2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Teaching Fixed Exchange Rates and Stockpiled Reserves to Undergraduates: Updating Demand and Supply Jannett Highfill Bradley University Department of Economics (309) 677-2304 Raymond Wojcikewych Bradley University Department of Economics (309) 677-3286 July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 1 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Teaching Fixed Exchange Rates and Stockpiled Reserves to Undergraduates: Updating Demand and Supply ABSTRACT: The paper argues that fixed exchange rates need to be taught to undergraduates because they are closely related to the kind of export-led growth strategies that have been successful for such countries as Japan, South Korea, and China. The paper further argues that supply and demand provides a useful framework for teaching fixed exchanged rates—providing non-linear demand functions are used. We argue in favor of isoelastic demand. The problem for instructors is that drawing graphs for power point slides or coming up with numerical examples for homeworks and exams becomes somewhat time-consuming. The major work of the paper is to provide a simple way of finding parameter sets that generate good teaching examples. INTRODUCTION While the global financial crisis dominated the economic news in recent years, the growing stockpiles of international reserves held by some countries have prompted a lingering debate as to the motives behind these massive accumulations. Leading the list of countries with some of the largest foreign reserves are three Asian economic superpowers, namely, China, Japan, and Korea. Just prior to the global crisis these three countries alone held 44%, or nearly half, of world reserves, around $1.6 trillion (IMF Annual Report, 2005). Today, China and Japan still top the world list with over $3.7 trillion in foreign reserves, while Korea’s holdings ($315 billion) keep it in the top ten world rankings (Global Finance, 2012). Economists continue to debate the underlying reasons for these huge accumulations of foreign reserves. In the present paper we argue that in a purely market- determined exchangeJuly 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 2 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 rate system, the exchange rate will adjust to balance out trade and capital flows. In other words, it seems impossible for a country to be able to accumulate foreign reserves without manipulating its exchange rate. Paul Krugman in his New York Times column recently came to a similar conclusion: Some observers question whether we really know that China’s currency is undervalued. But they’re kidding right? The flip side of the manipulation that keeps China’s currency undervalued is the accumulation of dollar reserves (Krugman, 2011). In this view, a country maintains an under-valued currency in order to promote its exports and thereby fuel economic growth. Resisting a revaluation of its currency requires selling domestic currency and buying foreign currencies. The latter is the source of foreign reserves accumulation. China, Japan, and Korea, at various times over the past four decades, have been accused of this type of modern mercantilist policy. An alternative explanation for the hoarding of reserves is the “self-insurance or precautionary demand” motive. In this view, foreign reserves act as a stabilizer defending against a possible drop in a country’s output or capital flight. Aizenman and Lee (2008) argue that the slowing of economic growth may in fact have provided motivation for both precautionary hoarding and modern mercantilism in the case of Japan and Korea. They argue the two motives can in fact reinforce each other. Hoarding reserves as a precaution against financial crises also promotes a competitive (undervalued?) exchange rate. China’s phenomenal economic performance (since 1991 at least) is often compared to Japan’s rise during the 1950’s and 1960’s. According to Ito (2006) similarities between the two countries during the respective time periods include rapid economic growth fueled by manufacturing, capital controls, increasing foreign reserves, and a dollar peg. (See also Obstfeld July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 3 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 (2007) for an analysis of these similarities.) Differences between the two countries, however, include a bigger reliance on the part of China on FDI for its growth, and, more moderate inflation in China whereas Japanese inflation was high (particularly in the mid 70’s when Japan transitioned off the dollar peg). South Korea’s economic ascendency followed Japan’s (but was before China’s) in its export-led growth strategy. The U.S. declared Korea an “exchange rate manipulator” under the Omnibus Trade Act of 1988 (Obstfeld, 2007). Over the period of 1973-1995, Korea was the country with the highest GDP per capita (Ito, 2006, 43). A common thread in the case of all three countries during their respective economic growth periods was a “fear of float” (Calvo and Reinhart, 2002). This fear of fluctuating exchange rates, in turn, fed the need for some sort of currency manipulation and concomitant foreign reserve accumulation. As noted earlier, massive international reserves accumulations can also be motivated by fear of crises of one kind or another. Some observers note that a financial bubble in China in recent years is similar to bubbles in Japan and South Korea in the past that precipitated crises in those countries. Credit as a percentage of GDP in China jumped from 122% in 2008 to 171% in 2010. If this credit bubble should burst (as it did in Japan in the early 90’s and South Korea a few years later), the resulting banking crisis could have serious negative consequences for China’s growth and stability. While Japan and Korea were unable to offset their respective crises, China, many believe, is better situated to stabilize any capital outflows and/or output declines given its vast international reserves. As a growth strategy, reliance by emerging economies on exports to drive their GDP engine appears to have a “life cycle.” While China is held up as the model of export-led efficiency, it should be noted that net exports contributed nothing to China’s growth in 2011(The July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 4 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Economist, May 2012, 11). Pressure from major trading partners also limits currencymanipulation as part of a country’s economic policy. Last fall the U.S. Senate passed a bill that calls for retaliation against any country that generates a large surplus with an undervalued currency (The Economist, May 2012, 5). A generation ago many economists thought that exchange rates would by now be all market determined, and many textbooks even now seem to be written that way. To be absolutely clear, this paper is not about China, Japan, or South Korea per se. We believe, however, that these countries experiences demonstrate that a world of all flexible exchange rates has not yet arrived. Nor, we would argue, will such a world be soon in coming. It seems likely that other major countries will take note of the development path of these examples and use a similar strategy. An immediate implication is that it is important to be able to talk in easy intuitive ways about what happens when the market for foreign exchange is not in equilibrium—the implications of the systematic under-valuing of one currency and the over-valuing of the other— and the implications for the financial markets in the country whose currency is over-valued. Essentially a demand and supply for foreign exchange analysis—warts and all—should be in the bag of teaching tools because it connects exchange rates with currency trading volumes. As will be seen later, we ourselves use demand and supply for foreign exchange in some slightly unconventional ways. But whether you use our tools or the convention “X” demand and supply picture—it is essential to have tools to connect, for example, an over-valued dollar in the dollaryuan market with China’s need to find ways to hold its dollars reserves. Implementing these ideas runs into an immediate technical snag. Students often master abstract concepts best when a numerical example or two is presented. For a demand and supply model linear curves are often the first choice of instructors because it is easy to find the slopes and intercepts to generate the July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 5 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 desired equilibrium (or disequilibrim). The problem is that linear demand and supply curves do not make much pedagogical sense in the case of the market for foreign exchange. As everyone who has ever taught exchange rates has explained, the demand for say, dollars in the dollar-yuan market is the same thing as the supply of yuan. To demand dollars is to supply yuan. But a linear demand function does not generate a linear supply function (or anything even close). (The Appendix gives a simple example of this.) The next easiest functional form, unit-elastic demand curves give rise to perfectly inelastic supply curves—also not pedagogically ideal. Thus the present paper proposes that exchange rates be taught with isoelastic demand curves. Doing so, when the demand is elastic, eliminates the pedagogical problems of a backward bending or vertical supply curve. But by introducing isoelastic demand finding numerical examples becomes a little tougher because there are both exponents and shift parameters. The main goal of the present paper is to suggest a simple algebraic strategy for producing numerical examples for the classroom. This is perhaps a modest goal. Examples can always be found by trial and error. But a unit that takes too long to prepare might well end up on the cutting room floor so to speak, even when the instructor is convinced of the topic’s importance. In the competition for scarce space on a syllabus, simplifying a unit’s preparation improves the odds that it is covered. And we believe the exchange rate/financial market implications of export-led growth are simply too important to the world economy to ever be omitted in a one semester principles class, or anywhere else. We hope to facilitate classroom coverage of the market basics of exchange rates by making it quite easy to produce numerical examples. MARKET BASICS July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 6 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Consider first agents holding dollars who want to exchange them for yuan. Assume a constant elasticity of demand for yuan function where QD¥ is quantity demanded, $ is the value of ¥ the yuan, n¥ is the price elasticity and a ¥ is a constant : $ QD¥ a¥ ¥ $ ¥ Q¥ D a¥ n¥ (1) 1/ n¥ (2) 1/1 n¥ ¥ a¥ $ QS$ 1 QD¥ a¥ 1n¥ QS$ (3) n¥ n¥ 1 . (4) These four equations contain the same economic information. The second is simply the inverse demand function to making graphing easy for students. The third is the (indirect) supply of dollars function using the exchange rate identity $ / ¥ QS$ / QD¥ . The fourth is what we call the “Want Yuan” offer curve—giving the relationship between yuan demanded and dollars supplied. (See Figure 2 and its discussion below.) Although no doubt some in-class time would be spent talking about the motives for participating in this market and example transactions given, this material is perhaps familiar enough to be omitted here. A typical part of that discussion is the fact that the demand for yuan implies a supply of dollars and conversely. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 7 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Table 1: Want yuan, have dollars Yuan Quantity Quantity Dollar per of of per Dollar Dollars Yuan Yuan 10 48.28 A 4.82 0.207 15 90 B 6 0.167 20 140 C 7 0.143 July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 8 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 In Table 1, the demand for yuan curve is derived by simply mapping the first two columns, and the supply of dollars by mapping the last two. (See Figure 1 and its discussion below.) The analysis for agents holding yuan who want to exchange them for dollars is similar. Again assuming a constant elasticity of demand for dollars function where QD$ is quantity demanded, ¥ is the value of the dollar, n$ is the price elasticity and a$ is a constant : $ ¥ QD$ a$ $ ¥ QD$ $ a$ $ ¥ n$ (5) 1/ n$ (6) 1/1 n$ a $¥ QS 1 QS¥ a$ n$ QD$ (7) n$ 1 n$ . (8) These are the four analogous equations to those above. A numerical example is given in Table 2. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 9 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Table 2: Want dollars, have yuan Yuan Quantity Quantity Dollars per of of per Dollar Dollars Yuan Yuan 12 84 a 7 0.143 15 90 b 6 0.167 20 98.37 c 4.92 0.203 July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 10 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 The demand for dollars is the first two columns and the supply of yuan is the last two. Figure 1 shows the traditional demand and supply approach. The demand for yuan and the equivalent supply of dollars is shown by the dashed lines. The points A, B, and C from Table 1 are plotted as shown. The demand for dollars and equivalent supply of yuan are the solids lines; the points a, b, and c from Table 2 are plotted as well. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 11 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Market for Yuan Market for Dollars Value of Yuan Value of Dollar 14 0.8 12 0.6 Supply of Yuan 10 Supply of Dollars 8 a 0.4 B 6 b A 0.2 B a b 50 4 c A Demand For Dollars Demand for Yuan 2 C 100 C c 150 200 Yuan 5 10 15 20 25 Dollars Figure 1: Demand and supply approach July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 12 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 As alert students will have noticed by now, the equilibrium value of the dollar is 6 (and the value of the yuan 1/ 6 1.67 ). But we believe the focus on quantities in the market for foreign exchange is especially appropriate when the exchange rate is not in equilibrium. Thus, when the value of the dollar is set at 7 (and the value of the yuan 1/ 7 1.43 ) the dollar is over-valued and the yuan is under-valued. Although the implications for currency reserves can be seen in Figure 1 we believe they are somewhat easier for students to see in Figure 2. Looking again at Table 1, the information in the demand for yuan (or equivalently the supply of dollars) is also contained in the two middle columns of the table. Using an analogy from trade theory, we graph the middle two columns in the dollar-yuan space and call the resulting curve the “Want Yuan” offer curve. (This method is explained in more detail in Highfill and Wojcikewych (2011); comparative statics which are not in the present paper are in Highfill and Wojcikewych (2012).) The points A, B, and C are plotted just as they were in Figure 1. Notice with the quantities on the axes, the exchange rate (the value of the dollar, the variable on the horizontal axis) is the slope of any ray from the origin. The intuitive explanation for students of this offer curve is that as the value of the dollar rises (and the yuan falls) Chinese goods become cheaper for Americans and they demand more of them. Demanding more Chinese goods means they need more yuan, and supply more dollars to obtain them. But notice that the Want Yuan offer curve is convex up. The intuitive explanation is that as the dollar gains value it takes smaller and smaller increments in number of dollars supplied to get equal increments in yuan demanded. (The curve is getting steeper.) July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 13 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Yuan 200 Want Yuan C 150 100 a 50 c b B Want Dollars 15 20 A 5 10 25 Dollars Figure 2: Offer curve approach July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 14 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 The “Want Dollars” offer curve is derived from the middle two columns of Table 2. The intuitive explanation for its slope is similar—with the appropriate adjustments for the fact that the currency demanded is on the horizontal axis rather than the vertical one. As the value of the dollar falls Chinese demand more U.S. good, more dollars, and supply more yuan to get them. But here the slope is getting flatter—as the yuan gains more and more value, a smaller yuan increment is needed to obtain any given dollar increment. The equilibrium value of the dollar is the slope of the ray going through the B-b point, i.e., 6—although the ray is not shown to keep the picture as simple as possible. But when the dollar is (over)valued at 7 yuan, Americans will find (as compared to equilibrium) that their dollars go further and they will buy more Chinese goods (or assets etc.). They want 140 yuan and supply 20 dollars to get them. On the other hand, Chinese agents will find American goods and assets more expensive (compared to equilibrium) and desire 12 dollars and supply 84 yuan to get them. So, looking at the yuan axis, Americans desire 140 yuan but private agents in China will supply only 84 yuan. The Chinese government must supply the difference, 56 yuan, the vertical distance between the dashed lines in Figure 2. Overvaluing the dollar is seen to be a feasible strategy for the Chinese government because they can always print the necessary yuan. Looking now at the dollar axis, Americans have supplied 20 dollars but private Chinese agents only want 12 dollars. This difference, 8 dollars, is the number of dollars the Chinese government has to absorb. This is the horizontal distance between the dashed lines in Figure 2. Whichever method is preferred, both Figures 1 and 2 help students “see” the key point— that an export-led growth strategy of overvaluing the dollar is precisely a policy of accumulating dollars reserves. No country can have a sustained export-led growth strategy of selling to the U.S. market without accumulating vast sums of dollars. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 15 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 FINDING PARAMETERS The primary argument of the present paper is that to use a teaching strategy something like the one suggested here, it is quite helpful to use numerical examples. But the trial and error method of finding them is time consuming. The present section shows how to begin with whatever solution you want to show the students in terms of the equilibrium exchange rate, disequilibrium exchange rate, and currency quantities, and then find the parameter set that generates them. For numerical examples there is usually a tradeoff between realistic numbers and something simple enough students can follow in class. The example above attempts a middle path, exchange rates that are ballpark correct, but simple enough quantities that at least some lines of the tables are intuitive. Different people with different teaching philosophies may emphasize one goal over the other. The method which follows allows for easy construction of numerical examples to match the specific teaching goals. As perhaps is apparent, we want to find parameters which produce relatively transparent numbers for five variables: (1) the flexible/equilibrium value of the dollar, (2) the quantity of dollars with a flexible/equilibrium exchange rate, (3) a fixed value of the dollar, (4) the quantity of dollars demanded at that fixed exchange rate, and (5) the quantity of dollars supplied at that fixed exchange rate. (The fixed and flexible value and quantities of the yuan are, of course, implied by these.) July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK Table 3 summarizes our choices for these in the example above. 16 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 Table 3: Teaching example starting values Q$flex 15 July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK e flex ¥ 6 $ e fixed 7 $ QDfixed 12 $ QSfixed 20 17 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 To simplify the notation notice we denote the value of the dollar by e with a subscript to distinguish between fixed and flexible exchange rates. It is also worth mentioning that $ $ since the fixed value of the dollar is by assumption higher than the flexible one. QSfixed QDfixed To find the parameters that yield these numbers it is useful to formally characterize both the flexible equilibrium and fixed exchange rate solutions. For flexible exchange rates, the $ $ equilibrium condition is simply that QSflex QDflex Q$flex , i.e., equation (3) is set equal to equation (6) which yields 1 e flex a n$ n¥ 1 $ a¥ (9) and equivalently n¥ 1 n$ Q$ flex a$ n$ n¥ 1 a¥ n$ n¥ 1 . (10) The fixed exchange rate case is even simpler. The supply of dollars is taken directly from (3) $ QSfixed e fixed 1 n¥ a¥ (11) $ QDfixed e fixed a$ . (12) and the demand for dollars from (5) n$ With these equations we can tackle what, for lack of a better term, we will call the technical problem—the opposite in some sense of the economic one. The economic problem is $ $ to find {Q$flex , e flex } and {QDfixed , QSfixed } for a given e fixed and given values of {a$ , a¥ , n$ , n¥ } . The technical problem is the reverse. To find values of {a$ , a¥ , n$ , n¥ } that will yield the (chosen by $ $ the instructor) values of {Q$flex , e flex , QDfixed , QSfixed , e fixed } for our example, the values in Table 3. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 18 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 $ $ Notice that in equations (9)-(12) the set {Q$flex , e flex , QDfixed , QSfixed , e fixed } are on the left-hand side and the {a$ , a¥ , n$ , n¥ } are on the right-hand side, except that in (11) and (12) the fixed exchange rate has an exponent related to the elasticity. It is computationally simpler now to use the log transformed versions of (9)-(12), which are respectively Log[e flex ] n$ n¥ 1 Log[a$ ] Log[a¥ ] (13) Log[Q$ flex ](n$ n¥ 1) (n¥ 1) Log[a$ ] n$ Log[a¥ ] (14) $ Log[ QSfixed ] (n¥ 1) Log[e fixed ] Log[a¥ ] (15) $ Log[QDfixed ] n$ Log[e fixed ] Log[a$ ]. (16) As a final step just to clarify the notation, define A$ Log[a$ ] A¥ Log[a¥ ] , next define $ r Log[e flex ] s Log[e fixed ] , and finally x Log[QDfixed ] , y Log[Q$ flex ] , and $ z Log[ QSfixed ] . So rewriting (13)-(16) again with this notation yields r n$ n¥ 1 A$ A¥ (17) y(n$ n¥ 1) (n¥ 1) A$ n$ A¥ (18) z (n¥ 1) s A¥ (19) x n$ s A$ . (20) Solving these for {n$ , n¥ , A$ , A¥ } is straight forward. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK A$ $ sy rx Log[e fixed ]Log[Q$ flex ] Log[e flex ]Log[QDfixed ] sr Log[e fixed ] Log[e flex ] (21) A¥ $ sy rz Log[e fixed ]Log[Q$ flex ] Log[e flex ]Log[ QSfixed ] sr Log[e fixed ] Log[e flex ] (22) 19 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 $ y x Log[Q$ flex ] Log[QDfixed ] n$ sr Log[e fixed ] Log[e flex ] (23) Log[ QSfixed ] Log[Q$ flex ] zy n¥ 1 1 . sr Log[e fixed ] Log[e flex ] (24) $ Given that these are logs they can be written in several equivalent ways, and it must be remembered that A$ Log[a$ ] and A¥ Log[a¥ ] i.e., that a$ Exp[ A$ ] and a¥ Exp[ A¥ ] . So to complete the example used for Tables 1-3 and Figures 1 and 2, a$ 200.686 , a¥ 0.530 , n$ 1.448 , and n¥ 2.866 . Now the work to construct as many examples as needed has been completed. To mention just a couple possibilities, if the goal is to have very transparent exchange rates and trading volumes, then {a$ 125, a¥ 125, n$ 1.322, n¥ 1.262} (25) will be generated by {Q$flex 125, e flex $ $ 1, QDfixed 50, QSfixed 150, e fixed 2}. (26) If the goal is to construct an example where the dollar is undervalued, then {a$ 150, a¥ 50, n$ 1.322, n¥ 1.263} (27) will be generated by {Q$flex 60, e flex $ $ 1, QDfixed 150, QSfixed 50, e fixed 2}. (28) These examples are simplified by the fact that one of the exchange rates is one, the log of one being zero, the constants are easy to compute, and the elasticities virtually the same. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 20 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 CONCLUSION As every student of economics knows the end of the Bretton Woods foreign exchange rate system did not necessarily spell the end of fixed exchange rates. Various countries, notably South Korea, Japan, and China, have found it to their economic advantage to manipulate exchange rates in their favor. Maintaining an undervalued currency has been (at various times during the past forty years) a critical component of their respective export-led growth strategies. However, to keep your currency from revaluation requires selling your currency and buying the foreign currency. The result is an accumulation of foreign reserves. Our goal in this paper has been to present a technique that facilitates more easily and intuitively the teaching of exchange rates and the important consequences of currency manipulation. The latter requires buying and selling vast quantities of currencies in the foreign exchange market. Our model focuses attention squarely on these trading volumes and allows the student to literally see that maintaining an undervalued currency leads directly to the stockpiling of foreign reserves. Since generating realistic numerical examples using our preferred isoelastic demand curves would not be every instructors best use of scarce time, we have provided a technique for generating these numerical examples. Using our “currency offer curves” pedagogy will hopefully take some of the mystery out of the not-so-rare practice of maintaining exchange rates different from equilibrium. While Korea and Japan have transitioned off the dollar peg and China may eventually do so as well, examples of emerging economies following their lead will surely not disappear any time soon. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 21 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 REFERENCES Aizenman, J., & Lee, J. (2008). Financial versus Monetary Mercantilism: Long-Run View of Large International Reserves Hoarding. World Economy, 31(5), 593-611. Calvo, G. A., & Reinhart, C. M. (2002). Fear of Floating. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117(2), 379-408. Global Finance. (2012). International Reserves of Countries Worldwide. http://www.gfmag.com/tools/global-database/economic-data/11859-internationalreserves-by-country.html#axzz22sNNJDLY Highfill, J., & Wojcikewych, R. (2012). A Note on Teaching the Yuan-Dollar Market vis-a-vis China’s Dollar Holdings. Global Economy Journal,12(1), article 7. Highfill, J., & Wojcikewych, R. (2011). The U.S.-China Exchange Rate Debate: Using Currency Offer Curves. International Advances in Economic Research, 17(4), 386-396. International Monetary Fund. (2005.) IMF Annual Report 2005. Washington DC. Ito, T. (2006). Robust Monetary Framework for China. China and World Economy, 14(5), 32-47. Krugman, P. (2011, October 3). Holding China to Account. New York Times, http://www.nytimes.com/2011/10/03/opinion/holding-china-to-account.html?_r=1. Obstfeld, M. (2007). The Renminbi’s Dollar Peg at the Crossroads. Monetary And Economic Studies, 25(S1), 29-55. The Economist . (2012, May 26). Prudence Without a Purpose. 403(8786), 8-11. The Economist . (2012, May 26). The Retreat of the Monster Surplus. 403(8786), 5. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 22 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 APPENDIX: LINEAR DEMAND FOR DOLLARS The goal of this appendix is to give a very brief example of what the supply of yuan curve looks like if the demand for dollars is linear. Suppose the demand for dollar function is ¥ 15 QD$ $ (29) as shown in Figure 3. July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 23 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ¥ $ ISBN : 9780974211428 Value of Dollar 14 12 10 8 6 4 D$ 2 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 Dollars Figure 3: Linear Demand for Dollars July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 24 2013 Cambridge Business & Economics Conference ISBN : 9780974211428 The equivalent supply of yuan is 2 ¥ $ 15 15 4QS ¥ 2QS¥ (30) as shown in Figure 4. $ ¥ Value of Yuan 1.5 1.0 0.5 S¥ 10 20 30 40 50 Yuan Figure 4: Supply of yuan derived from linear demand for dollars July 2-3, 2013 Cambridge, UK 25