Emerging Income Inequality and Widening Economic Divide: the Case of Sri Lanka Upali Vidanapathirana IDEAs Conference on Policy Perspectives on Growth, Economic Structures and Poverty Reduction:7-9, June, 2007 Tsinghua University, Beijing, China The puzzle Indicators Country category Low middle income countries Sri Lanka (2004) $ 826-3255 $1010 Life expectancy 58.1 (female) 69.8 74 Infant Mortality 79.1 24 13 Under 5 mortality 122.0 29.3 15 Adult Literacy 71.5 93.1 92 GNP per capita / Low or income countries Les than $ 825 Introduction Liberalization orthodoxy claims that ‘openness’ produces faster GDP growth rate on a sustainable basis Such growth engenders income equality Sri Lanka’s liberalization experience of about 30 years is adequate to test this claim using context specific empirical data Theoretical base of inequality and ‘openness’ Inequality in ‘open economies is explained in terms of archetypical Kuznet’ hypothesis where initial spurt in GDP growth increases inequality (Kuznet, 1955) Openness accelerates growth rate but it is distribution neutral (Kraay, 2000) HOSS theorem claims that ‘openness’ increase scope for jobs and increases real wage rates of unskilled workers to cause equality. Kuznet’s claims are not archetypical; inequality is harmful to growth (Rodrik, 1996; Thorebecke, 2002) Openness is not distribution neutral (Wood, 1999; Anderson, 2005) HOSS fails in many countries to give jobs to unskilled labour (Carter and Barham, 1996; Lipton, 1985 nd 2007) Proximate determinants of inequality 1 2 3 4 Economic growth is the most potent determinant of income distribution; its distributive implication depends on whether the growth was pro-poor or pro-rich. Growth performance of priority sectors become the second most potent determinant. It tells us where the growth occur and whether it excludes some sectors and communities. In the case of Sri Lanka the rural sector + estates house about 77 percent of the population. Employment generation is the third variable. If free trade serves unskilled labour better, naturally that should be pro-poor. The tenor of public policy is another crucial determinant; Fiscal contraction, for instance, aggravate conditions of inequality. This includes pruning financial flows to social welfare, physical and institutional infrastructure, and human development. 5 5 6 Arising from 4 above, the status of infrastructure including roads, markets, storage, irrigation canals, extension services etc undermines the distribution of economic opportunities. Education is considered an equalizer of income distribution; This depends on considerations of access and equity. So does health! Why reforms in Sri Lanka in 1977? Reforms in SL was conveniently referred to as ‘crisis driven’ although in practice it was more of ‘crisis creating’ (The reasons for reforms in Sri Lanka in 1977 much before its SA counterparts include ostensibly to address problems of low GDP growth, unemployment, poverty and inequality and also to correct problems arising from worsening economic fundamentals). But in reality it was a political project of a rightist government! Has reforms in Sri Lanka result in crisis? Many see a link between reforms and crisis in Sri Lanka(Lakshman, 1996; GOSL, 1990; Jayasuriya, 2004). Objectives of the paper To evaluate the Sri Lankan case of economic reforms (1977-2006) to ascertain whether the reforms have produced desirable outcomes in terms of equity and inclusiveness, What specific factors have engendered and/ or hindered such outcomes, What are the lessons of experience Sri Lanka provide to other developing countries Methodological issues The post-liberalization era is divided into two phases i.e., the ‘first wave-1978-1988) and the second wave (1989-2006); The liberalization experience is compared with the pre-reform era (1970-1977) to contrast the development trajectories Focuses on both income inequality and the broader space of economic divide and to identify some of the proximate determinants Data sources include CFS (CBSL) and HIES (DCS) series; here, one faces a huge challenge as data are not consistent for a variety of reasons. The paper uses other eclectic sources of data too . Income distribution by deciles (1973-2003/04) Decile distribution data are rather congested; Yet, they show that income shares of the first two quintiles declined relentlessly since 1978/79. Conversely the top most deciles gained persistently. The income share of the 1st decile fell from 2.79 in 1973 to 1.86 in 2004. The dividends of reforms have by passed the poor. The share of the 10th decile swelled from 28.03 in 1973 to 36.45 in 2004. The rich amassed the benefits of reforms Income inequality trends (income data) Quintiles 1973 1978/79 1981/82 1986/87 1996/97 2003/04 Bottom 7.2 5.7 5.7 5.0 5.7 5.1 2nd 12.1 10.3 9.5 9.1 10.0 9.1 3rd 16.2 14.3 13.3 13.5 14.1 13.4 4th 21.6 19.8 19.5 20.1 20.8 20.5 Top 42.9 49.9 52.0 52.3 49.4 52.0 Quintile distribution (1973-2004) The gains to the top 40 percent have increased from 64 percent in 1973 to 72 percent in 2004. However, what is more important perhaps is the changes in the income share of the top 1 percent which represent the ultra rich (For which we do not have data). Using the Mishra’s classification income share of 19.3 for the first 40 % in 1973 was permissible but this condition deteriorated sharply during the post reform period. Figure 1- Lorenz Curves for years 1973, 1981 and 1996. Source: Central Bank of Sri Lanka Lorenz Curves for 1973-2004 100 90 Cumulative distribution of income 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 Cum ulative distribution of population Line of perfect equality Lorenz curve 1973 Lorenz curve 1981 Lorenz curve 1996 100 How Gini ratio changed over the period 1963-2004 Inequality Ratios based on CFS data 1963-2004 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1963 1973 GINI coefficient for 1978/79 a) Spending units 1981/82 b) 1986/87 Income receivers 1996/97 c) 2003/04 Decile distribution* Other indices of income inequality Description 1973 1978/79 1981/82 1986/87 1996/97 2003/4 0.35 0.41 0.43 0.50 0.45 0.52 0.46 0.52 0.43 0.48 0.46 0.50 (Q1+Q2)/Q5 Q5/Q1 0.45 5.9 0.32 8.7 0.29 9.1 0.27 10.4 0.32 8.6 0.27 10.1 Theil Index 0.28 0.35 0.39 0.39 0.33 0.38 Gini ratios Spending units Income receivers Quintile Ratios Discussion Indicators are unanimous that income inequality has worsen. Inequality level was lowest in 1973; worst in 1986/87 (towards the end of the first wave). Second wave marks signs of leveling off but this trend was reversed again in 2004. The figures quoted are comparatively worse and here most of the SA countries perform much better. For instance, Gini ratio is around 0.3-0.4 for all the SA. The quintile ratio of 10 plus (meaning, the share of the top income decile is about 10 times the bottom income decile) compares with about 6 in India and Pakistan Consumption data Consumption data are generally supposed to be better than the income data. However, Sri Lanka’s consumption data series is not as consistent as the income data series of the DCS. DCS data series became comparable since 1990/91 Consumption Data Quintiles 1980/81 1990/91 2002 Bottom 2nd 3rd 4th Top 8.9 12.9 16.5 21.3 40.4 8.8 12.9 16.5 21.5 40.2 7.7 11.5 15.4 21.5 43.7 Cumulative % of Income for 1980 and 2002 Consumption data-Changing pattern of Gini ratios 1980-2002 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1 2 3 4 5 Cumulative % households Line of equality 1980 line 2002 line 6 Discussion of Income/expenditure distribution trends In the mid 1970s, poor gained both absolute and relative terms (Fields, 1980). These changes were directly policy driven. The changes had far reaching consequences (Land Reforms, 1972; Nationalization of Plantation Companies, 1975; Ceiling on Housing property, 1973; Compulsory savings for rich, 1994 and so on). 1977 reforms reversed this process (Tax concessions, amnesties, stipulations to increase land rent for share tenancy, privatization programme, removal of the universal food subsidy, reduction of social welfare expenses, removal of fertilizer subsidy, closure of PMB, closure of seed farms, elimination of state monopolies, reduction of expenditure on irrigation and road infrastructure and so on). Widening the divide Specific situations of reforms affecting nutritional levels of adults in the first wave and children under 5 in the second wave are identified. ‘Drop-outs in education’ and the gaps in educational quality by regions form another divide. Regional, sectoral and gender biases in terms of income, health, educational and employment opportunities cover another major problem area. Filters-GDP Growth Growth rates falling and becoming volatile In booms the ‘top’ deciles gain but in busts the ‘bottom’ loses disproportionately . Was the growth ‘pro-poor’? Who gain and where? Table 1.1-Economic growth as a filter 1970-1978 1978-1988 1989-2004 19702004 3.07 4.98 4.83 4.48 1.41 0.35 (1973) 2.95 0.46 (1987) 1.48 0.46(2004) 1.93 0.35-0.46 -22 31 0 31 Indicator/year Average growth rate Average rate of growth of agricultural sector Gini ratio Reduction of income inequality (%)[1] Source: Computed using data from the annual report of the Central Bank Negative figures indicate reduction of poverty ( Growth trends compared Priority sectors and growth In terms of distribution of income rural + estate sectors matter a lot; 77 % of the population and more than 90 % of the poor dwell here Agricultural income has fallen; minimum procurement prices have fallen; credit to the sector has fallen; irrigation investments have fallen Industrialization has centralized to the Western province (which is the top gainer of reform dividends); so does the booming services sector Table 1.2- Priority sectors (industrialization strategy) 1970-77 Indicators / Period Annual growth rate of Industrial GDP (deflated using GDP deflator). 6 Annual growth rate of exports 14.4 (in US $) 3.06 Annual growth rate of GDP 1978-88 19892004 8.8 6.1 12.4 16.7 4.98 4.45 Spatial distribution of industrial units Are food grains unproductive? Falling real prices of food grains Filters-Fiscal compression Investments on physical and institutional infrastructural have fallen Soft targets like education and health sectors suffered the most Subsidies including ‘food’ , fertilizer, credit, are immediate casualties % ag exp. Ag exp. 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 1984 1983 1982 1981 1980 Rs. millions (1996 price) / % ag expenditure / Total Exp. Falling public expenditure on agriculture Public expenditure in agriculture 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Reemergence of Malaria in the second wave Impact of Financial reforms Employment filter ‘Jobless growth’ – falling employment elasticity of growth leaving many ‘un’- or ‘under’ employed. Changes in the structure of employment favouring unorganized/ informal/ casual sectors. Privatization leading to ‘lay-offs’ and ‘casualization’ of work Wage levels falling in real terms Conditions of work deteriorating Employment as a Filter Table 1.3 –Data on the elasticity of employment Total Employment % Change of GDP % Change of employment 1971 229 3649 4.09 1.08 1979 321 4647 40.1 27.34 Year GDP (1996 factor cost price) Employment elasticity of agricultural GDP* Employment elasticity of GDP* 1.77(0.22) 0.68 (0.08) 0.09(0.008) 1987 462 5271 43.92 13.43 0.30(0.03) -0.16 (-0.01) 2003 929 6947 101 31.79 0.31 (0.02) 1.4-Percentage employed by status of Employment 1973 1978/79 1981/82 1986/97 1996/97 2003/04 60.9 -1.4 30.9 6.7 29.7 28.6 1.6 30.0 10.2 22.8 35.3 1.3 30.0 10.6 20.9 35.8 1.7 32.9 8.7 Category of employment Regular Casual* Employers Self employed Unpaid family workers 36.5 25.6 1.5 23.0 13.5 30.4 36.2 2.2 22.8 8.5 1.5-Dichotomies in weekly earnings by organized and the unorganized sectors Earnings for a Males in the week (Rs)* organized private sector Below 300 9.3 (9.3) 3001-600 30.9 (40.2) 601-1000 26.4 (66.4) 1001-2000 23.1 (89.7) 2001-3000 5.5 (95.2) Over 3001 4.8 (100) Females in the organized private sector 14.2 (14.2) 47.1 (61.3) 28.6 (89.9) 8.6 (98.5) 0.8 (99.3) 0.7 (100) Males in the unorganized private sector 22.3 (22.3) 35.2 (57.5) 27.4 (84.9) 13.3 (98.2) 1.1 (99.3) 0.7 (100) Females in the unorganized private sector 51.8 (51.8) 33.5 (85.3) 11.9 (97.2) 2.6 (99.8) 0.1 (99.9) 0.1 (100) Inflation filter Exchange rate-inflation link. Inflation is specially bad for workers in the agricultural and other unorganized sectors (whose wage rates are not indexed). It is also bad for producers whose bargaining power is limited; it lowers internal terms of trade for farmers when input costs rise at a faster rate than output prices. Exchange rate-inflation nexus 60 40 -40 -60 -80 -100 Infaltion Bud defici Ex rate % Ex debt % 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 1985 1983 1981 1979 1977 1975 -20 1973 0 1971 Percentage Change 20 Real wages falling for plantation workers in the second wave Overall welfare Sri Lanka’s ‘initial welfare gains’ are lost; she has failed to ‘increase the lead’ or even to ‘maintain the lead’. Other conditions of socio-political gains also are fast disappearing Suicides in the agricultural belts portray this calamity. Suicides in Sri Lanka The lessons Findings show that there is a marked divergence between the theory and practice of liberalization orthodoxy. In the case of Sri Lanka the dividends of reforms were ‘short-lived’ but the social costs were ‘deep’, ‘pervasive’, ‘long-drawn’. ‘Income inequality’ has undoubtedly increased; there is ample evidence to show that the other forms of divides are widening. These trends are directly linked to the reforms and various ‘filters’ of inequality also are identified. Context specific data shows that reforms thus far have failed to produce the promised results. The dangers are not over. Pressure for ‘market driven’ reforms in the ‘land, water, infrastructure, health and education markets’ are building; they will remove the remaining safeguards and with that ‘inclusiveness’ will disappear from the skies of Sri Lanka forever.