BEFORE THE Federal Communications Commission WASHINGTON, D.C. In the Matter of ) ) Access Charge Reform ) ) Price Cap Performance Review ) for Local Exchange Carriers ) ) Transport Rate Structure ) and Pricing ) ) Usage of the Public Switched ) Network by Information Service) and Internet Access Providers ) CC Docket No. 96-262 CC Docket No. 94-1 CC Docket No. 91-213 CC Docket No. 96-263 REPLY COMMENTS OF TIME WARNER COMMUNICATIONS HOLDINGS, INC. Brian Conboy Michael Jones Thomas Jones WILLKIE FARR & GALLAGHER Three Lafayette Centre 1155 21st Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20036 (202) 328-8000 ATTORNEYS FOR TIME WARNER COMMUNICATIONS HOLDINGS, INC. February 14, 1997 TABLE OF CONTENTS Page I. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY...................................1 II. THE MARKET-BASED APPROACH TO ACCESS CHARGE REFORM MUST NOT HARM THE DEVELOPMENT OF LOCAL ACCESS COMPETITION ..............AND MUST ENSURE THAT ACCESS CUSTOMERS AND CONSUMERS ARE BENEFITED..............................................3 A. The Availability Of Unbundled Elements Does Not Flexibility................................................5 B. Granting ILECs Pricing Flexibility In The Absence Remove The Incentive Necessary For ILEC Cooperation In The Removal Of The Local Bottleneck.....................9 C. Modifying The Price Cap Rules For Switched Access Promote The ILECs' Ability To Cross-Subsidize And Engage In Strategic Pricing...............................10 D. USTA's Suggestion That The Commission's Treatment Flexibility Prior To Assessing The Status Of Competition Is Incorrect..................................12 E. The Commission Should Reject Forbearance Proposals Services..................................................14 Provi Of Su Servi Of AT For S III. AMERITECH'S LOOP PORT RECOVERY CHARGE IS AN UNREASONABLE AND ANTICOMPETITIVE PROPOSAL..............................16 IV. THE ILEC "MAKE-WHOLE" PROPOSALS FOR "HISTORIC COST" RECOVERY ARE NOT SUSTAINABLE..............................17 A. The ILECs Are Not Owed Recovery Of Costs Of B. The ILEC Depreciation Reserve Deficiency Is C. Unidentified TIC Costs Must Be Allocated On A D. The Commission Should Correct For Any Regul Suspe Propo Separations Reform........................................22 E. The Proposals Before The Commission Do Not V. Impli THE COMMISSION SHOULD ALIGN COST RECOVERY WITH COST CAUSATION.................................................24 A. Tandem-Switched Transport Competition Will Not To Where Costs Are Incurred..........................25 B. The Commission Should Increase The Cap For Line Charges, Or, In The Alternative, Modify The Carrier Common Line Charge To A Flat-Rate, Per Line Charge...........................................27 VI. Juris THE COMMISSION SHOULD AVOID BURDENING NASCENT CLECS WITH TERMINATING ACCESS REGULATION........................28 VII. CONCLUSION................................................31 -ii- Devel Resid Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 BEFORE THE Federal Communications Commission WASHINGTON, D.C. In the Matter of ) ) Access Charge Reform ) ) Price Cap Performance Review ) for Local Exchange Carriers ) ) Transport Rate Structure ) and Pricing ) ) Usage of the Public Switched ) Network by Information Service) and Internet Access Providers ) CC Docket No. 96-262 CC Docket No. 94-1 CC Docket No. 91-213 CC Docket No. 96-263 REPLY COMMENTS OF TIME WARNER COMMUNICATIONS HOLDINGS, INC. Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc., ("TWComm"), by its attorneys, hereby submits its reply comments in response to the Commission's Notice of Proposed Rulemaking in the above-captioned proceeding.1 I. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY The comments filed in response to the Notice underscore the critical importance of the Commission's decision in this proceeding. Any action (or inaction) the Commission takes in this docket will result in far-reaching consequences for the telecommunications industry and for consumers. 1 TWComm is concerned that access charge See Access Charge Reform, CC Docket Nos. 96-262, 94-1, 91-213, 96-263, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, Third Report and Order, and Notice of Inquiry, FCC 96-488 (released December 24, 1996) ("Notice"). -1- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 reform is being considered primarily in light of its potential impact upon ILECs.i Undoubtedly, ILECs will experience the effects of the Commission's reforms. However, potential competitors, too, will be impacted by the Commission's decision. A failure by the Commission to promote competition and to prevent anticompetitive abuses would severely damage nascent competitive markets. Ineffective or delayed competitive entry combined with greater freedom for monopoly ILECs perversely would harm consumers under the 1996 Act. TWComm urges the Commission to consider this possibility when weighing the options for access charge reform. TWComm confines its Reply Comments to responding to issues raised by other parties. Specifically: A market-based approach to access charge reform must avoid harming the development of competition and the interests of ILEC access customers. The market approach proposed by the Notice and the ILECs fails to protect adequately against anti-competitive ILEC incentives. ILEC requests for pricing flexibility in the absence of substantial competition must be rejected. ·Ameritech's Loop/Port Recovery Charge proposal would insulate ILECs from competitive forces and would dampen the development of competition in the local and access markets. The Commission should dismiss the Ameritech proposal. Neither law nor economic theory nor sound public policy mandates the ILEC recovery of historic costs. The Commission should reject ILEC proposals for regulatory structures designed to guarantee historic cost recovery. The Commission must remove costs associated with tandem-switched transport from the TIC so that tandem-switched transport competition can develop. The Commission should avoid regulating CLEC terminating access in the absence of evidence that CLECs have actually overpriced such services. II. THE MARKET-BASED APPROACH TO ACCESS CHARGE REFORM MUST NOT HARM THE DEVELOPMENT OF LOCAL ACCESS COMPETITION AND MUST ENSURE -2- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 THAT ACCESS CUSTOMERS AND CONSUMERS ARE BENEFITED.2 TWComm supports a market-based approach to access charge reform, but not as initially proposed by the Commission,ii and not as proposed by the ILEC interests filing comments in this proceeding.3 TWComm believes that a market-based approach to access reform must condition ILEC pricing flexibility upon the presence of substantial competition in the provision of local access services; any approach that does not appropriately condition ILEC access pricing flexibility will squander the 1996 Act's promise of local telephone service competition and will pose a significant threat of harm to ratepayers.4 The market-based approach proposed by the Commission, modified as suggested by TWComm, will accomplish the objectives of the 1996 Act; the approach proposed by USTA and other ILEC interests simply will not. With certain variations on the theme, ILEC commenters generally propose that the Commission provide ILECs essentially unrestricted 2 3 4 This Section relates to Sections V.A and V.B of the Notice. See, e.g., USTA Comments at 25-35. See Appendix to TWComm Comments in which TWComm proposes a definition of the proper criteria for measuring substantial competition. TWComm recommends using the measurement criteria applied to AT&T for streamlining and pricing flexibility purposes, modified to account for the fundamental differences between AT&T and the ILECs regarding market power and bottleneck control. These criteria include an analysis of demand elasticity, supply elasticity and market share, with market share given the greatest weight. The LATA should serve as the relevant geographic market (which should include both intrastate and interstate services offered in that geographic area) and, subject to certain limitations, the existing price cap service categories could serve as the relevant product markets. The Commission must also consider the relative presence or absence of shared costs among products or geographic areas when the ILEC provides both competitive and non-competitive services in those categories. -3- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 pricing flexibility upon a showing that a given state has approved an interconnection agreement complying with sections 251 and 252 of the Act, or that a given state has approved a Statement of Generally Available Terms ("SGAT").5 ILEC commenters also propose that the Commission revise the Part 69 price cap regulations applicable to switched access services subject to Phase I regulation to consolidate the baskets within which such services fall. Such an approach will severely undercut the goals of the 1996 Act for the following reasons: The mere theoretical availability of unbundled elements does not demonstrate that the ILEC's access service offerings are subject to substantial competition; If pricing flexibility is granted in the absence of substantial competition, ILECs will have a reduced incentive to provide the degree of cooperation necessary for the development of local access competition; Revising the Part 69 price cap regulations to consolidate the baskets and service categories for switched access services will allow ILECs to deter competitive entry through cross-subsidization and strategic pricing; and Contrary to ILEC assertions, Commission precedent does not support granting pricing flexibility in the absence of substantial competition. Finally, ILEC requests for forbearance for Special Access and Collocated Direct Trunked Transport should be rejected because competition for such services is not sufficient to warrant deregulation. Where competition does not justify such relief on a LATA-wide basis, forbearance will only enhance ILECs' ability to shift costs to consumers of less competitive services. A. The Availability Of Unbundled Elements Does Not Provide A Sufficient Basis For Granting Pricing Flexibility.6 5 6 See, e.g., Bell Atlantic and NYNEX Comments at 43; BellSouth Comments at 30; Southwestern Bell Comments at 26. This Subsection relates to Section V.B of the Notice. -4- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 ILEC commenters justify their bid for unrestrained pricing flexibility in Phase I on the grounds that having an approved interconnection agreement or SGAT for the provision of unbundled elements ensures the removal of remaining entry barriers and will constrain the ability of ILECs to raise access rates.iii This justification is without merit and the ILEC proposal should be rejected. First, the mere availability of unbundled elements does not provide a sufficient basis for finding that an ILEC has effectively removed entry barriers. The fact that an interconnection agreement has been reached with a CLEC and approved by a state PUC does not indicate that the terms of the agreement will in fact be workable and implemented, much less allow the development of robust competition. The availability of a SGAT provides even less basis for concluding that entry barriers have been removed because the SGAT cannot account for the particular needs of a specific market entrant. Moreover, because the methods by which an ILEC can inhibit the entry of local access competitors are difficult to detect, only the presence of substantial competition over time will indicate that entry barriers have been removed. Unless substantial competition is present, the Commission should have no confidence that the terms of interconnection are free of barriers to competition and market growth. As evidence of the removal of entry barriers, an interconnection agreement or SGAT is a step in the right direction and nothing more. -5- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 The availability of unbundled elements pursuant to interconnection agreements and SGATs provides no evidence of functional local access supply alternatives. An assessment of supply alternatives for local access must depend on an examination of the status of actual competitive effects, not future hopes. This is particularly crucial now, when local access competition likely will focus on a few limited services. If accepted as proof of supply alternatives, interconnection agreements or SGATs could be used to support pricing flexibility for all access services, not merely those subject to substantial competition. Finally, the notion that an interconnection agreement or SGAT provides a reasonable restraint on the ability of ILECs to raise access rates is without merit. Whether or not unbundled elements will in fact prove to be a useful access alternative is, as yet, untested.7 As a factual matter, under the Commission's rules, unbundled elements may only be used to offer access services to local telephone customers of the unbundled element purchaser. Thus, unbundled elements are only a reasonable substitute for access where the IXC also offers local telephone services to end users using unbundled elements. IXCs with no local telephone service ambitions and IXCs pursuing a facilities-based or resale local telephone entry strategy must undertake a new line of business or change their business plan in order to arbitrage access charges using unbundled elements.8 7 8 Moreover, IXCs using unbundled elements as a local See Kwoka, John E., Jr., "Statement on LEC Price Cap Reform," at 16-17 (attached to MCI Comments) ("Kwoka"). It is, of course, by no means clear that the costs of entering the local telephone market through unbundled elements will allow -6- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 telephone entry strategy cannot use such elements to internalize access for all subscribers unless they win all of their existing interexchange customers as local customers. Further, as noted above, neither interconnection agreements nor SGATs, in and of themselves, provide any evidence that all access customers have reasonably available alternatives. More importantly, the availability of unbundled elements does not indicate the types of access services which are or will be offered using those elements; for the foreseeable future, some services and customers will have competitive alternatives while others will not. In these circumstances, the "potential" for access competition embodied in an interconnection agreement or SGAT is indeed a thin reed upon which to grant ILEC pricing flexibility. access arbitrageurs to undercut ILEC access charges. If unbundled element prices prove to provide an irresistible price advantage, that merely demonstrates the need for rate restructuring and rebalancing, not the need for access charge pricing flexibility. As demonstrated in TWComm's Comments, existing ILEC price flexibility is sufficient to respond to access rates based on unbundled element prices where unbundled element prices recover the full TELRIC of the elements. See TWComm Comments at 28. -7- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. B. February 14, 1997 Granting ILECs Pricing Flexibility In The Absence Of Substantial, Facilities-Based Competition Will Remove The Incentive Necessary For ILEC Cooperation In The Removal Of The Local Bottleneck.9 ILEC commenters assert that Phase I pricing flexibilityiv should be available on a statewide (study area) basis where unbundled elements are available to competitors, whether through an approved interconnection agreement or through an approved SGAT. proposal should be rejected. This Granting ILECs unrestrained pricing flexibility before their services are subject to substantial, facilities-based competition will eliminate the incentive necessary to ensure ILEC cooperation and thereby will allow ILECs to prevent such competition from developing and maturing. The Commission cannot simply allow competition in the provision of local services, and it cannot simply require that ILECs cooperate with this process. Rather, the Commission must provide ILECs a positive incentive to fully open the local access network to competition. This is because the ILECs possess nearly absolute control over their core markets. Most importantly, the ubiquity of the public switched network and its strategic importance empower the ILECs to control the success or failure of competitive entry. As such, the standard for increased pricing flexibility must be higher than the Section 271 standard for long distance entry. Unlike with the long distance market, the ILECs have virtually 100 percent of the local exchange market and absolute control over the facilities needed by potential competitors to interconnect with the ubiquitous ILEC network. 9 This Subsection relates to Section V.B of the Notice. -8- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Indeed, the ILECs can engage in violations of the Act that are difficult to detect. ILECs have historically proven adept at cloaking discrimination in the provision of bottleneck services with colorably legitimate business practices. ILECs can obtain a significant competitive advantage simply by withdrawing full cooperation from their competitors. Moreover, the Commission's Chief Economist has stated that "[t]hese problems are hard to regulate away, because the withdrawal of cooperation from rivals may be subtle, shifting, and temporary, but yet have real and permanent effects. . . ."10 For these reasons, it is crucial that ILECs be given every incentive to provide full cooperation. C. Modifying The Price Cap Rules For Switched Access Services Subject To Phase I Regulation Will Only Promote The ILECs' Ability To Cross-Subsidize And Engage In Strategic Pricing.11 Several ILEC commenters urge the Commission to revise the price cap rules for services subject to Phase I regulation.v Typically, these commenters propose that the Commission "simplify" the price cap scheme to consolidate baskets and service categories.12 For example, USTA favors consolidating the following service categories into a single "Network Services" basket: Tandem Switching and Transport, Local Switching, Database Services, and Common Line.13 10 11 12 13 Farrell, Joseph, "Creating Local Competition," 49 Federal Communications Law Journal 201, 207 (1996). This Subsection relates to Section V.B of the Notice. See USTA Comments at 27-28, 50-54; BellSouth Comments at 31-32; Bell Atlantic and NYNEX Comments at 45-46. See USTA Comments at 50. -9- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 These proposals will serve only to facilitate the ILECs' ability to subsidize services subject to competition with rates from less competitive services, thereby frustrating the purpose of the price cap system. Indeed, the Commission has tried to guard against this problem in the past by grouping services subject to similar levels of competition in the same basket.14 Even this process is imperfect, and ILECs currently possess the ability to cross-subsidize within baskets, limited only by the upper pricing bands. The ILEC price cap consolidation proposal is particularly troubling when combined with Phase I pricing flexibility. ILECs will be able to strategically offer contract-based, volume or term discounts for services subject to a competitive entry threat and recover some or all of the revenue shortfall with rates for less competitive services.15 Thus, consolidating services and baskets will allow ILECs to impose static efficiency losses on consumers paying higher rates and dynamic efficiency losses on all customers by deterring competitive entry. Thus, revising the Commission's price cap rules would weaken an already imperfect protection against cross-subsidization. D. USTA's Suggestion That The Commission's Treatment Of AT&T Supports The Application Of Pricing Flexibility Prior To Assessing The Status Of Competition Is Incorrect.16 14 15 16 See Notice at ¶ 216. This does not necessarily imply that rate increases would be solely relied upon. Rather, ILECs could flow all productivity gains into rate reductions for competitive services and areas, while leaving consumers in non-competitive areas without the benefit of overall cost reductions. By contrast, all new entrant services are highly competitive. New entrants cannot maintain monopoly rate levels on any of their services. This Subsection relates to Section V.B and V.C of the Notice. -10- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 USTA argues that ILECs should be allowed to offer volume and term discounts, provide service under contract tariffs and issue individual responses to RFPs in Phase I based in part on the assertion that "[t]he Commission adopted analogous regulatory reforms for AT&T prior to any determination regarding the status of competition in AT&T's markets."vi While USTA offers no citation for this proposition, an examination of the Commission's decision granting AT&T the authority to offer service under contract-based tariffs17 and other applicable precedent does not comport with USTA's assertion. 17 See Competition in the Interstate Interexchange Marketplace, CC Docket No. 90-132, Report and Order, 6 FCC Rcd 5880 (1991). -11- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Before granting AT&T contract tariff authority, the Commission made a careful examination of AT&T's competitive situation. First, the Commission found that demand for business services was highly elastic.18 Second, based on a review of analyses of traffic volumes and supply capacity, the Commission concluded that supply elasticities in the interstate interexchange market were high.19 Third, the Commission found that AT&T had never exceeded the price cap ceiling for the relevant basket and had a market share in business services of approximately fifty percent.20 The Commission noted that, combined with the high demand and supply elasticities of the market, a fifty percent market share was indicative of a highly competitive market.21 As noted in TWComm's initial comments in this proceeding, Commission precedent firmly establishes that some showing of actual competition beyond mere entry is required before the Commission will grant pricing flexibility.22 18 See id. 19 See id. 20 See id. 21 See id. at at at at 22 See TWComm ¶¶ 37, 40. ¶ 46. ¶¶ 49-50. ¶ 51. Comments at 35, n.70. -12- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Moreover, even if the Commission had not premised AT&T's contract tariff authority on a showing of competition, such a result would not support similar treatment of the ILECs. This is because the ILECs and post-divestiture AT&T simply are not similarly situated. facilities. Most significantly, ILECs possess control of bottleneck While the bottleneck is no longer legally protected, it is likely to persist in many areas for the foreseeable future and may persist indefinitely in many others.23 Thus, an analysis of the ILECs' competitive situation is necessary and proper before granting relief similar to that granted AT&T. E. The Commission Should Reject Forbearance Proposals For Special Access And Direct Trunked Transport Services.24 USTA and Southwestern Bell request that the Commission forbear from further regulation of Special Access and Collocated Direct Trunked Transport ("DTT") based on the assertion that competition exists for such services in certain high volume markets with high access line density.vii Characterizing competition for Special Access as widespread, USTA seeks forbearance for all ILECs (presumably in all markets) rather than proceeding under individual petitions for forbearance.25 The Commission should decline this request and continue to grant flexibility only where ILECs individually demonstrate the presence of substantial competition. 23 24 25 See Kwoka at 17. This Subsection relates to Section III.D and V.B of the Notice. USTA Comments at 46. -13- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Forbearance from regulation of Special Access and DTT should not be adopted by the Commission. First, competition for these services is not sufficient to warrant deregulation. At best, the data cited by USTA may demonstrate that Special Access services are competitive in certain geographic markets. The Commission has already granted appropriate pricing flexibility where ILECs have demonstrated that such services are subject to competition. On a going forward basis, the Commission should grant regulatory relief for Special Access and DTT where an ILEC demonstrates it is subject to substantial competition for such services, as described in the Appendix to TWComm's Comments.26 Relaxing regulation on a market-by-market basis will reduce the ILECs' ability to use pricing flexibility as a means of deterring competitive entry. Such an approach also will limit the extent to which ILECs can fund their responses to competition with Switched Access revenues. It is particularly important to safeguard against such cross-subsidization because Special Access and DTT are usually provisioned by ILECs using the same facilities as Switched Access. The common use of infrastructure by services subject to differing levels of competition provides a substantial opportunity for cost shifting. Forbearance would fail to provide any check on an ILEC's incentive or ability to cross-subsidize and, for this reason, the Commission should decline to adopt such proposals. III. AMERITECH'S LOOP PORT RECOVERY CHARGE IS AN UNREASONABLE AND ANTICOMPETITIVE PROPOSAL.27 26 See Appendix to TWComm Comments. 27 This Section relates to Section III and Section V of the Notice. -14- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Ameritech has proposed that the Commission establish what it refers to as the "loop/port recovery" or "LPR" charge.viii This charge would recover the costs allocated to the interstate rate base of the ILECs' loops and associated switching ports that are not recovered from the SLC.28 Ameritech proposes that this charge should be transitioned from price caps to actual costs and should be recovered from interstate carriers on a "competitively neutral basis."29 As the Commission no doubt recognizes, this is a totally unreasonable proposal. Indeed, the notion that a tax should be imposed on interstate carriers (including those not utilizing ILEC exchange access) to pay for ILEC interstate loop costs not covered by the SLC is nothing short of astonishing. On a general level, the LPR would effectively ensure the survival of the local loop bottleneck by eliminating opportunities for low cost new entrants to compete in the provision of local loops. More specifically, the LPR is essentially a universal service mechanism for the ILECs only, and therefore violates Section 214(e).30 Finally, the proposal to transition the LPR out of price caps so that the ILECs can recover actual loop and loop port costs also revives in full force the inefficiencies of rate of return regulation just at the time when Ameritech and other BOCs are attempting to enter the long distance business (and other price cap LECs are already in the long distance business) and other competitive businesses. 28 29 30 See id. Id. See 47 U.S.C. § 214(e)(any eligible common carrier -15- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. IV. February 14, 1997 THE ILEC "MAKE-WHOLE" PROPOSALS FOR "HISTORIC COST" RECOVERY ARE NOT SUSTAINABLE.31 TWComm has reservations about the purported existence and size of unrecovered historic costs in ILEC networks. Nonetheless, a definitive resolution of this issue is unnecessary. Even assuming that unrecovered ILEC historic costs remain, neither law nor policy compels the imposition of costs upon ratepayers and competitors to recover them. USTA and the ILECs identify four areas in which historic costs allegedly have not been recovered: (1) the costs of regulation; (2) under-depreciation of plant; (3) the TIC component costs; and (4) costs overallocated to the interstate jurisdiction by the Commission's separations rules.ix As explained below, the ILECs exaggerate the levels of unrecovered historic costs. Moreover, they attempt to broaden the legal standard for regulatory confiscation as a way to persuade the Commission to mandate recovery. "shall . . . receive universal service support")(emphasis added). 31 This Section relates to Section VII.B of the Notice. -16- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Economics attaches no inherent value to historic cost recovery in a non-regulated environment: inefficient. it is neither efficient nor In this sense, the decision of a firm to recover its historic costs or to write them off its books is best left to the judgment of the individual firm. An economic value does attach, however, when historic cost recovery becomes a mandatory regulatory feature. To the extent that historic costs would not be recovered in a competitive market, the mandatory recovery of historic costs skews competition and requires ratepayers to pay more to allow an incumbent firm's historic cost recovery. Whether these consequences merit the cost recovery feature is a matter of regulatory policy; neither law nor economic theory mandate recovery.32 A. The ILECs Are Not Owed Recovery Of Costs Of Regulation.33 32 It is self-evident that those historic costs resulting from ILEC inefficiency have no place in a discussion of regulatory recovery mechanisms. The recovery of inefficient ILEC expenditures is wholly the responsibility of ILEC shareholders. See, e.g., American Tel. and Tel. Co., Docket No. 19129, (Phase II), Phase II Final Decision and Order, 64 FCC2d 1, 49 at ¶ 118 (1977)("[E]xcessive investment is properly the responsibility and burden of the investor."); see also, 47 C.F.R. § 65.800 (indicating that the rate base shall include plant investments "used and useful in the efficient provision of interstate telecommunications services")(emphasis added). 33 This Subsection relates to Section VII.B of the Notice. -17- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 The ILEC position considers the historic costs of regulation but fails to consider its attending enrichments. The Sidak and Spulber Affidavit attached to the USTA Comments discusses at length the "regulatory contract" and the "substantial capital expenditures" ILECs were required to incur as part of their obligation to serve.x Yet, it tells only half the story. The analysis neglects to recognize the profits, for both regulated and non-regulated services, earned as a result of these "substantial capital expenditures." Many ILEC vertical service offerings, the profitability of which have been heralded by the financial press,34 are dependent upon the results of these capital expenditures. Combined with the "fair" rates of return allowed the ILECs for regulated use of the network (not to mention their substantial market shares), these profits represent historical financial advantages, not disadvantages, from the "regulatory contract."35 Ratepayers need not be compelled to contribute any further to this false public debt.36 34 35 36 See Gautum Naik, "Telecommunications: Baby Bells Profit by Tapping Phone Paranoia," Wall St. J., Sept. 3, 1996 at B1 (indicating that "the Bells and GTE Corp. rake in more than $4 billion a year on these new [vertical] services, and the take is growing" and that "the profit margins of 70% or more far exceed the less-than-10% profit that regional carriers typically get on basic phone service"); see also, Leslie Cauley, "Four Baby Bells Report Healthy Results," Wall St. J., Oct. 18, 1996 at B3 ("Four Baby Bells reported healthy profits for the third quarter, buoyed by strong consumer demand for second phone lines, enhanced services such as "Caller ID" and cellular fare")(emphasis added). Moreover, if AT&T offers any example of post-monopoly expectations, the historical ILEC advantages will increase as a result of the market paradigm shift generated by the 1996 Act (insofar as ILECs abandon the erroneous notion that they are guaranteed specific rates of return on their operations). Moreover, the conversion to price cap regulation in recent years was an implementation of ILEC requests to separate costs from -18- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. B. February 14, 1997 The ILEC Depreciation Reserve Deficiency Is Suspect.37 It is highly unlikely that ILECs retain legitimate interstate depreciation reserve deficiencies. Richard Lee's analysis demonstrates that ILECs may have a depreciation surplus rather than a depreciation deficiency.xi The analysis demonstrates that the replacement cost of outside plant accounts is greater than the current net book value of such plant (although the opposite may be true for ILEC switches).38 Because ILEC investment in outside plant is double that of its investment in switches, an ILEC's total plant replacement costs should be greater than its current net book value of the plant.39 As the analysis states, "[t]his would indicate a depreciation reserve surplus, not deficiency. . . ."40 Moreover, market values of the RHCs are greater than their book values, indicating the absence of a significant depreciation reserve.41 To understate the issue, the ILECs exaggerate the levels, if not the existence, of their interstate depreciation reserve deficiencies. C. Unidentified TIC Costs Must Be Allocated On A Proportionate Basis.42 37 38 39 40 41 42 rate levels to encourage efficiency. Their requests in this proceeding to reverse course and base rate levels upon underlying costs is inconsistent and would reinstitute the recovery methods (and attending inefficient incentives) of rate-of-return regulation. This Subsection relates to Section VII.B. of the Notice. See id. at 12. See id. Id. See id. This Subsection relates to Section III.E and Section VII.B of the Notice. -19- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 The Commission need not and should not abandon its preference for cost-based pricing when dismantling the Transport Interconnection Charge. The ILEC comments identify many of the cost components of the TIC.xii Where identifiable, TIC components should be assigned to the appropriate cost-causative interstate switched access elements. Those remaining TIC components which ILECs claim result from overallocation of costs to the interstate jurisdiction should be addressed through the Commission's upcoming separations reform proceeding. Any remaining costs not identified should be phased out over a three- to five-year period. Under no circumstances should ILECs be permitted to recover residual TIC components from the universal service fund. As TWComm indicated in its comments, to the extent that rates fail to recover the forward-looking costs of loop provisioning, the Joint Board's Recommended Decision allows for the proxy model to assess the appropriate reimbursement.43 TIC cost recovery from universal service would allow an unreasonable double recovery of costs. 43 Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Recommended Decision, FCC 96J-3 at ¶ 270 (released Nov. 8, 1996)("We find that forward-looking economic costs should be used to determine the cost of providing universal service."). -20- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Finally, the Commission must dismiss the unreasonable ILEC suggestion that a separate recovery mechanism, such as bulk billing, be established to preserve ILEC revenue requirements previously recovered through the TIC.44 Competition allows the generation of revenues; it does not require it. from this paradigm. The ILECs are no longer exempt Accordingly, the Commission should dismiss ILEC revenue requirement recovery proposals, which would reinstate the largely discredited rate base, rate-of-return regulatory structure and its attending harmful incentives. D. The Commission Should Correct For Any Jurisdictional Cost Misallocation Through Separations Reform.45 With respect to the ILECs' stated need for separations reform, TWComm agrees: critical.xiii reform of the jurisdictional separations regime is However, as a practical matter, access charge reform does not comprehend an immediate need for separations reform. No flash-cut dislocation of ILEC revenue streams will occur upon release of the Commission's order in this docket.46 Rather, under TWComm's proposal, the development of downward pressure on interstate access prices will occur gradually. The Commission has ample time to engage in a considered approach to jurisdictional separations reform. E. The Proposals Before The Commission Do Not Implicate Regulatory Confiscation.47 44 45 46 47 See, e.g., Southwestern Bell Telephone Company Comments at 9 (advocating the implementation of a new "Public Policy" charge to recover, among other items, costs embedded in the TIC). This Subsection relates to Section VII.B of the Notice. Only transport elements are subject to any competitive pressures currently. Any such pressure on remaining access revenue will result from competition for local exchange dialtone services, which will occur gradually over time. This Subsection relates to Section VII.B. of the Notice. -21- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 TWComm's proposals herein are not confiscatory. They permit ILECs the opportunity to recover historic costs but, as in any competitive market, they do not guarantee the ability to do so. The ILECs will not find themselves unable to attract capital for future investments, as evidenced by the reports of Merrill Lynch and other Wall Street analysts.xiv To the contrary, Wall Street seems bullish on ILECs, despite full anticipation of the potential effects of access charge reform.48 Hence, TWComm's proposal does not constitute confiscation, as judicially defined.49 The ILECs, on the other hand, advocate broadening the standard for confiscation. They contend that unless a regulated carrier is guaranteed perpetually the recovery of a profitable return on all ventures (past, present, and future), a taking has occurred.50 Ratepayers should not be financially burdened, nor should the development of competitive markets be impaired, to realize this unreasonable proposition. The proposals before the Commission do not threaten confiscation, as discussed at length in TWComm's initial comments,51 and ILEC assertions to the contrary are baseless. 48 49 50 See MCI Comments at 3 (stating that "financial analysts are anticipating access charge reductions" and citing to Wall Street analyses of anticipated BOC earnings in light of access charge reform). See, e.g., FPC v. Hope Natural Gas Co., 320 U.S. 591, 605 (1944)(rate regulation provides adequate compensation if it "enable[s] [a] company to operate successfully, to maintain its financial integrity, to attract capital, and to compensate its investors for the risk assumed."); see also, Duquesne Light Co. v. Barasch, 488 U.S. 299, 310 (1989)(holding that a taking had not occurred because the state law did not jeopardize the ability of the regulated firms to attract capital and compensate investors). See, e.g., PacTel at 44-46; Bell Atlantic and NYNEX Comments -22- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. V. February 14, 1997 THE COMMISSION SHOULD ALIGN COST RECOVERY WITH COST CAUSATION.52 The Commission's interstate access rate structure impedes the development of exchange access competition insofar as, in many cases, it does not permit recovery of costs from cost causers. The rate structure skews the price signals guiding new entrant investment decisions. The Commission should align cost recovery with cost causation. Restructuring would permit the development of competition which would improve the dynamic efficiencies of the market and ultimately result in reduced prices for end users. A. Tandem-Switched Transport Competition Will Not Develop Until The Commission Moves Cost Recovery To Where Costs Are Incurred.xv In its comments, the Competitive Telecommunications Association ("CompTel") notes the absence of competition in the provision of tandem-switched transport and that such competition is unlikely to develop in the foreseeable future.53 Its proposed solution to this situation is the imposition of prescriptive regulatory action.54 CompTel correctly identifies current market conditions for tandem-switched transport but misapprehends the cause of the condition and, therefore, suggests an inappropriate solution. 51 52 53 54 at 16-19. See TWComm Comments at 46-47. This Section relates to Section III of the Notice. See CompTel Comments at 15 ("[N]o carrier provides competitive tandem switching or tandem-switched transport, and effective competition is not likely to develop in this market segment in the foreseeable future."). See id. -23- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 TWComm agrees that tandem-switched transport is not provided competitively. The reason for the current absence of competition lies in the fact that a portion of tandem-switched transport costs are recovered through the TIC.55 Under the interim local transport structure, purchasers of dedicated transport and CAP transport essentially subsidize prices for purchasers of tandem-switched transport through TIC payments assessed in conjunction with end office switching.56 The below-cost tandem-switched transport pricing by ILECs, made possible by the TIC, precludes efficient entry into that market. The solution does not necessitate prescriptive regulatory reform. Rather, the Commission must move access charges in a cost-causative direction. Dismantling the TIC and eliminating its subsidy will go far to correct the non-competitive tandem-switched transport market. In doing so, the Commission must ensure that costs for tandem-switched transport are recovered from purchasers of tandem-switched transport.57 Removal of these costs from the TIC will allow CAPs to serve economically the smaller IXCs relying upon tandem-switched transport for access. 55 56 57 See USTA Comments at Attachment 10 and Attachment 11 (identifying over $1 billion in costs that can be reallocated to tandem-switched transport). See First Report and Order at 7019, ¶ 25 ("In order to ease the impact of a rate structure change on small IXCs, . . . we prescribe that the tandem element initially recover only twenty percent of the current tandem revenue requirement, with the remainder of the revenue requirement recovered through the interconnection charge"). As discussed in TWComm's Comments, to the extent costs are incurred to provide tandem overflow traffic to IXCs primarily utilizing direct-trunked transport, such costs should be recovered from those IXCs through local transport rate elements, -24- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. B. February 14, 1997 The Commission Should Increase The Cap For Residential And Single-Line Business Subscriber Line Charges, Or, In The Alternative, Modify The Carrier Common Line Charge To A Flat-Rate, Per Line Charge.58 TWComm has long advocated an increase in the cap for the residential subscriber line charge ("SLC") as a necessary step toward a more economically rational access charge structure.xvi Due to universal service mandates, the current state and federal rate structures maintain artificially low residential rates against which new facilities-based entrants must compete. Recovery of non-traffic sensitive costs through traffic sensitive rates causes market distortions which create significant entry barriers for a business contemplating the placement of substantial investment in alternative telephony infrastructure in the face of artificially constrained operating margins. Since the recovery of NTS costs on a TS basis shifts cost recovery from residential lines to high-volume, long distance users (i.e., primarily business customers), competitors are given the incentive to base initial entry strategies on the business market. This only serves to delay competitive entry into the residential market and its corresponding benefits to consumers. The problem is only compounded when ILEC services are made available for resale at the steep discounts reflected in the Commission's Local Competition Order59 and in state arbitration decisions. not end office rate elements. 58 This Subsection relates to Section III.B of the Notice. 59 Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions of the Telecommunications Act of 1996, CC Docket No. 96-98, First Report and Order, 11 FCC Rcd 15499 (1996)("Local Competition Order"), review pending, sub nom., Iowa Util. Bd., et. al. v. F.C.C., No. 96-3321 (8th Cir. 1996). -25- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 To provide new entrants with the proper economic signals for entry into the residential service market, rebalancing rates for residential service toward cost is essential. In the context of the Commission's access charge reform proceeding, the most direct vehicle to shift recovery to residential services is the SLC. Unfortunately, despite ample evidence that SLC increases have no impact on universal service objectives, this solution does not appear to be acceptable at this time. As TWComm recommended in its Comments, and as supported by other parties,60 the next best alternative would be a flat, per-line recovery of current CCLC revenue from IXCs. While the charges would continue to be billed to IXCs, it would shift cost recovery away from high-volume business to the individual line where the cost is incurred. VI. THE COMMISSION SHOULD AVOID BURDENING NASCENT CLECS WITH TERMINATING ACCESS REGULATION.61 60 See, e.g., USTA Comments at 55; BellSouth Comments at 68. 61 As a policy matter, restructuring the CCL charge to align rates more closely to the manner in which the underlying costs are incurred should be non-optional. This Section relates to Section VIII.A of the Notice. -26- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 CLECs are confronted with enormous entry barriers. The 1996 Act and the Commission's Local Competition Order were designed to reduce the entry barriers imposed by the ILECs. The appeal of the Commission's Local Competition Order foreshadows the continued strong resistance of the ILECs to the reduction of local entry barriers.xvii Despite legislation and Commission orders to reduce entry barriers, their vestiges will continue for some time. In the short term, CLECs will continue to face anticompetitive challenges to local exchange market entry. In addition to the anticompetitive barriers to entry, CLECs also face the natural financial hurdles of constructing networks and attracting customers. Significant CLEC resources will be devoted to this construction, expenditures which ILECs will not be required to make. In short, CLECs must devote their resources to confronting the many challenges of local market entry. The Commission should not add to these burdens the regulation of CLEC terminating access. TWComm understands the Commission's concerns that CLECs will overcharge IXCs for terminating access and concedes that this remains a theoretical possibility. However, because no evidence suggests that CLECs will, in fact, engage in this pricing strategy, regulation is premature at this time. Not only is regulation unnecessary, it could be detrimental to the development of both local and access competition in light of the many challenges already confronting CLECs. -27- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 Several commenters have suggested that CLECs be subject to terminating access regulation only if their termination charges exceed those of the ILEC with whom they compete.62 Once again, TWComm strongly counsels the Commission to avoid placing regulatory burdens on new entrants. The ILEC-baseline approach described above would be appropriate only after actual CLEC terminating access abuses are demonstrated. TWComm suggests that this approach be considered only as a potential future approach and one which is utilized only in the event that unreasonably high CLEC terminating access is shown to be a problem. TWComm remains cautious in its acceptance of this approach due to the burdens it could place on CLECs with legitimately higher cost structures. Nevertheless, this option seems to present a reasonable compromise that satisfactorily addresses the concerns of the Commission and CLECs alike. 62 See, e.g., Ameritech Comments at 52. -28- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. February 14, 1997 VII. CONCLUSION TWComm urges the Commission to adopt revised rules for interstate access in accordance with these reply comments and its initial comments. Respectfully submitted, _________________________ Brian Conboy Michael Jones Thomas Jones WILLKIE FARR & GALLAGHER Three Lafayette Centre 1155 21st Street, N.W. Washington, D.C. 20036 (202) 328-8000 ATTORNEYS FOR TIME WARNER COMMUNICATIONS HOLDINGS, INC. February 14, 1997 The Commission should note the disastrous consequences that can attach to attempts to ignore market realities in order to retain revenue neutrality for ILECs. See Transport Rate Structure and Pricing, CC Docket No. 91-213, Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 7 FCC Rcd 7006, 7023 at ¶ 34 (1992)("First Report and Order")("the interconnection charge would be priced residually as an initial matter so as to make transport charges as a whole under the new rate structure revenue neutral")(emphasis added). The TIC resulted from these efforts and the Commission's action was deemed arbitrary and capricious by the D.C. Circuit. Competitive Telecommunications Ass'n v. F.C.C., 87 F.3d 522, 532 (D.C. Cir. 1996). ii. See Notice at ¶¶ 162-164. iii. See USTA Comments at 27. iv. ILEC commenters suggest that Phase I pricing flexibility include the ability to deaverage switched access services by geographic area and class of customer, to offer volume and term discounts, to provide services based on contract rates, and to respond to Requests For Proposals ("RFPs"). See USTA Comments at 28. v. See USTA Comments at 27-28; BellSouth Comments at 31-32; Bell Atlantic and NYNEX Comments at 45-46. i. -29- Reply Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. vi. February 14, 1997 USTA Comments at 49. USTA Comments at 42-46; Southwestern Bell Comments at 19. viii. See Ameritech Comments, Attachment A at 7. ix. See, e.g., USTA Comments at 68-79; PacTel Comments at 44-50; Southwestern Bell Comments at 40-52; Bell Atlantic and NYNEX Comments at 16-31. x. See generally, Affidavit of J. Gregory Sidak and Daniel F. Spulber, Attachment 3 to USTA Comments, at 33-62. xi. Richard B. Lee, "Analysis of Local Exchange Carrier Depreciation Reserve Levels," Appendix C to AT&T Comments ("Lee Analysis"). xii. See PacTel Comments at 71-72; BellSouth Comments at 75-78; USTA Comments at 59. xiii. The Commission indicated its intent to initiate a proceeding to reform its jurisdictional separations rules. See Notice at ¶ 6. xiv. See MCI Comments at 3-5 (noting financial analysts' positive outlook on future BOC profits). xv. This Subsection relates to Section III.D and Section III.E of the Notice. xvi. Funding Universal Service: Maximizing Penetration and Efficiency in a Competitive Local Service Environment, CC Docket No. 96-45, Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. (filed April 12, 1996); Further Comments of Time Warner Communications Holdings, Inc. (filed Aug. 2, 1996). xvii. See also, CompTel Comments at 10 ("GTE has appealed every final arbitration award issued by a state regulatory commission to date"). vii. -30-