WTO’s Doha round in an era of high food prices Kym Anderson University of Adelaide, Australia Review session for Ch. 3 of the Monterrey Consensus, on International Trade as an Engine for Development United Nations, New York, 19 May 2008 Four key points Cost of trade distortions, esp. in agriculture, is very high, and esp. for developing countries including from DCs’ own policies Agric under GATT has been difficult politically to reform, because of fluctuating and falling real world prices for food during past 60 years To keep domestic food price stable, many govts. sought to insulate and increasingly protect farmers from international market forces • which makes the int’l market even less attractive to other countries, who follow suit Four key points (continued) We have suddenly entered a new era of higher int’l food prices that may be prolonged offering a fresh opportunity to reform agricultural policies under WTO’s DDA But for there to be sustained benefits, DDA’s agric negotiations have to be both ambitious and with minimal exceptions 1. Cost of trade protection policies is very high Global cost of 2004 tariffs on all goods plus agricultural subsidies: $287 billion per year plus cost of services regulations (so >$600 billion?) As % of GDP, cost to developing countries is 1/3rd higher than to high-income countries and nearly twice as high for Sub-Saharan Africa These costs (which are lower-bound estimates) are potential gains from trade liberalization Sources of cost to global economy Agric & food Textiles clothing Other merch. TOTAL High-income countries 135 15 9 159 (55%) Developing countries 47 23 58 128 (45%) 182 (63%) 38 (14%) $ billion due to policies in: All countries’ policies 67 287 (23%) (100%) Sources of cost to developing countries $billion due to policies in: Agric & food Textiles & clothing Other merch. TOTAL High-income countries (50%) Developing countries (50%) All countries’ policies (63%) (25%) (12%) (100%) 2. Real international food price trend and fluctuations, 1900-2005 180 160 1900-2005: -0.8% p.a. 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 Year 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Int’l prices in Jan-Feb 2008 (current US$) compared with Jan-Dec 2006 Source: World Bank Grains Vegetable oils Petroleum Coal Urea fertilizer Phosphate rock (2006 = 1.0) 1.7 2.2 1.4 2.3 1.6 4.3 IFPRI’s 2008 projection of international prices to 2050, real relative to 2000 Reference case: Alternative cases: slight slowdown faster/slower in ag R&D growth ag R&D growth Rice 1.3 0.7/2.6 Wheat 1.8 0.8/4.8 Maize 1.6 0.5/6.5 Soybean 1.2 0.8/1.8 IFPRI’s real price projection to 2050 (continued) Reference case: Alternative cases: slight slowdown faster/slower in ag R&D growth ag R&D growth Beef 1.4 1.1/1.9 Sheepmeat 1.1 0.9/1.6 Pork 1.3 0.9/2.0 Poultry 1.2 0.8/1.9 3. Why is a new era of higher int’l food prices relevant to the DDA? Because commitments to lower bound agric tariffs and subsidies at WTO will be politically painless for at least several years Providing ample time for farmers and consumers to adjust 4. But care is needed if DDA benefits are to be sustained DDA’s agric negotiations have to be both ambitious and with minimal exceptions especially in increasing market access but also in domestic support in the case of cotton Relative importance of 3 agric pillars Agric Agric All agric Welfare Agric effects market domestic export policies from: access support subsidies % for: Developing countries World 109 1 -10 100 93 5 2 100 Relative importance of 3 agric pillars just for cotton Agric Agric All agric Welfare Agric effects market domestic export policies from: access support subsidies % loss for: SubSaharan Africa World 2 77 1 100 10 89 1 100 Key agricultural elements of DDA negotiations to watch Reductions in tariff and subsidy binding overhang Treatment of ‘sensitive’ & ‘special’ products (SSPs) Tariff cap, and whether it applies to SSPs Extent of Special and Differential Treatment (SDT) invoked by developing and least-developed countries in terms of their willingness to reform Our modelled Doha scenarios 75% tiered cut to bound agric tariffs • without & with sensitive products • without & with a tariff cap of 200% • with & without Special and Differential Treatment (SDT) 75% tiered cut to domestic ag subsidy ceilings Abolition of agric export subsidies 50%/33%/0% cut in bound non-agric tariffs Services policies unchanged Big cuts needed to reduce applied agric tariffs, because of “binding overhang” High-income countries Developing countries (excluding LDCs) Least developed countries (LDCs) Bound % Applied % 27 14 48 20 78 13 Also big cuts in domestic support limits needed to reduce DS binding overhang 70 Overhang 60 50 US proposal G-20 proposal 40 EU proposal 30 Applied 20 10 EU US Japan Korea Mexico Canada Doha scenarios: Percent gain in real income from Doha scenario as share of global trade reform High-income 50 Developing 40 30 20 10 0 Ag+NAMA-SDT Ag+NAMA Ag Only Ag-SSP+Cap Ag+NAMA-SDT—No exemptions, no caps, no SDT. Ag+NAMA—Same as above but includes SDT. Ag Only—Only agriculture, no exemptions, no caps, includes SDT. Ag-SSP+Cap—Same as above plus exemptions (HIC-2%, LMY-4%) and caps (200%). Ag-SSP—Same as above but no caps. Ag-SSP Final point: why does tariff binding, and hence reducing binding overhang, matter? Because in its absence governments can reverse reform and raise agric protection again Where would Japan and Korea’s agric tariffs be today if GATT had disciplined them when they joined (in 1955 and 1967)? -50 0 50 100 150 Will China and India follow NEAsia in raising their assistance to farmers? 7 8 9 Ln real GDP per capita China Japan Korea Taiwan 10 India Thanks! www.worldbank.org/trade/wto www.worldbank.org/agdistortions www.worldbank.org/WDR2008 kym.anderson@adelaide.edu.au