Recurrent Survival Analysis of Sequential Conversions of Convertible Bond

advertisement
1
Recurrent Survival Analysis of Sequential Conversions of Convertible Bond
2
3
4
5
Lie-Jane Kao
Department of Finance and Banking, KaiNan University, Taoyuan,Taiwan
6
Li-Shya Chen
7
Department of Statistics, Cheng-Chi University,Taiwan
8
9
10
Cheng-Few Lee
Department of Finance & Economics, Rutgers University, NJ, USA
11
12
13
14
15
16
Instead of a block conversion assumed in previous literature, this study explores the
relationship between the hazard rate of sequential conversion over the lifespan of a
convertible bond and individual bond’s time-dependent characteristics, including the
difference between the equity’s price and conversion price, the dividend, and the risk-free
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
interest rate. The histories of 130 convertible bonds’ conversions and attributes listed on
the Taiwan Stock Exchange outstanding from January 2004 to December 2009 are collected.
By considering individual bond’s sequential conversions as recurrent events and a recurrent
survival analysis technique (Anderson and Gill, 1982; Prentice, Williams, and Peterson,
1981), an extension of the Cox proportional hazard model, is adopted. Our analysis shows
that the difference between the equity’s price and conversion price has a positive effect on
the hazard rate of conversion, while dividend and risk-free interest rate have negative effects.
It is hoped the results can provide a cornerstone for the pricing of convertible bonds based on
the observation of sequential conversion in real life instead of a block conversion assumed in
26
27
28
29
previous literature.
KeyWords. Block Conversion, Hazard Rate, Sequential Conversion, Recurrent Event,
Recurrent Survival Analysis.
30
1
31
1.Introduction
32
A convertible bond is a security that bundles straight debt with an option for the
33
bondholder to convert the bond for a preset number of shares of equity stock.
34
considered as a vehicle to mitigate the asset substitution problem by curbing shareholders’
35
incentive for risk.
36
bondholders in a one-period setting, shareholders often find it is more difficult to shift
37
investment opportunities to riskier projects and to transfer wealth to their own benefits.
38
Mayers (1998, 2002) argued that convertible debts ensure future investment opportunities are
39
made only if profitable, thus it can serve as a sequential financing vehicle to control the
40
over-investment problem.
It is often
In Green (1984), it was argued that in the presence of convertible
41
Nevertheless, the risk-mitigating effect of a convertible bond can be mitigated due to
42
the decision to convert the bonds prior to maturity by the bondholders or due to the decision
43
of a call by the shareholders (Francois et al., 2006).
44
will never be optimal to convert a convertible bond strategically prior to the maturity or the
45
call under the assumptions of a perfect market, constant conversion terms and no dividend
46
payments (Ingersoll, 1977).
47
dividends are paid and adverse changes in the conversion terms are not allowed, the optimal
48
conversion strategy is to convert a convertible bond either immediately prior to a dividend
49
payment date or at the maturity.
50
bondholders ensures the risk-mitigating effect of a convertible bond.
From the bondholders’ viewpoint, it
In another paper by Brennan and Schwartz (1977, 1980), if
In either situation, the optimal conversion strategy of the
51
In literature, the determinants of a bondholder’s decision to convert and the timings of
52
conversions are inclusive. It is argued that the expected probability of a conversion at
53
maturity or the expected time to conversion is determined by the initial design features of a
54
convertible bond (Lewis et al., 2003; Lee et al., 2009). According to Lewis et al. (2003), the
55
expected probability of a conversion at maturity is positively correlated with the differences
2
56
between the stock and conversion prices as well as the risk-free interest rate at the time of
57
convertible issue, but negatively correlated with the firm’s dividend yield for the year before
58
the convertible issue date.
59
separation of control and ownership rights are prone to issue more debt-like convertibles,
60
which have lower expected probabilities of a conversion at maturity, to avoid expropriation
61
of minority shareholders’ wealth by controlling shareholders.
62
addresses the strategic dimension of conversion by bondholders (Emanuel, 1983;
63
Constantinides, 1984; Asquith & Mullins, 1991; Bühler and Koziol, 2004; Francois et al., 2006;
64
Sirbu and Shreve, 2006).
65
value is sufficiently high and the downside protection premium offered by the bond is
66
sufficiently low, the cash flow differential of dividends over coupon interest can be great
67
enough to engender strategic conversion. In Sirbu and Shreve (2006), by considering the
68
conversion-call strategy as a two-person, zero-sum game, it was shown that if the coupon
69
rate is below the dividend rate times the call price, then conversion should precede call and
70
strategic conversion should be more prevalent for bonds with greater conversion values. On
71
the other hand, if the dividend rate times the call price is below the coupon rate, call should
72
precede conversion.
In Lee et al. (2009), it is documented that firms with higher
There are also literature
In Asquith & Mullins (1991), it is argued that when the conversion
73
All the aforementioned literature implicitly or explicitly assumed a block conversion in
74
which all the convertible bonds are completely converted at the same time or not at all.
75
Instead of a block conversion, however, one often observes sequential conversions by
76
competitive bondholders over time instead of a block conversion. Constantinides (1984)
77
showed that in the absence of straight bonds, a competitive equilibrium exists so that
78
sequential conversions can be optimal in that the price of a divisible convertible bond equals
79
that of a block one. In Bühler and Koziol (2004), by including additional straight bonds in a
80
firm’s capital structure, it was shown sequential strategic conversions is in general optimal
81
rather than a block conversion.
3
In Francois et al. (2006), by allowing the risk shifting due to
82
investment opportunity occurring randomly after capital structure was previously designed,
83
the decisions to shift risk and to convert strategically are considered as a non-cooperative
84
game between shareholders and convertible bondholders. When the game is sequential, it
85
was shown that shareholders substitute assets to shift risk and bondholders strategically
86
convert arises as an attainable Nash equilibrium which can prevail sequentially over time.
87
This study explores the relationship between the intensity of sequential conversion over
88
the lifespan of a convertible bond and the determinants of sequential conversions of
89
individual bond, including the conversion price, the equity’s price, the dividend, and the
90
bond’s coupon rate.
91
and attributes listed on the Taiwan Stock Exchange outstanding from January 2004 to
92
December 2009 are collected. Compared to previous studies in which a block conversion is
93
assumed, our approach considers individual bond’s sequential conversions as recurrent
94
events and recurrent survival analysis technique (Anderson and Gill, 1982; Prentice,
95
Williams, and Peterson, 1981), an extension of the Cox proportional hazard model, is
96
adopted. To our knowledge, this is the first study that uses the recurrent survival technique in
97
studying the conversion behaviors of bondholders in a dynamic setting.
To be able to do so, the histories of 130 convertible bonds’ conversions
98
The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 gives a review for the works in the survival
99
analysis of recurrent events. Section 3 develops the model. An empirical study is given in
100
Section 4, and Section 5 concludes.
101
1. Recurrent Survival Analysis: Variance-correction versus Frailty
102
Survival analyses of recurrent events that occur repeatedly over time for a given subject
103
are common in the study of health science (Prentice et al., 1981; Andersen and Gill, 1982;
104
Wei et al., 1989, 1990, 1997; Kelly and Lim, 2000; Cook and Lawless, 2002; Duchateau et. al.,
105
2003; Schaubel and Cai, 2005).
106
international conflicts (Beck et. al., 1998), presidential nominations (McCarty and Razaghian,
107
1999).
4
They also occur in the scope of political science, e.g.
108
In the study of recurrent events, event dependency within an individual is a common
109
theme. In addition, sometimes recurrent events within the same individual involve different
110
types of categories and the ordering of the events is important. The traditional Cox’s
111
proportional hazard model (Cox PH), which deals with a subject’s first failure, is therefore
112
biased in the recurrent events context. Two extensions of Cox PH model, namely, the
113
variance-correction models and frailty models were developed to account for this deficiency
114
(Box-Steffensmeier et al., 2006).
115
Variations within the variance-correction models depend on whether recurrent events
116
within the same individual are treated as identical or not.
117
different categories and the order of the recurrent events is important, variance-correction
118
models are developed using a stratified Cox model with different risk sets defined for each
119
strata. Three widely used variance-correction models are: the conditional risk set (PWP)
120
model (Prentice, Williams, Peterson, 1981), the Andersen-Gill (AG) model (Anderson and
121
Gill, 1982), and the marginal risk set (WLW) model (Wei, Lin, Weissfeld, 1989).
If recurrent events involve
122
In the Andersen-Gill (AG) model, which is based on a non-homogeneous Poisson
123
counting processes, all the recurrent events within an individual are treated as identical
124
(Andersen and Gill, 1982). Unless time-dependent covariates that capture the dependence of
125
recurrent events within an individual are included, the recurrent events on the same
126
individual are independent and identical under the AG model. In cases recurrent events
127
within the same individual are of different categories and the order of the events is important,
128
either the conditional risk set model or the marginal risk set model should be adopted.
129
the conditional risk set model by Prentice, et al. (1981), the risk set of the kth recurrent event
130
are restricted to the individuals who have experienced the first k-1 recurrent events, and the
131
baseline hazard functions are allowed to vary with k, k=1,2,…, K. In the marginal risk set
132
model proposed by Wei, et al. (1989), the risk set of the kth recurrent event contains all the
133
subjects that had not experienced the kth recurrent event or censored.
5
In
Similar to the
134
conditional risk set model, the baseline hazard function and the regression parameters may
135
vary with the order of recurrent event k in the marginal risk set model.
136
In contrast to variance-correction models, the frailty models use unobservable random
137
covariates to account for the dependence among the recurrent events within an individual,
138
which explain the heterogeneity across individuals. The simplest form of a frailty model is
139
the Andersen-Gill model with a random covariate. An estimation procedure for the
140
regression parameters, the variance of the frailty, and the underlying hazard function is
141
proposed by Nielsen et al. (1992). Whereas more advanced frailty model is proposed by
142
Clayton and Cuzick (1985), which assumes that the unobserved random covariate is from a
143
gamma distribution with mean one and an unknown variance. For the situation that the order
144
of recurrent events is important, the conditional frailty model that combines a random
145
covariate
146
Box-Steffensmeier et al., 2002, 2006).
with
event-based
stratification
is
proposed
(Kelly
and
Lim,
2000;
147
148
2. Model Development: Sequential Conversions as Recurrent Events
149
Suppose the time horizon is divided into L time intervals (t0, t1], (t1, t2], … , (tL-1, tL].
150
Consider a set of N convertible bonds For each bond, one or more of the following events
151
are observed: (1) A sequence of conversions, (2) The call announcement by the firm, (3) The
152
maturity of the bond, and (4) The exercise of put options by the bondholders.
153
of this paper is to explore the behavior of sequential conversions till the maturity date of the
154
bonds, the events of a call and exercises of put options will be ignored.
.
As the theme
155
To model the hazard of a conversion for bond i at time t, 1iN, the determinants of a
156
conversion in literature including the conversion price, the stock’s price, the dividend, the
157
bond’s coupon rate, and the risk-free interest rate are considered (Constantinides, 1984;
158
Asquith & Mullins, 1991; Bühler and Koziol, 2004; Francois et al., 2006). As the coupon
6
159
rates of the sample bonds are all zeros, we consider the following three time-dependent
160
covariates at time t: (1) The difference between the highest stock price and conversion price
161
X1i(t), (2) The dividend rate X2i(t), and (3) The risk-free interest rate X3i(t).
162
dividend effect is traced back to four months prior to the distribution date of the dividends.
Note the
163
If one considers the sequence of conversions within a bond as identical events and the
164
order of conversions is not important, one might adopt the variance corrected AG model by
165
Anderson and Gill (1982) due to its efficiency and precision in giving the most reliable
166
estimates of the covariates’ effects (Therneau and Grambsch, 2000).
167
proportional hazard (Cox PH) model, the hazard function of bond i for its kth conversion at
168
time t has the proportional form
ik (t )  0 (t ) exp 1 X 1i (t )   2 X 2i (t )   3 X 3i (t )
169
Like the Cox’s
(1)
170
where 0(.) is the baseline hazard function.
171
same individual are treated as independent observations, and therefore the partial likelihood
172
can be expressed as
In the AG model, the recurrent events of the
 ik
N K i 1

ik (Tik )

L(  )     N
K j  1 I (T


T

T
)

(
T
)


i 1 k 1 
j ,l 1
ik
j ,l
jl ik 
 j 1 l 1
173
(2)
174
where =(1, 2, 3) are the coefficients in (1), Tik is the time of the kth conversion of the ith
175
bond, 1kKi, while Ti , K i 1 is the termination time of the ith bond, 1iN. The indicator I()
176
is one if Tik  (T j ,l 1 , T j ,l ] and zero otherwise, while the indicator δik equals to 1 if bond i is
177
converted at Tik and zero otherwise.
178
random effect or frailty to account for the heterogeneity among bonds and the dependence
179
between sequential conversions within an individual bond. The hazard function (1) for the
180
AG frailty model becomes
ik (t )  0 (t ) exp 1 X 1i (t )   2 X 2i (t )   3 X 3i (t )   i 
181
182
The above AG model can be extended to include a
(3)
where  i is the frailty of bond i, 1iN. Note it is assumed the frailties  1 , …,  N share a
7
183
common mean one and a common variance  2 .
184
However, if one considers the sequence of conversions within a bond as heterogeneous
185
events and the order of conversions is important, the conditional risk set approach by
186
Prentice Williams, and Peterson (1981), i.e., the PWP approach, in which the observations
187
are stratified by the order of conversions, should be used.
In the PWP approach, different
188
baseline hazards will be employed for different stratum.
Let C=max{K1,…,KN} be the
189
maxima number of conversions within a bond among the N sample bonds, and thus there are
190
C stratum.
191
function of bond i for its kth conversion at time t has the usual proportional hazard form
Let 0k(t) be the baseline hazard at time t for the kth stratum, 1kC, the hazard
*ik (t )  0k (t ) exp1 X 1i (t )   2 X 2i (t )  3 X 3i (t )
192
(4)
Since a bond is not at risk for the kth conversion until its (k-1)th
193
where 1iN, 1kC.
194
conversion has been occurred, only the bonds whose (k-1)th and kth conversion occurs prior to
195
and after Tik, respectively, are considered to be at risk, where Tik is the kth conversion time for
196
the ith bond.


*ik (Tik )

L(  )     N
*

I
(
T

T

T
)

(
T
)

i 1k 1 
j ,k 1
ik
jk
jk
ik 
 j 1
N
197
198
Hence, the partial likelihood can be formulated as
 ik
C
(5)
A frailty term could also be included in (4), and the hazard becomes
*ik t   0k (t ) exp1 X1,i (t )  2 X 2,i (t )  3 X 3,i (t )  i 
199
(6)
200
where  i is the frailty of bond i, 1iN. Note it is assumed the frailties  1 , …,  N share a
201
common mean one and a common variance  2 .
202
203
3. Data
204
From the list on the Taiwan Stock Exchange, convertible bond that were outstanding
205
from January 2004 to December 2009 and terminated before December 31, 2009 are eligible
206
for our study.
8
Among the eligible convertible bond issues, we select our sample bond
207
issues based on the following criteria:
208
(1) Exclude the listed companies in the financial sector due to the comparability of
209
financial indicators;
210
(2) If two or more convertible bonds are issued by the same company, then only one of
211
them is randomly selected.
212
We thus have 170 eligible issues of convertible bonds. As the main purpose of the
213
analysis is to develop a hazard model that exhibits the dynamic features of the sequential
214
conversion phenomenon observed empirically. Therefore, the bond issues that were traded
215
with more shares for call or put are excluded from the sample. Further analysis shows 18
216
bond issues were traded with more shares for call, while 22 were traded with more shares for
217
put. After removing them, there are 130 bonds issues that are traded mainly for conversion.
218
For each sample bond, the history of conversions during January 2004 to December 2009 is
219
collected
220
http://www.gretai.org.tw/ch/bond_trading_info/bonds_info/monthly/cbnote.php. While the
221
covariates’ histories and the risk-free interest rates during January 2004 to December 2009
222
are collected from Taiwan Economic Journal (TEJ).
from
the
website
of
Taiwan’s
GreTai
Securities
Markets
at
223
From January 2004 to December 2009, all monthly records of the 130 eligible convertible
224
bonds are of the counting process format, i.e., (ID, 1, 2, Status, X1, X2, X3, …), where 1 and
225
2 denote the times when the monthly interval started and ended, respectively. Status
226
indicates whether conversion occurring at the interval specified by [1, 2), and X1, X2, X3, …
227
denote the covariates. As pointed by Therneau and Grambsch (2000) and Allison (2010),
228
counting process format helps to handle datasets with recurrent events and time-dependent
229
covariates.
230
Among the 130 eligible convertible bonds, observations with their differences between
231
the highest stock price and the conversion price exceeding $200 are considered as outliers.
232
By removing these outliers, our final sample consists of N=128 bonds and there is a total of
9
233
128
 ni  4497 observations for the empirical study. Table 1 gives the summary statistics of the
i 1
234
three covariates X1, X2 and X3 for the 128 sample bonds.
235
represents the standardized differences between the highest stock price and the conversion
236
price.
237
4. Empirical Analysis
Note that the covariate X1
238
The lifespans or durations in months since publication of the N=130 sample bonds are
239
summarized in Table 2, in which the frequency and the cumulative percent frequency
240
distributions of the lifespan are given.
241
lasted no more than 40 months: 12% of them had been traded fast and terminated within 15
242
months and one third of them terminated within 25 months. Only 16.9% of the sample bonds
243
had stayed to the end of the sample period.
244
percentages of conversions been made from January 2004 to December 2009 for a total of 60
245
months. Among the 130 bonds being studied, since their issuances, 6% converted before the
246
4th month, 41% converted before the 10th month, 67% converted before the 14th month. The
247
last conversion occurs at the 32th month.
From Table 2, about two third of the sample bonds
Table 3 provides frequencies and cumulative
248
In Table 4, the AG model with and without the frailty term are estimated, respectively.
249
Panel I shows the estimation result for the AG model without frailty; while Panel II shows
250
the results with the frailty effect. For all cases, all the three covariate X1, X2, and X3 are
251
significant at =0.10 level.
252
between the highest stock price and the conversion price X1 has a positive effect on the
253
hazard rate of conversion, while the dividend X2 and the risk-free interest rate X3 have
254
negative effects on the hazard rate of conversion.
Among the three covariates, the standardized difference
255
For the PWP model, as the maximum number of conversions within an individual bond
256
C=32, to avoid the problem of over stratification, we consider two stratification schemes
257
with four strata each.
10
The first scheme classifies observations of the 1st and 2nd conversion
258
as the first strata, observations after the 2nd up to the 5th as the second strata, observations
259
after the 5th conversion up to the 10th conversion as the third strata, while the remaining
260
observations are classified as the fourth strata. The second scheme classifies observations
261
up to the 5th conversion as the first strata, observations after the 5th conversion up to the 10th
262
conversion as the second strata, observations after the 10th conversion up to the 15th
263
conversion as the third strata, while the remaining observations are classified as the fourth
264
strata.
265
In Table 5, the PWP models under the two aforementioned stratification schemes are
266
estimated.
267
term, respectively, under the first stratification scheme are given. Estimates under the
268
second stratification scheme are given in Panels III and IV for the cases with and without the
269
frailty term, respectively.
270
with those of the AG models: all the three covariate X1, X2, and X3 are significant at =0.10
271
level.
272
price and the conversion price X1 has a positive effect on the hazard rate of conversion, while
273
the dividend X2 and the risk-free interest rate X3 have negative effects on the hazard rate of
274
conversion.
275
In Panels I and II, estimation results of PWP model with and without the frailty
In all cases, the results of the PWP models basically coincide
Among the three covariates, the standardized difference between the highest stock
The positive effect of X1, i.e., the standardized difference between the highest stock price
276
and the conversion price, coincides with that of Lewis et al. (2003).
277
of negative dividend effect 2 is in line with Lewis et al. (2003), in which the expected
278
probability of a conversion at maturity is negatively correlated with the dividend of the fiscal
279
year before the convertible issue. On the other hand, the estimated negative dividend effect
280
2 contradicts with those in Asquith & Mullins (1991) and Sirbu and Shreve (2006). As the
281
coupon rates are all zeros in our sample bonds, the cash flow differential of dividends over
282
coupon interest is not of the main concerns by the bondholders.
283
dividend yield diminishes the growth of future stock price, thus results in negative effect on
11
In addition, the result
Instead, the higher
284
the hazard rate of conversion.
285
portfolio consisting of an straight discount bond plus an option entitling the bondholders to
286
purchase the same fraction of equity with an exercise price determined by the principle of the
287
bond (Ingersoll, 1977), higher risk-free interest rate results not only lower straight bond value,
288
but also diminishes the value of the option to purchase the equity.
289
expect the negative risk-free interest rate effect 3. This contradicts the result that the
290
expected probability of a conversion at maturity is positively correlated with the risk-free
291
interest rate in Lewis et al. (2003).
In addition, as a convertible bond can be considered as a
Therefore, one can
292
293
5. Conclusion
294
From an empirical perspective, bondholders convert part of the outstanding convertibles
295
as long as it was feasible to convert is more prevalent than a block conversion. Not only that,
296
from a theoretical perspective, sequential conversion can also be optimal if one investor
297
holds all convertibles, or if competitive convertible bond holders act strategically (Emanuel,
298
1983; Constantinides, 1984). As the conversion strategy impacts the number of outstanding
299
stocks, their value, and the firm’s capital structure, thus the value of the convertible bonds
300
depends on the conversion strategy followed by the investors. However, most literature
301
implicitly or explicitly assumes a block conversion, i.e., convertible bonds are converted at
302
the same time or not at all to price a convertible bond.
303
technique to explore the relationship between the hazard of sequential conversion and three
304
determinants of a conversion, namely, the highest stock price and the conversion price, the
305
dividend, and the risk-free interest rate in a dynamic setting. It is hoped that the results can
306
provide a cornerstone for the pricing of a convertible bond based on the observation of
307
sequential conversion in real life.
308
12
This study uses a recurrent survival
309
310
Table 1. Summary Statistics of Covariates
Excluding Two Outliers
Variable
X1
X2
X3
311
312
Total obs.
4497
4497
4497
Min.
-1.477
0.000
0.862
1st Q.
-0.289
0.000
1.795
Median
-0.189
0.000
1.911
3rd Q.
0.0163
0.000
2.229
Max
Mean
25.47 10.437
7.494 0.088
2.649 1.985
Std
40.486
0.474
0.307
Note. X1 is the standardized difference between the conversion price and stock price; X2 is the dividend;
X3 is the risk-free interest rate.
313
13
314
Table 2. Distribution of Lifespans
Duration in
Months
1-5
6-10
11-15
16-20
21-25
26-30
31-35
36-40
41-45
46-50
51-55
56-60
315
316
Frequecy
1
3
11
11
17
10
15
17
12
4
2
25
Cumulative
Frquency%
0.78%
3.13%
11.72%
20.31%
33.59%
41.41%
53.13%
66.41%
75.78%
78.91%
80.47%
100.00%
Note. The two outliers of the N=130 sample bonds
are excluded.
317
14
318
319
Table 3. Distribution of Conversion Times
Duration in
Months
1-2
3-4
5-6
7-8
9-10
11-12
13-14
15-16
17-18
19-20
21-22
23-24
25-26
27-28
31-32
320
321
Frequecy
2
6
7
20
17
12
21
11
9
9
5
2
4
1
1
Cumulative
Frequency%
1.57%
6.30%
11.81%
27.56%
40.94%
50.39%
66.93%
75.59%
82.68%
89.76%
93.70%
95.28%
98.43%
99.21%
100.00%
Note. The two outliers of the N=130 sample bonds
are excluded.
322
323
324
325
326
327
15
328
329
Table 4. Analysis of AG Model
I. AG model without frailty
j
s.e.
X1
0.4376
0.0276
2value
d.f.
251.8
1
0.00000
p-value
X2
-0.0517
0.0312
2.75
1
0.09710
X3
-0.3144
0.1268
6.15
1
0.01321
3
0.00000
LRT
239.2
II. AG model with frailty
j
s.e.
2value
d.f.
X1
0.4339
0.0285
232.2
1
0.00000
X2
-0.0764
0.0322
5.61
1
0.01800
X3
-0.2924
0.1338
4.78
1
0.02900

0.1120
--
166.7
72.9
0.00000
75.8
0.00000
2
LRT
487.0
p-value
330
Note. LRT is the likelihood ratio of H0: 1=2=3 vs.
331
332
H1: Not all js are zeros.  2 is the common variance of the
N frailties  1 , …,  N .
333
334
16
335
336
Table 5. Analysis of PWP Model
I. First stratification scheme without frailty
j
se
2value
d.f.
p-value
X1
0.3667
0.0287
163.70
1
0.00000
X2
-0.0635
0.0318
3.99
1
0.04570
X3
-0.2893
0.1269
5.20
1
0.02260
3
0.00000
d.f.
p-value
LRT
161.5
II. First stratification scheme with frailty
j
se
2value
X1
0.3867
0.0294
172.69
1
0.00000
X2
-0.0708
0.0324
4.79
1
0.02900
X3
-0.2354
0.1338
3.10
1
0.07800
0.0706
--
57.5
0.00016
60.4
0.00000

2
LRT
104.13
313.0
III. Second stratification scheme without frailty
j
se
2value
d.f.
p-value
X1
0.4110
0.0285
207.79
1
0.00000
X2
-0.0651
0.0315
4.26
1
0.03900
X3
-0.3747
0.1285
8.51
1
0.00353
3
0.00000
d.f.
p-value
LRT
204.1
IV. Second stratification scheme with frailty
j
se
2value
X1
0.4362
0.0294
220.92
1
0.00000
X2
-0.0796
0.0328
5.89
1
0.01500
X3
-0.2755
0.1377
4.00
1
0.04500
 2
0.1750
260.65
85.6
0.00000
88.5
0.00000
LRT
-482.0
337
Note. LRT is the likelihood ratio of H0: 1=2=3 vs. H1: Not all js are
338
zeros.  2 is the common variance of the N frailties  1 , …,  N .
339
340
341
17
342
343
344
345
346
347
348
349
350
351
352
353
354
355
356
357
358
359
360
361
References
Allison, P.D. (2010) Survival Analysis Using the SAS System: A Practical Guide. Second Edition.
Cary, NC: SAS Institute.
Asquith, P., and Mullins, D.W. (1991) Convertible debt: Corporate call policy and voluntary
conversion, Journal of Finance 46, 1273-1289.
Andersen, P. K. and Gill, R. D. (1982) Cox’s regression model for counting processes: a large sample
study, Annals of Statistics, 10, 1100-1120.
Brennan, M. J., and Schwartz, E. S. (1977) Convertible bonds: Valuation and optimal strategies for
call and conversion, The Journal of Finance 32, 1699-1716.
Brennan, M. J., and Schwartz, E. (1980) Analyzing convertible bonds, Journal of Financial and
Quantitative Analysis, 15, 4, 907–929.
Box-Steffensmeir, J. M. and Zorn, C. J. W. (2002) Duration Models for Repeated Events.
Journal
of Politics 64.
Box-Steffensmeir, J. M. and Boef, S.D. (2006) Repeated events survival models: The conditional
frailty model, Statistics in Medicine, 25, 3518-3533.
Bühler, W. and Koziol, C. (2004) Valuation of convertible bonds with sequential conversion,
Schmalenbach Business Review, 54, 302-334.
Clayton D. (1994) Some approaches to the analysis of recurrent event data. Statistical Methods in
Medical Research , 3, 3, 244 –262.
Clayton, D. G. and Cuzick, J. (1985) Multivariate generalizations of the proportional hazards model
362
(with discussion), Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B, 148, 82-117.
363
364
365
366
367
368
369
370
Constantinides,G.M. (1984) Optimal stock trading with personal taxes: Implications for prices and
371
372
373
374
375
376
377
378
Emanuel, David C. (1983), Warrant Valuation and Exercise Strategy, Journal of Financial
the abnormal January returns Journal of Financial Economics, 13(1), 65-89.
Cook, R.J., and Lawless, J.F. (2002) Analysis of repeated events. Statistical Methods in Medical
Research , 11, 141-166.
Cox, D. R. (1972) Regression models and life-tables (with discussion), Journal of the Royal
Statistical Society, Series B, 34, 187-222.
Duchateau L, Janssen P, Kezic I, and Fortpied, C. (2003) Evolution of recurrent asthma event rate
over time in frailty models. Applied Statistics, 52, 355-363.
Economics, 12, 211-235.
Gray, R.J. (1992) Flexible methods for analyzing survival data using splines, with applications to
breast cancer prognosis. Journal of the American Statistical Association 87, 942-951.
Green, R. (1984) Investment incentives, debt, and warrants, Journal of Financial Economics 13,
115-136.
Ingersoll, J. E. (1977) A contingent-claims valuation of convertible securities, Journal of Financial
Economics 4, 289-321.
18
379
380
381
382
383
384
385
386
387
388
389
390
391
392
393
394
395
396
397
398
399
400
401
402
403
404
405
406
407
Kelly P.J., Lim L.L. (2000) Survival analysis for recurrent event data: an application to childhood
infectious disease. Statistics in Medicine, 19, 1, 13-33.
Lee, C.F., Lee, K.W. and Yeo, G. (2009) Investor protection and convertible debt design, Journal of
Banking & Finance 33, 985–995.
Lewis, M., Rogalski, R., and Seward, J., (2003) Industry conditions, growth opportunities and market
reactions to convertible debt financing decisions. Journal of Banking and Finance 27, 153–181.
Mayers, D. (1998) Why firms issue convertible bonds: the matching of financial and real investment
options, Journal of Financial Economics 47, 83-102.
Nielsen, G. G., Gill, R. D., Andersen, P. K. and Sørensen, T. I. A. (1992) A counting process
approach to maximum likelihood estimation in frailty modelsÕ, Scandinavian Journal of Statistics,
19, 25-43.
Prentice, R. L., Williams, B. J. and Peterson, A.V. (1981) On the regression analysis of multivariate
failure time data, Biometrika, 68, 373-379.
Schaubel, D.E., and Cai, J. (2005) Analysis of clustered recurrent event data with application to
hospitalization rates among renal failure patients. Biostatistics, 6, 404-419.
Sirbu, M., and Shreve, S. (2006). A two-person game for pricing convertible bonds. SIAM J. Control
Optimization, 45, 4, 1508–1539
Therneau, T. M. and Grambsch, P.M. (2000) Modeling Survival Data: Extending the Cox Model.
Statistics for Biology and Health New York: Springer–Verlag.
Wei, L. J., Lin, D. Y. and Weissfeld, L. (1989) Regression analysis of multivariate incomplete failure
time data by modeling marginal distributions, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 84,
1065-1073.
Wei, L. J., Ying, Z. and Lin, D. Y. (1990) Linear regression analysis of censored survival data based
on rank tests, Biometrika, 77, 845-851.
Wei LJ, and Glidden, D.V. (1997) An overview of statistical methods for multiple failure time data in
clinical trials. Statistics in Medicine, 16, 8, 883–939.
19
Download