Financial Analysis, Planning and Forecasting Theory and Application Chapter 6 Valuation and Capital Structure: Theory and application By Alice C. Lee San Francisco State University John C. Lee J.P. Morgan Chase Cheng F. Lee Rutgers University 1 Outline 6.1 Introduction 6.2 Bond valuation 6.3 Common-stock valuation 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS 6.5 Degree of financial leverage and combined effect 6.6 Optimal capital structure 6.7 Summary and remarks Appendix 6A. Derivation of Dividend Discount Model Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML Appendix 6C. Convertible security valuation theory 2 6.1 Introduction Components of capital structure Opportunity cost, required rateof-return, and the cost of capital 3 6.1 Introduction E ( R j ) R f ( E ( Rm ) R f ) j , (6.1) where E ( Rj ) = Expected rate of return for asset j, R f = Return on a risk-free asset, ( E ( Rm ) R f ) = Market risk premium, or the difference in return on the market as a whole and the return on a risk-free asset, j = Beta coefficient for the regression of an individual’s security return on the market return; the volatility of the individual security’s return relative to the market return. 4 6.2 Bond valuation Perpetuity Term bonds Preferred stock 5 6.2 Bond valuation n CFt PV , t t 1 (1 kb ) (6.2) where n = Number of periods to maturity, CFt = Cash flow (interest and principal) received in period t, kb = Required rate-of-return for bond. 6 6.2 Bond valuation CF PV . kb (6.3) n It P PV , (6.4) t n (1 kb ) t 1 (1 kb ) where It = Coupon payment, coupon rate X face value, p = Principal amount (face value) of the bond, n = Number of periods to maturity. 7 6.2 Bond valuation TABLE 6.1 Convertible bond: conversion options Advantages Purchase Price Of Bond Gain (1) Conversion to stock if price rises above $25. $1000 Sell 40 shares at $30, = $1,200, for a return of 12%. (2)Interest payment if stock price remains less than $25. $1000 $100 per year, for a return of 10% (3)Interest payment versus stock dividend. Dividend must rise to $2.50 per share before return on stock = 10%. The results in this table are based on a $1000 face-value bond with 10% coupon rate, convertible to 40 shares of stock at $25 each. 8 6.2 Bond valuation PV dp kp , (6.5) where dp = Fixed dividend payment, coupon X par on face value of preferred stock; kp = Required rate-of-return on the preferred stock. 9 6.3 Common-stock valuation Valuation Inflation and common-stock valuation Growth opportunity and common-stock valuation 10 6.3 Common-stock valuation d1 d2 Pn Po , 2 n (1 k ) (1 k ) (1 k ) (6.6a) where P0 = Present value, or price, of the common stock per share, dt = Dividend payment, k = Required rate of return for the stock, assumed to be a constant term, Pn = Price of the stock in the period when 11 sold. 6.3 Common-stock valuation dt Pn . t t n 1 (1 k ) P0 dt t 1 (1 k ) t , d1 P0 . (k g n ) (6.6b) (6.6c) 12 6.3 Common-stock valuation d 0 (1 g s ) t d n 1 1 P0 , (6.7) t n (1 k ) ( r g n ) (1 k ) t 1 n where gs = Growth rate of dividends during the super-growth period, n = Number of periods before super-growth declines to normal, gn = Normal growth rate of dividends after the end of the super-growth phase, 13 r = Internal rate-of-return. 6.3 Common-stock valuation dt pEPSt where dt = Dividend payment per share in period t, p = Proportion of earnings paid out in dividends (the payout ratio, 0 p 1.0), EPSt = earnings per share in period t. 14 6.3 Common-stock valuation p(Qt ( Pt Vt ) Ft)(1 ) dt N (6.8) Where Qt = Quantity of product sold in period t, Pt = Price of the product in period t, Vt = Variable costs in period t, F = Depreciation and interest expenses in period t, = Firm tax rate. 15 6.3 Common-stock valuation dt p{(inflows)t (1 i )t (outflows)t (1 0 )t }(1 ) t (1 k ) (1 k )t (6.8a) where (1 K ) (1 k )(1 ), Anticipate d annual inflation risk , i Anticipate d annual inflation rate in the cash inflows , 0 Anticipate d annual inflation rate in the cash outflows , (inflows) t Pt Qt , and (outflows) t QtVt Ft . The equation (6.8) is related to operating-income hypothesis which has been discussed in chapter 5 on pages 158-160. 16 6.3 Common-stock valuation X0 V0 k b( r k ) 1 , k br (6.9) where X 0 = Current expected earnings per share, b = Investment (It) as a percentage of total earnings (Xt), r = Internal rate of return V0 and k = Current market value of a firm and the required rate of return, respectively. 17 6.3 Common-stock valuation X 0 (1 b) D1 V0 , k br kg d1 P0 . kg (6.9a) (6.9b) 18 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS 6.4.1 Measurement 6.4.2 Effect 19 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS D k e r (r i ) E (6.10) where ke = Return on equity, r = Return on total assets (return on equity without leverage) i = Interest rate on outstanding debt, D = Outstanding debt, E = Book value of equity. 20 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS rA iD ke , E (6.11) D ke r ( r i ) , E (6.10a) D Mean of ( ke ) ke r (r i ) , E (6.12a) 21 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS 2 D Variance of (ke ) 1 Var(r ) . E [(rA iD) (rA iD)] ke , E D ke r (r i ) (1 ). E (6.12b) (6.10b) (6.13) 22 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS ~ ~ ~ D k e r (r i ) (1 ). E ~ D Mean (k ) k e r ( r i ) (1 ) E (6.14) (6.15a) 2 ~ D 2 Var (k e ) (1 ) 1 Var (~ r) E (6.15b) 23 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS (rA iD ( rA iD )) EPS , N E h , N D EPS r ( r i ) (1 )h E (6.16) (6.17) (6.18a) 24 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS 2 D Var(EPS) h (1 ) 1 Var ( ~ r ). E 2 2 EPS r (1 )h (6.18b) (6.18c) 2 D Var(EPS) (1 ) h 1 Var (~ r ). E 2 2 (6.18d) 25 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS Figure 6.1 26 6.4 Financial leverage and its effect on EPS Standard Deviation of EPS r [1 ( D / E )] CVEPS Mean(EPS) r ( r i )( D / E ) H 1, H 1, D 1 r if E 1 r i D 1 r if E 1 r i (6.19) (6.20) k (18% (18% 15%)( 0. 6))( 0.5) 9. 9%, k (1 0.5)(1 0. 6)(2%) 1. 6%. 27 6.5 Degree of financial leverage and combined effect EPS/EPS EBIT , EBIT/EBIT EBIT iD (6.21) Q( P V ) F DFL Q( P V ) F iD (6.22) CLE DFL DOL, Q( P V ) Combined Leverage Effect (CLE) , Q( P V ) F iD (6.23) 28 6.5 Degree of financial leverage and combined effect Q( P V ) DOL , Q( P V ) F Q( P V ) F DFL , Q( P V ) F iD Q( P V ) CLE . Q( P V ) F iD 29 6.6 Optimal capital structure Overall discussion Arbitrage process and the proof of M&M Proposition I 30 6.6.1 Overall Discussion ij it, X jt ) Cov(X ( X it ) ( X jt ) Cov( CX it , X jt ) C ( X it ) ( X jt ) 1, it X it 1 X Rit , X i ,t 1 CX jt CX jt 1 R jt Rit CX jt 1 31 6.6 Optimal capital structure V j ( S j Dj ) V L j (1 j ) X j kj Xj jIj Sj V jU j D j . r ( r ) D j , , (6.24) (6.25) (6.26) 32 6.6 Optimal capital structure kj Sj (1 j ) [ r ] D j Sj , (6.27) s2 Y2 ( X 2 rD2 ) 2 ( X rD2 ), (6.28) D2 S2 s1 Y1 X 1 1 X , S1 (6.29) 33 6.6 Optimal capital structure Y1 1 ( S2 D2 ) S1 V2 X r1 D2 1 X rD2 . (6.30) V1 s2 Y2 ( X rD2 ) rd S2 s1 D2 ( X rD2 ) r V2 V2 s1 (6.31) s1 s1 X 1 X , V2 V2 34 6.6 Optimal capital structure TABLE 6.2 Valuation of two companies in accordance with Modigliani and Miller’s Proposition 1 Initial Disequilibrium Total Market Value ( V j ) Debt ( D j ) Equity ( S j ) Expected Net Operating Income ( X ) Interest (rj D j ) Net Income ( X r D ) j j Cost of Common Equity ( k j ) W1 D j V j W2 S j V j Average Cost of Capital ( p j ) Final Equilibrium Company 1 Company 2 Company 1 Company 2 $500 0 500 $600 300 300 $550 0 550 $550 300 250 50 0 50 50 21 29 50 0 50 50 21 29 10.00% 0 1 9.67% 11.6% 1 2 9.09% 0 1 10.00% 8.34% 9.09% 9.09% 1 2 6 11 5 11 35 6.6 Optimal capital structure C PS ( 1 )( 1 j j ) L U V j V j 1 D j , PD 1 j (6.32) (1 Cj )(1 PS j C 1 j PD (1 j ) 1 Cj ) Dj. 1 PD (1 j ) r0 r0 rs rd , C PD 1 j 1 j (6.33) (6.34) 36 6.6 Optimal capital structure Fig. 6.2 Aggregated supply and demand for corporate bonds (before tax rates). From Miller, M., “Debt and Taxes,” The Journal of Finance 29 (1977): 261-275. Reprinted by permission. 37 6.6 Optimal capital structure X (1 C )( X R ) R (1 C ) X C R (1 C ) X Z C R , (6.35) Var ( X ) Var [( X C R ) Z C R ] CR C Var X 1 Z R X (6.36) 2 C R ( X ) 1 . X 2 z 38 6.6 Optimal capital structure Y U m U V C (1 ) XZ , (6.37) m C Y L [(1 ) XZ ]. C L (6.38) ( S (1 ) D ) L S (1 ) D S D D V D V . L C L L L C L L C L U 39 6.6 Possible Reason for Optimal Capital Structure • • • The traditional Approach of Optimal Capital Structure Bankruptcy Cost Agency Cost 40 Possibility of Optimal Debt Ratio when Bankruptcy Allowed 41 6.7 Summary and remarks In this chapter the basic concepts of valuation and capital structure are discussed in detail. First, the bond-valuation procedure is carefully discussed. Secondly, common-stock valuation is discussed in terms of (i) dividend-stream valuation and (ii) investment-opportunity valuation. It is shown that the first approach can be used to determine the value of a firm and estimate the cost of capital. The second method has decomposed the market value of a firm into two components, i.e., perpetual value and the value associated with growth opportunity. The criteria for undertaking the growth opportunity are also developed. An overall view on the optimal capital structure has been discussed in accordance with classical, new classical, and some modern finance theories. Modigliani and Miller’s Proposition I with and without tax has been reviewed in detail. It is argued that Proposition I indicates that a firm should use either no debt or 100 percent debt. In other words, there exists no optimal capital structure for a firm. However, both classical and some of the modern theories demonstrate that there exists an optimal capital structure for a firm. In summary, the results of valuation and optimal capital structure will be useful for financial planning and forecasting. 42 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory j m Pt t 1 rF (1 ) [( P0 F )( n m)] F (1 ki ) t (1 ki ) j m (6.A.1) where P = Market value of the convertible bond, r = Coupon rate on the bond, F = Face value of the bond, P0 = Initial market value, ki = Effective rate of interest on the bond at the end of the period m (now), n = Original maturity of the bond, m = Number of periods since the bond was issued, j = Number of periods from the time the bond was issued till the time of conversion, F’= Value of the stock on date of conversion, t = Marginal corporate tax rate. 43 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory Fig. 6.A.1 Hypothetical model of a convertible years’ bond. (From Brigham, E. F. “An analysis of convertible debentures: theory and some empirical evidence,” Journal of Finance 21 (1966), p. 37) Reprinted by permission. 44 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory C max(Cs , Cb ), Cs ps B / ps 0 Cb B B / ps (6.A.2) f (i, t0 )[ B i (t ) ps ]di (t ), (6.A.2a) f (i, t0 )[i (t ) ps B ]di (t ), (6.A.2b) B / ps 0 0 C i (t ) psf (i, t0 )di (t ) f (i, t0 )[ B i(t ) ps ]di (t ), (6.A.3) 45 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory E ( P) 0 E ( P) 0 x y x y 0 h dx yxh dx g ( y ) dy, y y y x y 0 h dx y xh( x, y)dx dy, y (6.A.4) (6.A.4′) y E ( P ) xh( x, y )dx ( y x )h( x, y )dx dy , 0 0 0 (6.A.5) Expecte d stock v alue Value of floor guarantee E ( P ) yg ( y )dy ( x y )h( x, y )dxdy, 0 0 y Expected straightdebt value Expected value of the conversion option (6.A.6) 46 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory 0 y E ( P ) yg ( y )dy ( x y ) f ( x )dx, y E (CB) yh ( x )dx xb( x )dx, 0 (6.A.6′) y x a Beta 1 , m x (6.A.7) (6.A.8) 47 Appendix 6A. Convertible security valuation theory E en ( i ( t )) CB a a 1 2 x e (1 / 2 )[( x x ) / x ]2 dx (6.A.9) x a 1 2 x e (1 / 2 )[( x x ) / x ]2 dx. G (V , ; B , c, ) F (V , ; B , c,) W ( V , ; B ), (6.A.10) H (V , ) F (V , ; B , c) W ( V , ; B ) Z F ( V , ; B / , c)], 2 ( r p )/ 2 [ F ( V , ; B , c) (6.A.11) 48 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML I. DOL II. DFL III. DCL (degree of combined leverage) 49 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML I. DOL Let Sales = P×Q′ EBIT = Q (P – V) – F Q′ = new quantities sold The definition of DOL can be defined as: DOL (Degree of operating leverage) Percentage Change in Profits Percentage Change in Sales EBIT EBIT Sales Sales {[Q ( P V ) F ] [Q( P V ) F ]} Q ( P V ) F ( P Q P Q) ( P Q) Q ( P V ) Q( P V ) Q ( P V ) F P (Q Q) P Q (Q Q)( P V ) [Q ( P V ) F ] P(Q Q) P Q 50 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML I. DOL (Q Q) ( P V ) Q (P V ) F P Q P (Q Q) Q (P V ) Q (P V ) F Q (P V ) F F Q (P V ) F F Q (P V ) F Q (P V ) F Q (P V ) F 1 F Q (P V ) F 1 Fixed Costs Profits 51 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML II. DFL Let i = interest rate on outstanding debt (or iD = interest payment on debt ) D = outstanding debt N = the total number of shares outstanding τ = corporate tax rate EAIT = [Q(P – V)– F– iD] (1–τ) The definition of DFL can be defined as: 52 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML II. DFL DFL (Degree of financial leverage) EPS EPS (EAIT N ) (EAIT N ) EBIT EBIT EBIT EBIT EAIT EAIT EBIT EBIT [Q( P V ) F iD](1 ) [Q( P V ) F iD](1 ) [Q( P V ) F iD](1 ) [Q( P V ) F ] [Q( P V ) F ] [Q( P V ) F ] 53 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML II. DFL [Q( P V )](1 ) [Q( P V )](1 ) [Q( P V ) F iD ](1 ) [Q( P V )] [Q( P V )] [Q( P V ) F ] [ (Q Q)( P V ) ] (1 ) Q( P V ) F [Q( P V ) F iD ] (1 ) (Q Q)( P V ) Q( P V ) F Q( P V ) F iD EBIT EBIT iD 54 Appendix 6B. Derivation of DOL, DFL, and CML III. DCL (degree of combined leverage) = DOL × DFL Q( P V ) F Q( P V ) Q( P V ) Q( P V ) F Q( P V ) F iD Q( P V ) F iD 55 Appendix 6C. Derivation of Dividend Discount Model I. Summation of infinite geometric series II. Dividend Discount Model 56 Appendix 6C. Derivation of Dividend Discount Model S = A + AR + AR2 + … + ARn −1 (6.C.1) RS = AR + AR2 + … + ARn −1 + ARn (6.C.2) S − RS = A − ARn 57 Appendix 6C. Derivation of Dividend Discount Model A(1 R ) S 1 R n (6.C.3) S∞ = A + AR + AR2 +…+ ARn −1 +…+ AR∞, (6.C.4) A S 1 R (6.C.5) 58 Appendix 6C. Derivation of Dividend Discount Model D3 D1 D2 P0 (6.C.6) 2 3 1 k 1 k 1 k D1 D1 (1 g ) D1 (1 g )2 P0 2 3 1 k 1 k 1 k or D1 D1 (1 g ) D1 (1 g ) P0 2 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 k 1 k 2 (6.C.7) D1 (1 k ) D1 (1 k ) P0 1 [(1 g ) (1 k )] [1 k (1 g ) (1 k )] D0 (1 g ) D1 (1 k ) D1 (k g ) (1 k ) (k g ) kg 59