New incentives for new agricultural technology development in Africa William A. Masters Purdue University www.agecon.purdue.edu/staff/masters www.ifpri.org/publication/accelerating-innovation-prize-rewards African Economic Conference • 13 Nov. 2009 • Addis Ababa, Ethiopia Motivation: Why might new incentives be needed? • Why not just intellectual property rights (IPRs)? – succeeds only for excludable innovations that can be sold – gains from adoption may flow to consumers and other users • Why not just grants & contracts? – succeeds only for known services that can be bought – procurement of R&D may face asymmetric information and other problems in project selection, supervision, and management • Market-like “pull” mechanisms can help – allow donors to pay for results, after achievement occurs – the most familiar ex-post payment scheme is a prize contest A typology of innovation incentives Investor: Private for-profit Public or philanthropic (to avoid need for value capture) Instrument: Direct grants & contracts Ex-post payments and prizes (to avoid need for project selection and supervision) Many private labs, or… Novartis to UC Berkeley for plant biology (‘99-03); Chocolate makers to STCP for cocoa in West Africa (2000-present) Many government labs, or… grants and contracts to public and private institutions, universities and other agencies Eli Lilly and others on Innocentive (since 2001); Procter & Gamble etc. on NineSigma (since 2000) X Prizes for space flight etc. (1996-present), AMC for new pneumococcal vaccine (launched June 2009) Philanthropic prizes have a long history (shown here: 1700-1930) Net present value of prizes paid French Academy of Sciences Montyon prizes for medical challenges (2006 US dollars, not to scale) $51,118,231 Deutsch Prize for flight between the $12,600,000 Aero-Club de France and Eiffel Tower British Longitude prize for determining longitude at sea The Daily Mail prize for flight $5,997,097 across the English Channel $3,364,544 French government prize for food preservation techniques $1,045,208 Hearst prize for crossing continental US in 30 day French government prize for large scale hydraulic turbine French government prize $421,370 for producing alkali soda $644,203 Milan Committee prize for flight across Alps $618,956 $582,689 The Daily Mail prize for transatlantic flight $515,770 $289,655 Chicago Times-Herald prize for motors for self-propelling road carriage $123,833 Scientific American prize for first plane in US to fly 1 km $56,502 Wolfskehl prize for proof of Fermat’s Last Theorem 1700 1750 1800 1850 Orteig prize for solo flight NY to Paris 1900 $31,690 1930 Philanthropic prizes have grown quickly (shown here: 1930-2009) Net present value of prizes paid (2006 US dollars, not to scale) Advance market Commitment for pneumococcal disease vaccine up to $1.5 billion Soviet Incentive Awards For Innovative Research 1930 Bigelow Space Prize for crew transport into orbit $ 50,000,000 Super Efficient Refrigerator Program for highly efficient CFC free refrigerator $165,755,396 $37,682,243 Virgin Earth Challenge for removal of greenhouse gases $ 25,000,000 European Information and Communication Technology Prize $ 10,917,192 Ansari X Prize for private manned space flight $ 10,717,703 Archon X Prize for sequencing the human genome $ 10,000,000 $7,000,000 Millennium Math Prizes for seven unsolved problems DARPA Grand Challenge for robotics in vehicles $6,660,406 $6,000,000 Lemelson-MIT Prize for invention of a patented product useful to society $4,300,000 Methuselah Mouse Prize for demonstration of slowing of ageing process on mouse NASA Centennial Challenges for Improvements in space exploration $2,000,000 $1,882,290 Schweighofer Prize for Europe’s forest industry competitiveness $1,600,000 International Computer Go Championship $1,210,084 Budweiser Challenge for first non-stop balloon flight around the globe $1,210,084 Rockefeller Foundation Prize for Rapid STD Diagnostic Test $1,210,084 Grainger Challenges for development of economical filtration devices for the removal of arsenic from well water in developing countries $588,092 Kremer Prize for Human Powered Flight Across the English Channel Kremer Prize for Human Powered Flight (Figure 8) $290,153 CATS Prize for inexpensive commercial launch of payload into space $654,545 Feynman Prizes for nano tech robot technology $250,000 $250,000 Electronic Frontier Foundation Cooperative Com$50,000-250,000 puting Challenge for new large prime numbers Beal’s $128,489 Fredkin Prize for Chess Computer Program Conjecture Prize $100,000 Loebner Prize for Computer that can pass the Turing Test $100,000 Polytechnische Gesellscaft Prize for Human Powered Flight $59,240 1940 Goldcorp Challenge for best gold prospecting methods or estimates 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Well-designed prize contests offer very powerful incentives • By “well-designed prizes”, we mean: – An achievable target, an impartial judge, credible commitment to pay • Such prizes elicit a high degree of effort: – Typically, entrants collectively invest much more than the prize payout – Sometimes, individual entrants invest more than the prize • e.g. the Ansari X Prize for civilian space travel offered to pay $10 million • the winners, Paul Allen and Burt Rutan, invested about $25 million • Why do prizes attract so much investment? – contest provides a credible signal of success – so winners can sell their product more easily • the X Prize winners licensed designs to Richard Branson for $15 million • and eventually sold the company to Northrop Grumman for $??? million • total public + private investment in prize-winning technologies ~ $1 billion …but traditional prize contests have serious limitations! • Traditional prize contests are winner-take-all (or rank-order tournaments with consolation prizes) – this is inevitable when only one (or a few) winners are needed, but... • Where multiple successes could coexist, imposing winner-take-all payoffs introduces inefficiencies – strong entrants discourage others • potentially promising candidates will not enter – pre-specified target misses other goals • more (or less) ambitious goals are not pursued – focusing on few winners misses other successes • characteristics of every successful entrant might be informative • New incentives can overcome these limitations with more market-like mechanisms, that have many winners New pull mechanisms allow for many winners • From health and education, two examples: – pilot Advance Market Commitment for pneumococcal disease vaccine • launched 12 June 2009, with up to $1.5 billion, initially $7 per dose – proposed “cash-on-delivery” (COD) payments for school completion • would offer $200 per additional student who completes end-of-school exams • What new incentive would work for agriculture? – what is the desired outcome? • unlike health, we have no silver bullets like vaccines • unlike schooling, we have no milestones like graduation • instead, we have on-going adoption of diverse innovations in local niches – what is the underlying market failure? • for AMC and COD, the main problem is making commitments • for agriculture, the main problem is learning what works, where What new incentives could best reward new agricultural technologies? • New techniques from elsewhere did not work well in Africa – local adaptation has been needed to fit diverse niches – new technologies developed in Africa are now spreading • Asymmetric information limits scale-up of successes – local innovators can see only their own results – donors and investors try to overcome the information gap with project selection, monitoring & evaluation, partnerships, impact assessments… – but outcome data are rarely independently audited or publically shared • The value created by ag. technologies is highly measureable – gains shown in controlled experiments and farm surveys – data are location-specific, could be subject to on-side audits • So donors could pay for value creation, per dollar of impact – a fixed sum, divided among winners in proportion to measured gains – like a prize contest, but all successes win a proportional payment Proportional prizes complement other types of contest design Target is pre-specified Success is ordinal (yes/no, or rank order) Success is cardinal (increments can be measured) Target is to be discovered Most technology prizes (e.g. X Prizes) Achievement awards (e.g. Nobel Prizes, etc.) AMC for medicines, COD for schooling (fixed price per unit) Proportional prizes (fixed sum divided in proportion to impact) How proportional prizes would work to accelerate innovation • Donors offer a given sum (e.g. $1 m./year), to be divided among all successful new technologies • Innovators assemble data on their technologies – controlled experiments for output/input change – adoption surveys for extent of use – input and output prices • Secretariat audits the data and computes awards • Donors disburse payments to the winning portfolio of techniques, in proportion to each one’s impact • Investors, innovators and adopters use prize information to scale up spread of winning techniques Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Data needed to compute each year’s economic gain from technology adoption Price D S S’ S” Variables and data sources J (output gain) P K ΔQ (cost reduction) Field data Yield change×adoption rate J Input change per unit I I (input change) Q Market data P,Q National ag. stats. Q’ Economic parameters K Supply elasticity (=1 to omit) ΔQ Demand elasticity (=0 to omit) Quantity Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Data needed to estimate adoption rates across years Fraction of surveyed domain First survey Other survey (if any) Projection (max. 3 yrs.) Linear interpolations First release Application date Year Implementing Proportional Prizes: Data requirements Computation of cumulative economic gains Discounted Value (US$) “Statute of limitations” (max. 5 yrs.?) First release Projection period (max. 3 yrs.?) Year NPV at application date, given fixed discount rate Implementing Proportional Prizes: An example using case study data Measured Social Gains (NPV in US$) Measured Social Gains (Pct. of total) 14,109,528 39.2% 392,087 2. Cotton in Chad 6,676,421 18.6% 185,530 3. Rice in Sierra Leone 6,564,255 18.2% 182,413 4. Rice in Guinea Bissau 4,399,644 12.2% 122,261 5. “Zai” in Burkina Faso 2,695,489 7.5% 74,904 6. Cowpea storage in Benin 1,308,558 3.6% 36,363 231,810 0.6% 6,442 $35.99 m. 100% $1 m. Example technology 1. Cotton in Senegal 7. Fish processing in Senegal Total Reward Payment (US$) Note: With payment of $1 m. for measured gains of about $36 m., the implied royalty rate is approximately 1/36 = 2.78% of measured gains. In summary… • New payment incentives can be helpful – when funders can specify outcome but not method • Proportional payments can be used… – when increments of achievement can be measured – to discover and reward all kinds of achievement • Outcome of proportional prizes would be: – a portfolio of winners, each paid its share of gains – a visible guide to what works, where and when to attract additional investors and adopters Implementing proportional prizes: What’s done, what’s next • Refinement and endorsement of the initiative – 3 journal articles, 21 presentations since 2003 – 9-member Advisory Board formed October 2004 – FARA as potential Africa secretariat since Sept. 2005 • Funding for concept development – Adelson Family Foundation, 2004-06 – International Food Policy Research Institute, 2006-08 • Funding for prize rewards – could be single or multidonor, e.g. through CAADP For more information… wmasters@purdue.edu www.agecon.purdue.edu/staff/masters www.ifpri.org/publication/accelerating-innovation-prize-rewards