able to trust it, and feels hopeful that it will succeed. She recently invested R50 in the bank from her pension money, and says she will continue to do so each month so that she will qualify for a loan. This example demonstrates the role of a stable income in the form of a government grant and the potential for personal relations to act as a kind of economic resource (Seekings & Nattrass 2005). It also supports the observation that access to land inside the Irrigation Scheme gives farmers a considerable advantage over dry-land farmers. Of the 13 members interviewed who had reinvested in the bank, 10 were farmers working within the scheme. None were dry-land farmers. The advantage experienced by farmers working within the scheme, therefore, is emerging from the investment patterns of Simunye bank. As Mrs Dlamini’s account illustrates, many South Africans draw upon multiple sources of income in order to make a living. Mrs Dlamini does not aspire towards one particular career, but minimizes risk by engaging in a variety of strategies. This is of key importance, particularly in the absence of a stable In addition to the availability of actual resources such as land is the range of existing or potential sources of income available to individuals. These 4 resources include a variety of income generating activities, government grants, as well as relationships with, for example, family members that were employed. Thus, financial stability is not necessarily about having one successful business, but rather about reducing risk through diverse pursuits: ‘Risk explains people’s concern to establish and maintain a rural base, to disperse their households and to diversify their sources of livelihood’ (Francis 2000: 52). It may be that Simunye loans will feed into these multiple strategies, rather than into a single business. A final example demonstrates the frustrations felt by a farmer who is struggling to make a living farming outside of the scheme (see Case 5). Mandla’s story highlights the potential challenges of a performance-based loaning system, which runs the risk of excluding the poorest members. Case 5: Mandla Mandla began farming a year ago, because he was unable to find any other kind of job. He managed to acquire the land by collaborating with several others who were in a similar situation. They all share the same area of land, each with a separate plots. Mandla sells his produce locally at a roadside or by going from house to house. He has funded his farming by borrowing from a mashonisa which charges high rates of interest (40 rand a month for every 100 rand borrowed). As a result it has been difficult to get any returns from farming yet. He describes his farming as only just surviving financially, and he sometimes has to ask his neighbours for seeds when he cannot afford them. He supplements his income by collecting old iron and other pieces of metal and takes them to the scrap yard, where he is paid for each piece according to its weight. Mandla joined Simunye because he wanted to receive a loan in order to buy good quality seeds – ‘professional seeds’ as he called them – that would prevent crops from rotting or being eaten by insects.4 When we spoke in May, he had become very disillusioned with the board members of the bank, accusing them of failing to take into account his situation. How could he pay 50 rand a month, he complained, when all of his money had to go to his children, back into farming or returned to the mashonisa? During a meeting he accused the board indignantly of leading him to the false belief that his initial payment of 100 rand would render him eligible for a loan. He later raised his suspicions about the SAMAF representative: ‘He’s only helping the bank, by borrowing money from other banks and people, but he’s not helping the people who started it.’ Mandla’s negative attitude about Simunye is unrepresentative of members in general. Most were more hesitant in making any judgements of this kind and, instead, expressed cautious hope and sometimes optimism. Yet it does raise an interesting question about to what extent expectations about the bank’s success were related to the degree of personal economic vulnerability. Expectation The second factor that influenced a person’s intention to invest money in Simunye was the degree of willingness to invest trust in the processes of standardisation. The lack of choice available to Mandla has enhanced his suspicion of the bank and those perceived to control it. Another woman, living off a pension and subsistence farming, said that she no longer trusts those in charge of Simunye bank: ‘They are telling us they won’t help anyone who doesn’t invest this 50 rand each month. If I were working I could pay it, but I’m not… They are not trustworthy’. Like for Mandla, the perceived untrustworthiness of the bank and this respondent’s own limited resources went hand in hand. Those responsible for organising and running the bank engaged in efforts to gain legitimacy for Simunye, such as calling a meeting to celebrate the formal receipt of a certificate of accreditation from SAMAF. In doing this, they were making a claim to the bank’s formal status. Yet this process of formalisation was under threat from several angles, the most obvious being accusations of corruption. Another source of threat was a view of the bank as parochial and unsophisticated in relation to the high-street commercial banks. Complaints 4 Genetically-modified seeds are used widely in the Makhathini area. They are also partly responsible for the different standards of produce, and the competitive disadvantage experienced by very small-scale farmers such as Mandla. 5 proliferated, for example, about the office being ‘in the forest’, away from the convenient location of town. When asked whether they would begin to invest the R50 a month that had been agreed upon in the April meeting, many said they would do so when the bank becomes more established, better functioning, or more conveniently located in town. Criticisms that were centred on this and corruption allegations indicated the fear held by members of reverting to the messy, uncertain and uncertified realm of the informal. These tensions have to do with efforts at stabilising the ‘domains of cognitive classifications’ that are vital for an institution’s success (Guyer 2004: 127). Conclusion As Case 5 shows, trust in the bank may also have to do with one’s personal circumstances. Mandla’s mistrust was enhanced by his sense of being economically and spatially peripheral. In Case 1, personal circumstances – this time of an historical dimension – gave impetus behind Mr Nyawo’s support of Simunye. His story locates Simunye as the most recent intervention in a long trajectory of cycles of loaning and indebtedness that has characterised the institutional landscape of Makhathini. Unlike for Jabulile (Case 2), whose early career situation gives her a feeling of a wide array of possibilities, Mr Nyawo invests – financially and emotionally – in Simunye because he believes it will be his last opportunity to access much needed credit. Second, despite the individualising discourses evident in some rhetoric around the idea of ‘entrepreneurship’, wide structural and historical factors play a role in determining the likelihood of individuals to invest in Simunye. The most apparent of these is the dynamics of farming in Makhathini, and the advantage that scheme farmers have over dry-land farmers. This is a distinction which is evident in the investment patterns of the bank, and raises the question of in what ways Simunye – when it begins to deliver loans – will interact with existing power relations characterising this local economy. A number of strands can be drawn together in conclusion. Firstly, given the multiple strategies in which people engage in order to survive, the majority strive towards successfully negotiating a number of income sources; continuing as many different pursuits as successfully as possible. This is, for many, the most effective way of reducing risk. Farming, in particular, rarely serves exclusively as a means of livelihood, even for those working within the scheme. It remains to be seen how Simunye loans will fit alongside these strategies. Third, the variety, flexibility and regularity of an individual’s income sources – and hence the degree of financial risk they experience – influences the way that they conceptualise the bank and formulate judgements about its possible future success. In the case of Mandla, it is apparent that a generalised sense of exclusion both from local resources and from the formal economy enhances his sense of mistrust in the bank and the perceived threat of corrupt benefactors. A feeling of economic marginalisation is often mirrored by a sense of the bank as peripheral to the formal sphere. Thus, the bank’s struggle to gain legitimacy as a formal institution reflects the vulnerability felt by its members and vice versa. Knowledge of this local history may serve as a warning to new attempts at intervention, particularly given a national context in which it is increasingly difficult to make a viable living from small-holder farming (James 2007). Mrs Dlamini’s story (Case 3) shows that the effectiveness of a possible Simunye loan will depend on a wider set of institutional arrangements and government interventions. It seems unlikely that, even with credit, Mrs Dlamini could continue with cotton farming unless the government reopens the nearby ginnery. For her, expectations about Simunye are intertwined with a wider set of institutional developments as well as personal livelihood strategies. References - Day, C., F. Monticelli, P. Barron, R. Haynes, J. Smith & E. Sello. 2010. District Health Barometer 2008/09. Health Systems Trust. 6 See: http://www.hst.org.za/publications/864. - Francis, E. 2000. Making a Living: Changing Livelihoods in Rural Africa. London: Routledge. - Guyer, J.I. 2004. Marginal Gains: Monetary Transactions in Atlantic Africa. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. - James, D. 2007. Gaining Ground? ‘Rights’ and ‘Property’ in South African Land Reform. Oxon: Routledge-Cavendish. - Porteous, D. & E. Hazelhurst. 2004. Banking on Change: Democratising Finance in South Africa, 1994-2004 and beyond. Cape Town: Double Story. - Seekings, J. & N. Nattrass. 2005. Class, Race, and Inequality in South Africa. New Haven and London: Yale University Press. 7