Fear, Greed, andFinancialCrises: ACognitiveNeurosciences Perspective* †AndrewW.Lo FirstDraft: August28,2011 LatestRevison: October12,2011 Abstract Historical accounts offinancial crises suggest that fearand greed arethe common denominators ofthese disruptive events: periods of unchecked greed eventually lead to excessive leverageandunsustainableasset-pricelevels,andtheinevitablecollapseresultsinunbridled fear, which must subside beforeanyrecovery is possible. Thecognitive neurosciences may providesomenewinsightsintothisboom/bustpatternthroughadeeperunderstandingof the dynamics ofemotion and human behavior. In this chapter, I describe some recent researchfromtheneurosciencesliteratureonfearandrewardlearning,mirrorneurons,theory ofmind,andthelinkbetweenemotionandrationalbehavior. Byexploringtheneuroscientificbasisofcognitionandbehavior, wemaybeabletoidentifymorefundamentaldrivers offinancialcrises,andimproveourmodelsandmethodsfordealingwiththem. *Prepared for J.P. Fouque and J. Langsam, eds., Handbook on Systemic Risk, Cambridge University Press. ResearchsupportfromtheMITLaboratoryforFinancialEngineeringisgratefullyacknowledged. I thank Jayna Cummings and Hersh Shefrin for helpful comments and discussion. The views and opinions expressedinthisarticlearethoseoftheauthoronlyanddonotnecessarilyrepresenttheviewsandopinions of AlphaSimplex Group, MIT, any of their affiliates oremployees, or any ofthe individuals acknowledged above. †Harris&HarrisGroupProfessor,MITSloanSchoolofManagement,andChiefInvestmentStrategist, AlphaSimplex Group, LLC. Please direct all correspondence to: Andrew W. Lo, MIT Sloan School of Management,100MainStreet,E62–618,Cambridge,MA02142. Contents 1 Introduction 1 2 A Brief Historyofthe Brain 4 3 Fear 7 4 Greed 12 5 Risk 17 6 Rationality 21 7 Sentience 28 8 Interactions 31 9 PolicyImplications 36 10Conclusion 39 References 44 1 Introduction InMarch1933,unemploymentintheUnitedStateswasatanall-timehigh. Over4,000banks hadfailedduringtheprevioustwomonths. Breadlinesstretchedaroundentireblocksinthe largest cities. The country was in the gripoftheGreatDepression. This was the context in which Franklin Delano Roosevelt delivered his first inaugural address to the American peopleasthe32ndpresidentoftheUnitedStates. Hebeganhisaddressnotbydiscussing economicconditions,norbylayingouthisproposalforthe“NewDeal”,butwithapowerful observation that still resonates today: “So, first of all, let me assert my firm belief that theonlythingwehavetofearisfearitself—nameless,unreasoning,unjustifiedterrorwhich paralyzesneededeffortstoconvertretreatintoadvance”. Seventy-five years later, these words have become more relevant than FDR could ever have imagined. The current set of crises—the bursting of the U.S. real-estate bubble, the unprecedentedhomeownerdefaultsandlossesbymajorfinancialinstitutionsthatsecuritized and leveraged these loans, the U.S. debt-ceiling debacle and political stalemate, and the European sovereign debt crisis—is, in essence, all about fear. Since money was invented, fortunes have always been made and lost by intrepid investors, but the current crisis feels different because of the sheer magnitude and complexity of the reported losses and the apparentrandomnessoftheirtimingandvictims. Fromanarrowperspective,fearsofinsolvencyinthebankingindustryinAugust2007, alongwith thesudden breakdown ofinterbank lending andshort-term financing, were the initialflashpointsofthecrisis. However,thesefearsweretriggeredbythenationaldecline in U.S. residential real estate which, in turn, caused mortgage-related securities such as collateralizeddebtobligations(CDOs)tolosevalueandbecomehighlyilliquid. Thefailure of large credit default swap (CDS) counterparties, the apparent inaccuracy of AAA bond ratings,regulatorylapsesandforbearance,politicaleffortstopromotethe“homeownership society”, andtheimplicitgovernment guaranteesofFannieMaeandFreddieMaccanalso becitedassignificantfactorsincreatingthecrisis. Althoughthe“blamegame”islikelyto continueforyearstocome, thefactthatnoprosecutionsorarrestshavebeenmadeinthe wakeofthecrisisof2007–2009suggeststhattherearenosimpleanswersastowhoorwhat wasresponsible. 1 But even a cursory review of expansive histories of past crises such as Kindleberger’s (1978) classic and Reinhart and Rogoff’s (2010) more recent definitive treatise suggests a common originforall financial bubbles andbusts: fearand greed. Aperiodofunchecked greed leads tounsustainable asset-price levels, andthe inevitable price decline ushers in a period of unbridled fear. The broader the participation in the growth of the bubble, the deepertheimpactontherealeconomybecauseofthenumberofhouseholdsaffectedbythe bubble’sbursting. Therelevanceofhumanbehaviortofinancialmarketsandeconomicaffairsisnotanew idea. JohnMaynardKeynes(1936)observedoversevendecadesagothateconomicdecisions were due more to “animal spirits” than carefully weighed probabilities, and that financial markets operated more like beauty contests than efficient price-discovery platforms. However,despitetheearlysuccesses ofKeynesianmacroeconomics,themorerecentdominance of the rational expectations school ofthought has left little roomfor animal spirits in the policymaker’s toolkit. Oneofthefewpositive consequences oftherecentfinancialcrisisis the realization that the current approach tomeasuring andmanaging systemic risk in the financialsystemisinadequate,andthatpolicymakersneedabroaderintellectualframework. Inthischapter,Ihopetoservethatneedbyexploringtheneuroscientificunderpinnings ofhumanbehavior,particularlythosebehaviorsmostrelevanttosystemicrisk. Iffearand greed are the key drivers of all financial crises, then a better understanding of how the brain produces these behaviors may eventually allow us to formulate more effective policiestomanagetheirconsequences. Forexample,neuroscientistshaveshownthatmonetary gain stimulates the same reward circuitry as cocaine—in both cases, dopamine is released intothenucleus accumbens. Similarly, thethreatoffinanciallossapparentlyactivatesthe samefight-or-flightresponseasaphysicalattack,releasingadrenalineandcortisolintothe bloodstream,resultinginelevatedheartrate,bloodpressure,andalertness. Thesereactions are hardwired into human physiology, and while we’re often able to overcome our biology througheducation,experience,orgeneticgoodluckduringnormalmarketconditions,under more emotionally charged circumstances, the vast majority of the human population will behaveinlargelypredictableways. ThisneurophysiologicalbasisforKeynes’sanimalspiritshasimportantimplicationsforregulatoryre form,includingtheneedforpath-dependent andadaptivecapitalrequirementsandleverageconstraints,moreaccurateandtimelymea2 suresofsystemicrisksoregulatorsandmarketparticipantscanrespondappropriately,and more direct feedback loopsbetween policies and outcomes thatwill enhance ourcollective intelligencethroughreinforcementlearning. Todevelopthiscognitiveneurosciencesperspectiveoffinancialcrises,IbegininSection 2 with a brief history of our understanding of the brain, which was surprisingly primitive until quite recently. Of course, the brain is extraordinarily complex, so by necessity we havetonarrowourfocustojustthosecomponentsthataremostrelevantforourpurposes: fear,greed(or,itsclosecomplement,pleasure),riskpreferences,rationality,andthevarious combinations of these elements. In Section 3, I describe fear learning and the amygdala, one of the most important neural components of financial crises. In Section 4, I turn to theneuralmechanisms mostcloselyassociatedwiththebuild-upofbubbles—pleasure and greed—andshowhowtheadaptivenessofneuralsystemsforrewardandpunishmentmakes crisesvirtuallyunavoidable. ThistendencyisspelledoutmoreclearlyinSection5,whichis devotedtotheeffectsofriskondecision-making,whichispredictableand,inthecaseofrogue traders,oftendisastrous. Toomuchemotioncantriggerirrationalbehavior,butsocantoo littleemotion,andinSection6,Idescribeadefinitionofrationalityfromtheneurosciences perspectivethat’sradicallydifferentfromtheeconomicnotionofrationalexpectations,the differencehingingcriticallyontheuniqueroleofemotion. ThemechanismsofSections3–6 allrefertoindividualbehavior,butinSection7,Iexploretheimpactofsocialinteractions throughtheneurophysiology ofmirrorneurons, braincells dedicated toallowing othersto “feelyourpain”. Alloftheseneuralcomponentsinteracttoproduceintentionsandactions, and in Section 8, I describe some properties of the “executive brain” in orchestrating the complexityofwhatweobserveashumanbehavior. Iconsiderthepublicpolicyimplications oftheneurosciencesperspectiveinSection9andarguethatoneofthemostimportantaspects of government and regulation is to protect ourselves from our own behavioral patterns by moderatingtheextremesoffearandgreed. IconcludeinSection10withsomethoughtson thepotentialrolethatthecognitiveneurosciencescanplayinfinancialeconomics. 3 2 A BriefHistoryoftheBrain Itseemsobviousthatabetterunderstandingofthebrainshouldleadtoabetterunderstandingofecon omicdecision-making. Ourownsubjectiveexperienceashumanbeingsstrongly suggeststhatwedon’talwaysactrationallyorinourownself-interest. Undertheinfluence of strong emotion or stress, or even for no reason we can consciously pinpoint, we’ve all madedecisionsthatwelaterregret. Inthetwenty-firstcentury,wenowknowthatthought takesplaceinthebrain,throughtheinterconnectionsofnerves,mediatedbychemicalsand electricity, even ifwe’reunsureoftheexactdetails. Itseems eminentlylogicalthenthata betterunderstandingofthebrainwouldnecessarily leadtoabetterunderstanding ofhow humans make economic decisions, just as a better understanding of the heart led William Harveytodiscoverhowthebloodflowsthroughthehumanbody. However, this understanding of the brain is a very new development in science. For decades, ifnot centuries, the study ofeconomics has been more highly advanced than the study of the brain. Adam Smith sought to explain human behavior in terms of our inner psychology, yet there was noway hecould measure themoralsentiments he soeloquently described. Aslateas1871,theBritisheconomistWilliamStanleyJevonscouldwrite: 1Farbeitfrommetosaythatweevershallhavethemeansofmeasuringdirectly thefeelingsofthehumanheart. Aunitofpleasureorofpainisdifficultevento conceive;butitistheamountofthesefeelingswhichiscontinuallypromptingus tobuyingandselling, borrowingandlending, labouringandresting, producing and consuming; and it is from the quantitative effects of the feelings that we mustestimatetheircomparativeamounts. Moderneconomicsemergedundertheassumptionthattheinternalprocessesleadingtoan economic decision could never be directly measured. This assumption led to the ideas of revealedpreferenceandutilitytheory,whichstillformthebedrockofmodernmicroeconomics today. Incomparison,thescientificstudyofthebrainwouldremainbackwardsforquitesome time. DuringJevons’s time, even theideathatnerves were composedofindependent cells wasstillindoubt. Thisissurprisingtoustoday,whenchildren’sbooksandprescriptiondrug commercials routinely contain illustrations of neurons, admittedly sometimes fanciful, and 1Jevons(1871,pp.13–14). 4 howtheywork. IttookthelaboratoryadvancesoftheItalianpathologistCamilloGolgiand the close observations ofthe Spanish pathologist Santiago Ram´on y Cajal to demonstrate the validity of the “neuron theory”, using state-of-the-artmicroscopic techniques fortheir time. Golgi and Ram´on y Cajal were quickly honored for their work, jointly winning the NobelPrizeinPhysiologyorMedicinein1906(althoughGolgihimselfwasnotabelieverin neurontheory)! 2In the same way, most scientists were skeptical that the brain contained specialized regions for different purposes until remarkably late in the scientific era. Today, we refer casuallyto“speechcenters”or“visualcenters”,anditisnaturalforustospeculateifthere isaparticularpartofthebrainwhichassesseseconomicvalueorfinancialrisk,butformuch ofthemodernera,thiswouldhavesoundedlikenonsensetoaneducatedperson. Thiscan beexplainedinpartbythesociologyofscience. Inthemid-eighteenthcentury,theSwedish philosopherEmanuelSwedenborgcorrectlydescribedthespecializednatureofthecerebral cortex,linkingitsstructuresofnervefiberstotheirfunction,butSwedenborgwasalsoknown forhisreligiouswritingsaboutdreamsandangels(thereisstillaSwedenborgChapelonthe Harvardcampus),andhishypothesiswasignoredfordecades.Meanwhile,thephysiologist Franz Joseph Gall also believed that different parts of the brain had different functions; however, he believed that these were reflected in the external shape ofthe skull. This led tothepseudoscienceofphrenology,throughwhichone’spersonalitycouldbedeterminedby examiningthebumpsonone’shead,atheorywhichwasquitepopularinthefirsthalfofthe nineteenthcentury. Eventually,thisdisciplinecameintodisrepute,creatingacertaindegree ofskepticism-by-associationfortheheterogeneousnatureofthebrain. Thisskepticismwasslowlyoverturnedinthenineteenthcentury,principallythroughthe study of individuals with brain tumors, lesions, or other head injuries. One of the most celebrated cases was of a young New Hampshire man named Phineas Gage, who had an iron rod pass under his upper jaw and through the topof his head during arock-blasting accidentintheconstructionoftheRutland&BurlingtonRailroadin1848. Gagesurvived andrecoveredfromthishorrificaccident—wellenoughtolaterbecomeastagecoachdriverin Chile!—buthispersonalityandhabitschangedmarkedly. Gage’scaseisespeciallyinteresting fromaneconomicpointofview. Inthewordsofhisdoctor,writingseveralyearsafterGage’s 2Finger(1994,pp.29–30). 5 3death,“Theequilibriumorbalance,sotospeak,betweenhisintellectualfacultiesandanimal propensities,seemstohavebeendestroyed”. Beforetheaccident,Gagewas“ashrewd,smart businessman, very energetic and persistent in executing all his plans of operation”. After the accident, however, Gage was “impatient of restraint or advice when it conflicts with hisdesires, attimespertinaciouslyobstinate,yetcapriciousandvacillating,devisingmany plansoffutureoperations,which arenosoonerarrangedthanthey areabandonedinturn forothersappearingmorefeasible”.Itwas asthoughanimportantcomponentofGage’s abilitytoplanaheadrationally hadbeenremovedalongwithpartofhisbrain. 4Asinterestingasthesehintstothebrain’sfunctionweretomedicalresearchers,theymade verylittleimpactonthefieldofeconomics. EvenJohnMaynardKeynes,withhisinterest inmedicalpsychologyandpsychiatry,couldonlyinvoke“animalspirits”asacharacteristic of human nature in 1936: “a spontaneous urge to action rather than inaction, and not as the outcome of a weighted average of quantitative benefits multiplied by quantitative probabilities”.5WhileKeynes’sanimalspiritsareanevocativemetaphoragainsttheconcept ofHomo economicus—rationaleconomic man—they sound fartooshaman-like to bevery satisfyingasanexplanationforhumanbehaviortoday. At the same time that neuroscience was developing a more detailed understanding of how the brain works, economic theory was becoming more narrowly focused on models of perfectly rational behavior, so much so that despite the intellectual merits of alternatives suchasHerbertSimon’s“satisficing”theoryofboundedrationality,themoremathematically sophisticated rational expectations school of thought pioneered by John Muth (1961) and RobertLucas(1972)quicklybecamethedominantperspectiveoftheeconomicsprofession inthe1960sand1970s. Themoreempirical,foundationalapproachofneurosciencehadlittle appealinthatclimate,anddespitethesubsequentexplosionofresultsinthebrainsciences, thetwofieldswouldhavelittletosaytoeachotheruntilthe1990s. 3Harlow(1868,1974). 4Keynes(1936;1960,p.161). 5Keynes himself took the term from the Scottish Enlightenment philosopher David Hume’s Enquiry ConcerningHumanUnderstanding. 6 3 Fear 6Several years ago, Robert Thompson, an airline pilot, stopped at a convenience store to pick up a few magazines, but he turned around and walked right out of the store that he just entered because he felt afraid, even though at the time he couldn’t understand why. It turned out the store was being robbed at gunpoint, and shortly after Thompson left, a police officer entered the store and was shot and killed. Only afterwards—with some thoughtful debriefing by Gavin de Becker, a public safety expert—did Thompson realize some of the things that may have triggered his discomfort: a customer wearing a heavy jacketdespitethehotweather,theclerk’sintensefocusonthatcustomer, andasinglecar with the engine running in the parking lot. But Thompson’s decision to leave the store camealmostinstantaneously,longbeforehewasevenawarethathehadobservedanything unusual. Fearoftheunknown—FDR’s“nameless,unreasoning,unjustifiedterror”—isoneofthe mostpowerful motivatingforces ofourconscious andsubconscious minds. Neuroscientists havedemonstratedwithremarkabledetailthatourfearcircuitryishighlyrefined,insome casesreactingmuchfasterthanwecanperceive. The“fightorflight”response, hardwired in all mammals, is just one example of the wonderful evolutionary mechanisms that have keptourspecies aliveforthepast100,000years. Butphysical threatsarenotthesameas financial threats, and while high blood pressure, dilated blood vessels in our muscles, and a rush of adrenaline may protect us from the former, they do little to shield us from the latter. Infact,sustainedemotionalstresshasbeenshowntoimpairrationaldecision-making abilities,leadingtosomewell-knownbehavioralbiasessuchas“doublingdown”ratherthan cuttinglosses, selling atthebottomandbuying backatthetop,andotherfinancialtraps thathaveconfoundedmostretailinvestorsandnotafewprofessionaltraders. 7Todevelopadeeperunderstandingofhowfearworks,wehavetolookinsidethehuman brain, perhaps the most complicated structure known to science. Most estimates put the numberofneuronsinthebrainataroundonehundredbillion,notcountingthemanyother important cell types found there.Each neuron can have several thousand synapses send6SeedeBecker(1997,p.27–28). 7See Williams and Herrup (1988). Of course, this is only an “order of magnitude” estimate: the total numberhasneverbeenphysicallycounted. 7 ingsignalstoothercells, forminganincredibly dense network ofinterconnections between neurons. Incomparison, thenumber ofhuman beings thathave ever lived is estimated to be substantially less than one hundred billion. If the average person throughout history only made afew hundred personal connections in his orher lifetime (asseems likely), the extended social network of everyone who has ever lived is still much less complex than a singlehumanbrain. The brain is not only complicated, but also extremely difficult to examine while functioning. It is, in effect, what the mathematician Norbert Wiener called a “black box”, by which he meant not an airplane’s flight-data recorder (those are brightly colored orange, incidentally),butanopaquesystemwhereonecanonlyexaminetheinputsandtheoutputs. Formanyyears,informationonhowtheblackboxfunctionedinternallywasscarce. Brain researcherscouldonlyrelyonevidencefrompost-mortemneuroanatomy,casestudiesafter brain surgery or other head injuries like Phineas Gage, and rather distressing “ablation” experiments—in whichregionsofthebrainareselectively destroyed surgicallytosee what theimpactis—performedonrats,monkeys,andothercreatures,undertheassumptionthat brainfunctionsaresimilarinevolutionarilyrelatedspecies. 8Onesuchexperimenttookplacein1937,theyearafterKeynesmadehispronouncement about“animalspirits”. Tworesearchers, theGerman´emigr´epsychologist Heinrich Kl¨uver andtheAmericanneurosurgeonPaulBucy,wereattemptingtodiscoverwhichareasofthe brain were involved in the visual hallucinations caused by mescaline, the active chemical compoundinpeyotecactus. Inonesetofexperiments,Bucyremovedthetemporallobesof the lateralcerebral cortex ofrhesus monkeys (inhumans, this part ofthe brain is slightly aboveandbehindtheears). Kl¨uverandBucydiscoveredsomethingstartling: themonkeys’ ability to see was not impaired, but their ability to recognize objects was. “The hungry animal,ifconfrontedwithavarietyofobjects,will,forexample,indiscriminatelypickupa comb,aBakeliteknob,asunflowerseed,ascrew,astick,apieceofapple,alivesnake,apiece ofbanana,andaliverat. Eachobjectistransferredtothemouthandthendiscardedifnot edible”. Atthesametime,themonkeysalsolosttheirsenseoffear,behavingcalmlyinthe presenceofhumansandsnakes. Kl¨uverandBucycalledthisbehavior“psychicblindness”. Themonkeysapparentlysufferednolossofvisualacuity,butwhattheysawhadlosttheset 8Kl¨uverandBucy(1937). 8 Kl¨uver-Bucysyndromewaslaterfoundinhumans,althoughitisveryrare. ofemotionalandphysicalassociationstheypreviouslyconveyed. Thiswasaremarkableresult—aparticularpartofthebrainwasresponsibleformediating theemotionalresponsetorecognizinganobject. Weliveinaworldwhereimagerecognition bycomputersisbecomingmorecommonbytheday,andwetendtothinkofitasanunemotional,purel yrationalact. Itwouldbedisconcerting,tosaytheleast,ifwediscoveredthat thesoftwareprocessingphotographsoflicenseplatenumbersinspeedtrapshademotion-like responsesbasedonthenumbersitrecognized—butthat’sexactlywhatoccursinthebrain! Infact,thebrainappearstohaveseveralpathwaysthatmediateemotion. Kl¨uverandBucy had fortuitously removed the part of the brain essential for linking memories to fear: the amygdala. Theamygdalaisasmallbutdistinctstructurelocateddeepwithinthebrain. Inhumans, it is located roughly where a line entering one’s eye and a line entering one’s ear would intersect. Like most brain structures, the amygdala is paired. Early anatomists thought itresembled an almond, hence its name, amygdala (the Latinized formofthe Greek word for“almond”). ResearchersfollowinginKl¨uverandBucy’sfootstepssuspectedthatitwas involvedinhowthebrainlearnedfear. Itwasnotuntilthelate1970s,however,whenthefirst neurophysiological studies used the technique offearconditioning toexamine thefunction oftheamygdala. Even though it’s over a century old, many people know the story of Pavlov and his dogs: theRussianscientistwouldringabellwhilefeedinghisdogs,andthedogsbecameso conditionedtothesoundofthebellthattheywouldstillsalivatewhenPavlovranghisbell, eveniftheyweren’tfed. Fearconditioninginvolvesreplacingtheunconditionedstimulus—in Pavlov’sexperiments,food—withanegativestimulussuchasanelectricshock. Conditioned fearlearningismuchfasterthanotherformsoflearning. Itcantakeplaceeveninasingle sessionoflinkedstimuli,andcomparedtootherformsoflearning,itisnearlyindelible. There aresoundevolutionaryreasonsforthisasymmetry, andthesamekindoffearconditioning hasbeenfoundthroughouttheanimalkingdom,notmerelyinmammals. 9In1979,BruceKappandhisteamattheUniversityofVermontfirstpublishedevidence thatlesionsonthecentralnucleusoftheamygdaladisruptedfearconditioninginrabbits. Inspired bythiswork, JosephLeDoux(thenatCornellUniversity MedicalCollegeinNew 9Kapp(1979). 9 10YorkCity;nowatNewYorkUniversity’sCenterforNeuralScience),setouttotraceexactly how a fear-conditioned stimulus was processed by the brain. In his book The Emotional Brain, LeDoux recounts how he discovered that pathway, or as he puts it, “the road map offear“.LeDoux made lesions in thebrains ofrats conditioned to fearaspecific sound, workingbackwardsalongtheknownpathwaysforauditoryprocessing. LeDouxwrites,“My approachwastoletthenaturalflowofinformationbemyguide...Ireasonedthatdamaging theearwouldbeuninteresting,sinceadeafanimalisobviouslynotgoingtobeabletolearn anythingaboutasound. So,instead,Istartedbydamagingthehighestpartsoftheauditory pathway”. It turned out that damaging the higher auditory functions in the cortex—the ‘rind’ of the brain—had no effect on fear conditioning. Damaging the auditory thalamus furtherindid. ThisposedapuzzleforLeDoux: wheredidtheroadmapoffearlead,ifnot alongthestandardauditorypathway? Tofindtheanswer,LeDouxinjectedaspecialchemicaltracerintotheauditorythalamus. Theneuronsthereabsorbedthetracerandsentthechemicaldownthelongthinconnections oftheaxonstothenextstageofthepathway. Thebrainswerethensectionedandstainedto determinewherethetracerendedup: “Brightorangeparticlesformedstreamsandspeckles against a dark-blue background. It was like looking into a strange world of inner space”. LeDouxfoundfourregionsthatcontainedthetracer. Threeofthoseregions,whendamaged, showed no change in response in fear conditioning. The fourth region was the amygdala. Theamygdala,itturnedout,wasthefinaldestinationoftheroadmapoffear. Thereareseveral importantimplicationsofLeDoux’sresearchforfinancialcrises. Fear is the hardwired fire alarm of the brain, setting off sprinkler systems and calling the fire department automatically, sometimes even faster than we know. In his book, The Gift of Fear,publicsafetyexpertGavindeBeckerpointsoutthatwecandetectandprocesssubtle cues of impending danger far faster than our conscious minds realize. For example, when the hairs on the back of your neck stand up, that’s your fear instinct kicking in, and you should pay attention to it. The amygdala has direct connections to the brainstem, the central switchboard for all the muscles in our body, and this neural shortcut from fear to physicalmovementiswhatallowsusto(sometimes)duckapunchbeforewe’reevenaware thatsomeoneistryingtohitus,andwhatcaused RobertThompsontomakeaquick exit 10LeDoux(1996). 10 even beforeheunderstoodwhy. Naturally,these automaticbehaviorsareextremely useful forsurvival,particularlyinthefaceofphysicalthreats. But when taken out ofits proper context, ourfear circuitry can becounterproductive, andinsomecases,downrightdeadly. ThenaturalinstinctsthatsavedRobertThompson’s lifeinthatconveniencestorewouldprobablyhavekilledhimlongagointhecontextofflying anairplane, ifitweren’t forhis trainingasacommercial pilot. Pilotsrequire hundreds of hoursoftrainingdesignedtoovercomeournaturalinstinctsashumanbeings. Forexample, anall-too-commonmistake amonginexperienced pilots isthetendency topullback onan airplane’scontrolwheeltopreventtheplanefromcrashingduringastall. Pullingbackon thewheelcausestheairplanetopointupwards,andinthefaceofalife-threateningsituation, it’snosurprisethatourinstinctivereactionistodirecttheplanetowardtheskyandaway fromtheground. 11Unfortunately,inthiscontextourinstinctisexactlywrong—pointingtheplaneupwards reducesitsairspeed,makingastallallbutcertainandsealingthepilot’sfate. Thecorrect butcounterintuitivebehavioristopushthecontrolwheelforward,pointingtheplanedown— towards the ground and a loss of altitude—which has the effect of increasing the plane’s airspeed,decreasingthe“angleofattack”whichincreaseslifttoitswings,andallowingthe pilottorecoverfromthestall,afterwhichhecanregainaltitude.Ofcourse,thismaneuver involveslosingaltitudefirst,sothepilothastomakesurethattheangleandspeedofdescent isn’ttoosteep;otherwisehe’llhitthegroundbeforegeneratingenoughlifttopulloutofthe dive. Thisbalancingactisplayedoutinamatterofseconds,whichiswhysomanyhours oftrainingisneededbeforeapilotbecomesapilot. Thesamelogicappliestofinancialinvestments, riskmanagement,economicpolicyand regulation,andcrisisresponse. Ineachofthesecontexts,fearcanplayaproductiveroleif properlybalancedagainstotherconsiderations. Thefearoflosingmoneywillrationallycause investorstomanagetheirrisksactivelyandinproportiontotheirexpectedreward;extreme fear, however, can cause investors to quickly sell all their risky assets at fire-sale prices in 11One of the industry’s standard textbooks, Jeppesen’s Guided Flight Discovery: Private Pilot (Willits, 2007,p. 3–38),lists three key steps to recoverfrom a stall, of which the first is this: “Decreasethe angle ofattack. Depending onthe typeofaircraft,youmayfindthatadifferentamountofforwardpressureon thecontrolwheelisrequired. Toolittleforwardmovementmaynotbeenoughtoregainlift;toomuchmay imposeanegativeloadonthewing,hinderingrecovery”. 11 favorofgovernmentbondsandcash,whichmaynotservetheirlonger-termobjectivesifthey maintaintheseholdingsfortoolong. Onabroaderscale,ifweallowourfearinstinctstodrive ourreactiontofinancialcrises,wemayeventually regretthepolicyresponsesproducedby ouramygdalas. Thisappliesnotonlytoinvestors,butalsotoregulatorsandpolicymakers, whoseresponsetofearmayhaveconsiderablylargerconsequences. TheworkofKapp,LeDoux,andmanyothersshowedthatthepathwayforfearresponse in the brain sidesteps the higher brain functions, including the ones we usually associate withrationality. Thispathwayleadsinsteadtoaspecificcenterthatprocessestheemotional significanceofstimuli. Wefearthingsforreasonsoutsideourconscious,rationalmind,and we do this because we have no choice; we are physiologically hardwired to do so. More broadly, we behave, think, reach conclusions, and make decisions with the effects of the emotionalbrainalwaysrunninginthebackground. Thishasclearimplicationsforeconomic behavior,aswehaveseenoverthepastseveralyears. 4 Greed Neurosciencehasshownthatfearanditsemotionalresponseareintimatelylinkedtodecisionmakin ginthehumanbrain. Butwhataboutthemorepositiveemotions,suchashappiness, joy, asense ofaccomplishment, orpleasure? Surely most economic decisions are madefor non-averse reasons: after all, William Stanley Jevons spoke of a “double coincidence of wants”, nota“double coincidence offears”. Itturns outthatneuroscience has something tosayaboutthepleasurableemotionsaswell. 12In1954,tworesearchersatMontreal’sMcGillUniversity,JamesOldsandPeterMilner, implanted electrodes into the septal area of the brains of rats. These rats were placed in Skinner boxes with a lever which, when pressed, would deliver a low voltage of 60-cycle alternating current to the rat’s brain. These rats then did something remarkable: they wouldchoose tohavetheirbrainselectricallystimulatedbyrepeatedlypressingthelever— on oneoccasion, almost two thousand times a hour! Olds andMilner were careful torule outthatthevoltagewasreducingthepainofimplantationinstead(understandablyso). This strongly suggested to neuroscientists that there was a “pleasure center” in the 12OldsandMilner(1954). 12 brain. In fact, many electrode studies were performed across a variety of animals to find thepleasure center, including several (ofdubious ethics) onhumans. As withmostthings involving the brain, however, it was more complicated than it first appeared. Instead of a pleasure center, the brain seems to have a reward system. The term “reward” may be a little confusing to the reader with an economics background; in psychology, a “reward” is anything positive which makes a behavior more likely. Rewards can be as basic and fundamentalasfood,orasabstractandintangibleasintellectualsatisfaction. Surprisingly, allthesedifferentrewards—food,sex,love,money,music,beauty—appeartousethesame neurologicalsystem. Moreover,thepathwaysofthissystemalltransmitthesamechemical signal: dopamine. 13Dopamineisacomparativelysimplecompoundthatwasoncethoughttohaveverylittle neurologicalsignificance. Itwasbestknownasaprecursortoadrenalineinthebodyuntilin 1957theSwedishresearcherArvidCarlssonshowedthatitwasinfactaneurotransmitter,a discoveryforwhichhewontheNobelPrizeforPhysiologyorMedicinein2000.14Carlsson hadgivenreserpine,adrugknowntodepleteneurotransmitters,torabbits,whichthenfell intoacatatonicstate. Carlssontheorizedthattherabbits’catatoniawascausedbyalackof anas-yet-undiscoveredneurotransmitter. ByinjectingtherabbitswithL-DOPA,achemical whichwouldbeconvertedtodopamineinthebrain,Carlssonwasabletorevivetherabbits— leadingtheGreek-AmericanneurologistGeorgeCotziasonlyafewyearslatertosuccessfully treatpatientswithParkinson’sdisease,andtheneurologistOliverSackstotreatparalyzed patientswithsleepingsickness,ascelebratedinhisfamousbookAwakenings. OnepeculiarityofpatientstreatedwithL-DOPAwasthattheyoftenbecameaddictedto gambling. Thiswasoneofthefirstcluesthatdopaminewasinvolvedinthebrain’sreward system. Other researchers discovered that addictive drugs such as cocaine and methamphetamine flooded the brain with dopamine through the mesolimbic pathway, releasing it intothenucleus accumbens, which islocatednotveryfarfromtheseptalareawhereOlds andMilnerhadimplantedtheirelectrodes. Neuroanatomistshavenowdiscoveredeightseparatedopaminepathwaysinthebrain,includingon esassociatedwithattentionandlearning. While the full picture of how dopamine and the reward system interact is still far from 13Carlssonetal.(1957). 14Sacks(1974). 13 15clear, there is growing consensus among neuroscientists that the broad outlines have been established.Theimplicationsforfinancialcrisis isclear: animbalance inanindividual’s dopaminesystem caneasilyleadtogreaterrisk-taking,andifrisk-takingactivitiesare,on average,associatedwithfinancialgain,apotentiallydestructivepositive-feedbackloopcan easilyemergefromaperiodofluckydraws. 16Inanotherfascinatingstudyofthebrain’srewardsystem,ateamledbyHansBreiterat HarvardMedicalSchoolandMassachusettsGeneralHospital,andincludingtheparticipation ofpsychologistDanielKahneman,usedatechniqueknownas“functionalmagneticresonance imaging”(fMRI)todetermine which areasofthebrainwere activatedwhenanindividual experiencedmonetarygainsandlosses.Thisexperimentaldesigninvolvesplacingasubject in an MRI machine (a long horizontal tube surrounded by a powerful magnet), attaching amirrorata45-degreeangletotheceilingofthetube(sothesubjectcanseeacomputer screenplacedjustoutsidethetube),askingthesubjecttoengageinavarietyofcomputergeneratedt asksrequiringonlysimplemouse-clicks(whichsubjectscandosincetheirhands arefree),andimagingtheirbrainsallthewhile. WhatdoesfMRIactuallymeasure? Thisisanimportantquestioninallimagingstudies, and indeed in all physiological studies of the human brain. The common denominator for allsuchstudiesistofindphysical“correlates”tointernalmentalprocesseswithintheblack boxofthebrain—minute physiological changes thatcorrelate tosubjective experience. In themostcommonlyusedformoffMRI—blood-oxygenation-level-dependent contrastfMRI (BOLD fMRI)—the oxygenation levels of the blood throughout the brain are measurable becausehemoglobinmoleculeswithoutoxygenrespondmorestronglytoamagneticfieldthan thosewithoxygen. Neuroscientistsreasonthatinanactiveregionofthebrain,theneurons will use more oxygen than average, implying that the level of deoxygenated hemoglobin in that area will increase relative to other areas. In deactivated regions of the brain, in comparison,theneuronswilluselessoxygenthanaverage. Inthisway,fMRIdatacanshow whichregionsofthebrainbecomemoreactive(orlessactive)inresponsetoagiventask. In Breiter’s study, subjects were given a $50 stake (in real money, unlike other fMRI 15It is tempting to speculate that because of the multiplicity of uses and pathways of dopamine in the brain, we have many ways to feel pleasure, while we only have only one way to feel fear. There is some supportforthisasymmetryfrompurelyevolutionarygrounds. 16Breiteretal.(2001). 14 17experiments), and while in the fMRI machine, they were asked to play a simple gambling game. On the computer screen that was projected into the tube in which they lay, one ofthreecomputer-animatedspinners wasdisplayed, similartothekindfoundinchildren’s board games. Each spinner was divided equally into three possible outcomes: the ‘good’ spinnerwith$10,$2.50,and$0;the‘intermediate’spinnerwith$2.50,$0,and-$1.50;and the‘bad’spinnerwith$0,-$1.50,and-$6.Thearrowonthespinnerwastimedtotake sixsecondstoreachitsfinaldestination,longenoughforthefMRItoimagethe“prospect” phase in the subject. Once the spinner stopped, the arrow flashed for six more seconds, longenoughforthefMRItoimagethe“outcome”phase. Unknowntothetestsubjects,the outcomesofthespinnersonlyappearedtoberandom. Infact,thespinnerswentthrougha preprogrammedsequencesuchthateachsubjectearned$78.50bytheendoftheexperiment. What did Breiter, Kahneman, and their colleagues find? As the monetary rewards increased, so did the activation in: the nucleus accumbens, part of the reward system; the sublenticular extended amygdala,associatedwithemotionalreaction; thehypothalamus, a partofthebraincloselylinkedtotheendocrinehormonalsystem;andtheventraltegmental area, which releases dopamine into the reward system. This was a direct neurological correlatetomonetaryreward. Evenmoreintriguing,thepatternofactivationsinthemonetaryrewardprocesslooked extremely familiar to Breiter. In fact, it was the same pattern he had found a few years beforeinanotherstudyheconductedwithcocaineaddictsandfirst-timemorphineusers! In thehumanbrain, monetarygainstimulates thesame rewardcircuitry ascocaine—inboth cases,dopamineisreleasedintothenucleusaccumbens,reinforcingthebehavior. Inthecase ofcocaine,wecallthisaddiction. Inthecaseofmonetarygain,wecallthiscapitalism. In other words, our most fundamental reactions to monetary gain are hardwired into human physiology. NeuroscientistshavealsoattemptedtolinktheresultsoffMRIresearchdirectlytoeconomictheor y. Forexample,ReadMontagueatBaylorMedicalCenterandGregoryBernsat EmoryUniversity SchoolofMedicine have triedtodiscover howthebrain’sdifferentreac17As the experimenters note, “The gains were made larger than the losses to compensate for the wellestablished tendency of subjects to assign greater weight to a loss than to a gain of equal magnitude”, a psychologicalresultwhichcomesdirectlyfromKahnemanandTversky’sresearch. 15 Theysuspectthatthe brainusesacommonscaleofvaluationtocomparedifferentoutcomes. Intheirview,dueto thevastmultiplicityofpossiblehumanbehaviors,thebrainneedsasingleinternalscaleof representingvaluetochooseapropercourseofaction—althoughthiscourseofactionmight notberationalfromthestandpointofHomoeconomicus! 18tionstofinancialrewardtranslateintoaninternalmental“currency”. 19Other researchers have tried touse fMRI research topredict economic behavior. Since many brain regions are activated before a specific type of behavior—e.g., the nucleus accumbensandrisk-seeking—BrianKnutsonandPeterBossaertsatStanfordUniversityhave theorizedtheseanticipationscouldbeusedtocreatea“physiologicallyconstrained”theory ofdecision-making.ThisissomewhatreminiscentofHerbertSimon’sattempttoemulate thepsychology ofthehuman decision-making process inacomputer program. Here, however,theneurologicalcorrelatescouldbedirectlymeasuredbyfMRIandotherbrainimaging techniques,andtheresultingbehaviorscomparedagainsttheresultsofthetheoreticalmodel. 20Ofcourse,thefMRImethodhasitslimitations. Itsspatialresolution,whichcandetect volumes the size of a grain of sand or the head ofa pin, is much toocoarse to detect the activityofasingleneuron,orevenofasmallgroupofneurons. Itsresolutionintimeiseven coarser,takingseveralsecondstobuildupasingleimage.Someresearchersareskeptical of the chain of logic which links deoxygenated blood to local brain activity; at best, they argue, it is imperfectly correlated. Moreover, even under the most favorable conditions, fMRIonlyprovidestheresearcherwithbrain-activitydata. Itisalittleasthoughsomeone were attempting to study how New York City worked, but the only information they had aboutthecitywasthepowercompany’smeterreadingsblockbycityblock. Itwouldtake atrulyskilledresearchertodiscoverthepurposeoftheFinancialDistrictorBroadwayfrom that data, and events as memorable as the Thanksgiving Day parade would effectively be invisibletotheresearcher. Nevertheless,fMRIhasbeenrevolutionaryinallowingresearcherstoseeinsidethe“black box”ofthebrainastheynevercouldbefore. Entirelynewareasofresearchlinkingneurosciencetoeconomicsandfinancehaveemergedthanks totheuseoffMRI,andwehavebarely 18MontagueandBerns(2002). 19KnutsonandBossaerts(2007). comparison, the old-fashioned electroencephalograph could record changes in the brain’s surface electricalactivityinmilliseconds. 20In 16 scratchedthesurfaceofpotentialinsightsfromthistool. Inparticular,wehaven’ttouched onhigherbrainfunctionssuch aslogicalreasoning,numerical computation, andlong-term planning,allintimatelyinvolvedintheeconomicandfinancialdecision-makingprocess. Nor have we faced the thorny questions of intelligence and consciousness, about which we are stillinastateofdeepignorance,evenifourknowledgeisgrowingexponentiallyeachday. 5 Risk 21If our reactions to monetary gain are hardwired, what about our reactions to monetary risk? Aversiontoriskseemsnearlyuniversalamongalllivingorganisms,mostlikelyaclose corollaryofthesurvivalinstinct. Infact,inasimpleevolutionarymodelofbehavior,Thomas BrennanandIhave shown thatwhen therearesystematic environmental risks tofertility, theforcesofnaturalselectionwillfavorthoseindividualsthatareriskaverse!22Thereason issimple: ifonecourseofactionleadstothreeoffspringwithcertainty,andasecondcourse of action leads to a 50/50 gamble of two or four offspring, it can be shown that the first courseofactionleadstomuchfasterpopulationgrowth. 23Buthumanresponsestoriskaremoresubtlethansimpleriskaversionsuggestions. One strikingexampleisthe“Peltzmaneffect”,namedaftertheUniversityofChicagoeconomist SamPeltzmanwho,in1975,publishedacontroversialstudyshowingthatgovernmentregulationsr equiringtheuseofautomobilesafetydevicessuchasseatbeltsdidlittletoreduce thenumberofhighwaydeathsbecausepeopleadjustedtheirbehavioraccordingly,presumablydriv ingfasterandmorerecklessly.Infact, someofhisdatashowed thatovertime, while the number of fatalities among auto occupants did decline, this benefit was almost entirelyoffsetbyanincreaseinthenumberofpedestriandeathsandnonfatalaccidents. He concluded thatthebenefits ofsafetyregulationswere mostlynegatedbychanges indriver behavior. Sincethen,manystudieshaveextendedPeltzman’soriginalstudybyconsidering additionalsafetydevicessuchasairbags,anti-lockbrakes,crumplezones,etc. Insomecases thesenewstudieshaveconfirmed,andinothercasesthey’verefutedPeltzman’sfindingsaf21BrennanandLo(2011). 22ThisisaconsequenceofJensen’sInequality,which,inthissimpleexample,isillustratedbythefactthat thesafechoiceyields3×3=9individualsaftertwogenerationswhereastheriskychoiceyields2×4=8 onaverage. SeeBrennanandLo(2011)foramoreformalderivation. 23Peltzman(1975). 17 24tercontrollingforotherconfoundingfactorssuchasenforcementpractices,driverage,rural vs. urban roads, vehicle weight, and so on.These ambiguous results are not surprising giventhemanydifferentcontextsinwhichwedriveautomobiles. Whileitseemsreasonable thataharriedcommuterwouldcertainlytakeadvantageofimprovedsafetybydrivingfaster and gettingto work afew minutes earlier, the same probably doesn’t hold forvacationers touringthecountryside. 25However,inthemostrecentstudyofthisgenre,twoeconomists,RussellSobelandTodd Nesbit, decided to turn their attention to the one driving venue where there are very few confounding factors, and there’s no doubt thatalldrivers areintensely focused on getting totheirfinaldestinationasquicklyaspossible—NASCARraces.Theirconclusion: “Our results clearly support the existence of offsetting behavior in NASCAR—drivers do drive more recklessly in response to the increased safety of their automobiles”. When the only goalistoreducedrivingtime,itseemsperfectlyrationalthatincreasedsafetywouldinduce driverstodrivefaster. Fromafinancialperspective,thisiscompletelyconsistentwithbasic portfoliotheory: ifanasset’svolatilitydeclinesbutitsexpectedreturnremainsunchanged, investors will put more money into such an asset, other things (like correlations to other assets)equal. Butwhatifsafetyimprovementsareperceived tobemoreeffectivethantheyare? Then drivers mayenduptakingmoreriskthantheyintended to,simply because theyfeltsafer thantheyreallywere. Riskperceptionmaydifferfromriskreality,andthiswasobviously a critical factor in the recent financial crisis. Given the AAA ratings of CDOs and their relativelyshorthistoryofgrowthandprofitability,certaininvestorsmayhavethoughtthey were safer than, in fact, they were. This adaptive natureofhuman risk preferences is one ofthemostimportantreasonsforproducingaccurateandtimelyriskanalyticsinfinancial contexts. However,evenwhenriskisaccuratelymeasured,humanbehaviorshowssomeveryinteresting biasesinhowlossesandgainsareweighed. Forexample,consideraslightlymodified version of an experiment conducted by Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky in 1979 for 24See,forexample,CrandallandGraham(1984),Farmeretal.(1997),andCohenandEinav(2003). 25SobelandNesbit(2007). 18 which Kahneman was awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics in 2002. 26Suppose you’re offered two investment opportunities, A and B: A yields a sure profit of $240,000, and B isalotteryticket yielding $1millionwitha25%probability and$0with75%probability. If you had to choose between A and B, which would you prefer? While investment B has anexpectedvalueof$250,000whichishigherthanA’spayoff,youmaynotcareaboutthis fact because you’ll receive either $1 million or zero, not the expected value. It seems like there’snorightorwrongchoicehere;it’ssimplyamatterofpersonalpreference. Facedwith this choice, most subjects prefer A, the sure profit, to B, despite the fact that B offers a significantprobabilityofwinningconsiderablymore. Thisisanexampleofriskaversion. Now suppose you’re faced with another two choices, C and D: C yields a sure loss of $750,000,andDisalotteryticketyielding$0with25%probabilityandalossof$1million with75%probability. Whichwouldyouprefer? Thissituationisnotasabsurdasitmight seematfirstglance;manyfinancialdecisionsinvolvechoosingbetweenthelesseroftwoevils. In this case, most subjects choose D,despite the fact that D is more risky than C. When faced with two choices that both involve losses, individuals seem to behave in exactly the oppositeway—they’reriskseekinginthiscase,notriskaverseasinthecaseofA-versus-B. The factthatindividuals tendtoberiskaverse inthefaceofgainsandriskseeking in thefaceoflosses—whichKahnemanandTversky(1979)called“aversiontosureloss”—can leadtosomeverypoorfinancialdecisions. Toseewhy,observethatthecombinationofthe mostpopularchoices,A-and-D,isequivalenttoasinglelotteryticketyielding$240,000with 25%probabilityand-$760,000with75%probability,whereasthecombinationoftheleast popularchoices,B-and-C,isequivalenttoasinglelotteryticketyielding$250,000with25% probabilityand-$750,000with75%probability. The B-and-Ccombinationhasthesame probabilitiesofgainsandlosses,butthegainis$10,000higherandthelossis$10,000lower. Inotherwords,B-and-CisidenticaltoA-and-Dplusasureprofitof$10,000. Inlightofthis analysis,wouldyoustillpreferA-and-D? Acommonresponsetothisexperimentisthatit’sunfairbecausethetwopairsofinvestmentoppor tunitieswerepresentedsequentially,notsimultaneously. Butthefactisthatall ofusareconstantlymakingdecisionsaboutriskychoicesoneaftertheother,andwedon’t alwayshavetheluxuryofcontemplatingthecumulativeeffectsofthosedecisionsbeforewe 26Tverskydiedin1996,otherwisehewouldnodoubthavesharedtheprizewithKahneman. 19 makethem. In fact, aversion to sure loss is a very real problem thatlies at the heart of one of the biggestpotentialexposuresofeverymajorfinancialinstitution: theroguetrader. Thecases ofNickLeeson(Barings,1995,£827millionloss),YasuoHamanaka(Sumitomo,1996,$2.6 billionloss),JohnRusnak(AlliedIrishBanks,2002,$691millionloss),ChenJiulin(China AviationOil,2005,$550million),JeromeKerviel(Soci´et´eG´en´erale,2006–2008,e4.9billion loss), Boris Picano-Nacci (Caisse d’Epargne, 2008, e751 million loss) and, most recently, KwekuAdoboli(UBS,2011,$2.3billionloss)arealltoofamiliar: atraderlosesmorethan heexpected,butratherthanowninguptothelossandmovingon,hehidesitandincreases hisbet,hopingtomakeituponthenexttrade,afterwhichallmightbeforgiven. Ofcourse, this rarely happens, and the “doubling down” process continues, usually until the losses become so large as to be impossible to hide. No wonder the first piece of advice given to novicetradersbymoreseasonedprofessionalsisto“cutyourlossesandrideyourgains”;in otherwords,don’tbeoverlyaversetosurelosses! 27This advice applies not only to traders and investors, but also regulators. While we still have much to learn about the behavior of bank supervisors in the years leading up totherecentfinancialcrisis,someeconomistsclaimthatregulatoryforbearance—thetacit or active cooperationof regulators in overvaluing bank assets to avoid violating minimum capitalrequirements—ispartlyresponsibleforthecrisis.28Althoughthereareelaborateexplanation sforwhyregulatoryforbearancemightoccur,includingglobalcompetitionamong regulatoryagenciesandthepoliticaleconomyofregulation,amoremundaneexplanation is aversion to sure loss. When a bank supervisor first identifies an undercapitalized bank, he must decide whether torequire thebank toraise additional capital, orto waitand see whether the bank’s assets will rebound. Requiring a bank to raise capital is costly to the supervisorintermsofthebank’sinvariablynegativeresponse,aswellasthepotentialrisk that this action may cause a loss of confidence among the bank’s customer base, possibly triggering abank run. Even worse, the regulatory action may, in retrospect, seem unwarranted,causingalossofconfidenceintheregulator’scompetence. Waitingtoseewhetherthe bank’sassetswillincreaseinvalue—therebyeliminatingtheneedforsuchcostlyregulatory 27HuizingaandLaevan(2010),BrownandDinc(2011). 28Espinosa-Vega,Kahn,Matta,andSol´e(2011). 20 action—isaformof“doublingdown”,withsimilarconsequences. Notsurprisingly,theasymmetrybetweenourreactionstomonetarygainsandlosseshas 29aneurophysiologicalexplanation. CameliaM.KuhnenandBrianKnutsonatStanfordUniversityquicklyfollowedupBreiter’sexperime ntswithanotherfMRIstudy.Experimental subjects played acomputergameKuhnenandKnutsondeveloped—the BehavioralInvestmentAllocationStrategy(BIAS)task—whilebeingscannedintheMRI.Theplayer shada choicebetweenthreeinvestment options,a“safe”bondoroneoftwostocks, whichmoved randomly. Unknowntotheplayers, oneofthestockswasa“good”stock, whichgainedin the long run, and the other, a “bad” stock, which declined in the long run. Additionally, the“good”stockgavealargerlong-runrewardthanthe“safe”bond,onaverage$2.50per turnversusaconsistent$1. 30KuhnenandKnutsondiscovered averyinterestingpattern. Whenplayersmadeariskseeking mistake—e.g., choosing the “bad” stock over the “good” stock—their nucleus accumbenswasactivatedbeforetheymadetheirdecision. Recallthatthenucleusaccumbens isthesamepartoftherewardcircuitthatisactivatedinresponsetococaineandmonetary gain. Incontrast,beforeplayersmadearisk-aversemistake—e.g.,choosingthe“safe”bond overthe“good”stock—acompletelydifferentpartofthebrainwasactivated,theanterior insula. Thispartofthebrainisnotassociatedwithanyrewardpathwaysatall;rather,it seemstobeassociatedwithdisgust,whetherduetoanunpleasantodor,expressionsofsomeone reacting to an unpleasant odor, or seeing graphic pictures of contamination or bodily mutilation.Itseemsrisk-averseinvestorsprocesstheriskofmonetarylossalongthesame circuittheycontemplateviscerallydisgustingthings,whilerisk-seekinginvestorsprocessthe riskypotentialgainalongthesamerewardcircuitsascocaine. 6 Rationality Inthemid-1970s,asuccessful35-year-oldbusinessmanbegansufferingfromintenseheadaches and a lack of concentration, enough to disrupt his personal and professional life. He was diagnosedwithabraintumor,ameningiomathesizeofasmallorange,whichwaspressing athisfrontallobesfrombelow. Hissurgerytoremove thetumorwassuccessful, although 29KuhnenandKnutson(2005). 30Wickeretal.(2003),Wrightetal.(2004). 21 31some frontal lobe tissue was removed as well. His intelligence, his motor skills, his ability touselanguagewereundamagedinhisrecovery,buthispersonalitywasdrasticallyaltered. Helostallsenseofproportionathisplaceofemployment,spendingthedayobsessingover unimportantdetailswhileignoringthemostpressingtasks. Decidingwhatclothestowear in the morning or what restaurant to dine in at night consumed an inordinate amount of time. He soonlosthisjob, quickly runningthroughaseries ofbadbusiness ventures, and thenhiswifelefthim. Heremarriedandthenquicklydivorced. Bythetimetheneurologist Antonio Damasio encountered him, this man was attempting to get his disability benefits restored;theyhadbeencancelledsincehismentalandphysicalabilitieswere,intheopinion ofotherdoctors,stillintact. Themanwas,toallexternalappearances,a“malingerer”. Damasiowasdoubtful. Thenewimagingtechniques ofthetime—computerizedtomography(CT),magneticresonanceimaging(MRI),andsingle-photo nemission computedtomography (SPECT)—were used to scan the patient’s brain. They revealed very localized lesions on the left and right frontallobes ofhis cortex. The man—the neurological literaturereferstohimas“patientE.V.R.”,butDamasioinhisbookDescartes’Error giveshim thepseudonym“Elliot”—onlyhadasmallportionofhisbraindamaged,theventromedial prefrontalcortex, locatedafewcentimeters behindthelower forehead. Damasiotheorized thatthissmallsectionofthebrainwasinvolvedinthehigherfunctionofdecision-making. 32However, unlike otherpatients with frontal-lobedamage, Elliotperformed normallyon specialized psychological and personality tests. After extensive conversations with him, however, Damasiobegantobelieve there was something else missing besides hisability to makegooddecisions. Althoughapleasant,evenwittyconversationalist,Elliotshowedvery littleemotionalaffecttalkingabouthismisfortunes. AsDamasioprobedfurther,hefound thatElliotwasalmostalwaysonaseeminglyevenemotionalkeel: neversad,neveranxious, never impatient, and only very briefly angry. Psychological tests measuring physiological reactions to violent imagery confirmed this deficit. Afterone series oftests, Elliot himself confirmedthischangetoDamasio: “topicsthathadonceevokedastrongemotionnolonger causedanyreaction,positiveornegative”. Damasiotentativelycalledthissetofconditions “acquired sociopathy”.Apparently, this loss of emotional faculties had a surprisingly 31Damasio(1994,pp.34–37),EslingerandDamasio(1985). 32Damasio(1994,pp.41–45),SaverandDamasio(1991),Damasio,Tranel,andDamasio,(1991,1998). 22 profoundeffectonElliot’sday-to-dayactivities,asDamasio(1994,p.36)describes: Whenthejobcalledforinterruptinganactivityandturningtoanother,hemight persistnonetheless,seeminglylosingsightofhismaingoal. Orhemightinterrupt theactivityhehadengaged,toturntosomethinghefoundmorecaptivatingat that particular moment... The flow of work was stopped. One might say that theparticularstepofthetaskatwhichElliotbalkedwasactuallybeingcarried outtoowell,andattheexpenseoftheoverallpurpose. OnemightsaythatElliot hadbecomeirrationalconcerningthelargerframeofbehavior.... Elliot’sinabilitytofeel—hislackofemotionalresponse—somehowcausedhimtomakeirrationalch oicesinhisdailydecisions. 33This conclusion surprises many economists because oftheassociationbetween emotion andbehavioralbiases. Afterall,isn’titfearandgreed,or“animalspirits”asKeynesonce suggested, that cause prices to deviate irrationally from “fundamentals”? In fact, a more sophisticated view of the role of emotions in human cognition is that they are central to rationality.Emotionsarethebasisforareward-and-punishmentsystemthatfacilitatesthe selectionofadvantageousbehavior,providinganumeraireforanimalstoengageina“costbenefitan alysis”ofthevariousactionsopentothem(Rolls,1999,Chapter10.3). Evenfear and greed—the two most common culprits in the downfall of rational thinking, according tomostbehavioralists—aretheproductofevolutionaryforces,adaptivetraitsthatincrease theprobabilityofsurvival. Fromanevolutionaryperspective,emotionisapowerfultoolfor improving the efficiency with which animals learn from their environment and their past. When an individual’s ability to experience emotion is eliminated, an important feedback loopisseveredandhisdecision-makingprocessisimpaired. What,then,isthesourceofirrationality,ifnotemotion? Theneuroscience perspective provides a hint, from which we can craft a conjecture. Neuroscientists have shown that emotion—especiallyfearandthefight-or-flightresponse—isthe“firstresponse”inthesense 33See, for example,Damasio (1994)andRolls (1990,1994,1999). Recent researchinthe cognitiveneurosciences and economics suggest an important link between rationality in decision-making and emotion (GrossbergandGutowski,1987;Damasio,1994;Elster,1998;Lo,1999;LoandRepin,2002;Loewenstein, 2000;andPetersandSlovic,2000),implyingthatthetwoarenotantithetical,butinfactcomplementary. Forexample,contrarytothecommonbeliefthatemotionshavenoplaceinrationalfinancialdecision-making processes,LoandRepin(2002)presentpreliminaryevidencethatphysiologicalvariablesassociatedwiththe autonomicnervoussystemarehighlycorrelatedwithmarketeventsevenforhighlyexperiencedprofessional securitiestraders. Theyarguethatemotionalresponsesareasignificantfactorinthe real-timeprocessing offinancialrisks,andthatanimportantcomponentofaprofessionaltrader’sskillsliesinhisorherability tochannelemotion,consciouslyorunconsciously,inspecificwaysduringcertainmarketconditions. 23 34that we exhibit emotional reactions to objects and events far more quickly than we can articulatewhatthoseobjectsandevents are,asinRobertThompson’s case.Infact,extremeemotionalreactionscan“short-circuit”rationaldeliberationaltogether(seeBa umeister, Heatherton, and Tice, 1994), i.e., strong stimulus to the amygdala seems to inhibit activityintheprefrontalcortex,theregionofthebrainassociatedwithlogicaldeliberation andreasoningability. Fromanevolutionarystandpoint,thisseemsquitesensible—emotional reactionsareacall-to-armsthatshouldbeheededimmediatelybecausesurvivalmaydepend onit,andhigherbrainfunctionssuchaslanguageandlogicalreasoningaresuppresseduntil thethreatisover,i.e.,untiltheemotionalreactionsubsides. 35However,inourcurrentenvironment,many“threats”identifiedbytheamygdalaarenot, infact,life-threatening,yetourphysiologicalreactionsmaystillbethesame. Insuchcases, thesuppressionofourprefrontalcortexmaybeunnecessaryandpossiblycounterproductive, whichisimplicitinthecommonadvicetorefrainfrommakinganysignificantdecisionsafter experiencingthedeathofalovedone,orasimilaremotionaltrauma. Thisissageadvice,for theabilityto“thinkstraight”isgenuinelyphysiologically hamperedbyextremeemotional reactions. Thecomplexity oftheinteractionsamongthedistinctcomponentsofthebrainmaybe illustratedbytwoexamples. Thefirstinvolvesthedifferencebetweenanaturalsmileanda “forced”smile(seeDamasio,1994,pp.141–143andFigure7-3),whichiseasilydetectedby mostofus, butwhy? The answer liesinthefactthatanaturalsmile isgeneratedby one regionofthebrain—theanteriorcingulate—andinvolvescertaininvoluntaryfacialmuscles thatarenotunderthecontrolofthemotorcortex. Theforcedsmile, however, isapurely voluntary behavior emanating from the motorcortex, and does notlook exactly the same because involuntary muscles donotparticipateinthisaction. Infact,ittakes greateffort andskilltogenerateparticularfacialexpressionsoncue,asactorstrainedinthe“method” school can attest—only by conjuring up emotionally charged experiences in their past are theyabletoproducethekindofgenuine emotionalreactionsneeded inagivenscene, and 34SeeSection3,deBecker(1997),andZajonc(1980,1984). 35Otherfamiliarmanifestationsoftheantagonisticeffectofemotionontheprefrontalcortexincludebeing soangrythatyoucannotsee(“blindedbyyouranger”,bothphysicallyandmetaphorically),andbecoming tongue-tiedanddisorientedinthepresenceofsomeoneyoufindunusuallyattractive. Bothvisionandspeech aremediatedbytheprefrontalcortex. 24 anythinglessauthenticisimmediatelyrecognizedas“badacting”. ThesecondexampleisfromastudybyEisenberger,Lieberman,andWilliams(2003)in which they deliberately induced feelings ofsocial rejection among agroup ofsubjects and thenidentifiedtheregionsofthebrainthatweremostactivatedduringthestimulus. They discovered thattwocomponents were involved, theanteriorcingulate andtheinsula, both ofwhicharealsoknowntoprocessphysicalpain. Inotherwords,emotionaltrauma—hurt feelings,emotionalloss,embarrassment, andshame—cangeneratethesamekindofneural response that a broken bone does. Many who have experienced the death of a loved one havecommentedthattheyfeltphysical painfromtheirlossdespitethefactthatnophysical trauma was involved, and we are now beginning to develop a neuroscientific basis forthis phenomenon. Eisenberger,Lieberman,andWilliams(2003,p.292)concludethat“...social painisanalogousinitsneurocognitivefunctiontophysicalpain,alertinguswhenwehave sustainedinjurytooursocialconnections,allowingrestorativemeasurestobetaken”. These two examples illustratesomeofthemanyways inwhich specialized components in the brain can interact toproduce behavior. The first example shows that two different components of the brain are capable of producing the same outcome: a smile. The second example shows that the same components can be involved in producing two different outcomes: physicalandemotionalpain. Thepointofspecializationinbrainfunctionisincreasedfitnessintheevolutionarysense. Eachspecializedcomponentmaybeviewedasan evolutionaryadaptationdesignedtoincreasethechancesofsurvivalinresponsetoaparticularenvir onmentalcondition. Asenvironmentalconditionschange,sotoodoestherelative importanceofeach component. Oneofthe unique features ofHomo sapiens is theability toadapttonewsituationsbylearningandimplementingmoreadvantageousbehavior,and thisisoftenaccomplishedbyseveralcomponentsofthebrainactingtogether. Asaresult, what economists call “preferences” are often complicated interactions among the various componentsofthebrain. Thisperspectiveimpliesthatpreferencesmaynotbestablethroughtime,butarelikely tobeshapedbyanumberoffactors,bothinternalandexternaltotheindividual,i.e.,factors related tothe individual’s personality, andfactors related tospecific environmental conditionsinwhichtheindividualiscurrentlysituated. Whenenvironmentalconditionsshift,we shouldexpectbehaviortochangeinresponse,boththroughlearningand,overtime,through 25 changesinpreferencesviatheforcesofnaturalselection. Theseevolutionaryunderpinnings are more than simple speculation in the context offinancial market participants. The extraordinarydegree ofcompetitiveness ofglobalfinancialmarkets andtheoutsized rewards thataccruetothe“fittest”traderssuggestthatDarwinianselectionisatworkindeterminingthetypical profileofthesuccessfulinvestor. Afterall,unsuccessfulmarketparticipants areeventuallyeliminatedfromthepopulationaftersufferingacertainleveloflosses. 36SinceDamasio’spathbreakingstudiesoftheroleofemotioninrationalandirrationalbehavior,sev eralofDamasio’sstudentsandcolleaguesattheUniversityofIowahavedeveloped newtestsforpatientswithsimilarneuropathologies. AntoineBechara,thenDamasio’spostdoctoralstudent,devisedwhatisnowcalledtheIowaGambli ngTask.Thispsychological testtakessomeofitsinspirationfromDanielKahnemanandAmosTversky’sexperiments, butBechara wanted touse asrealistic adecision-making task as possible, so heturned to thatverycommonpastime,adeckofcards. Inthebasictask,theexperimentaltestsubject—calledthe“player”—isseatedinfront offourdecksofcardsandisgiven$2,000inrealistic-lookingplaymoney. Theobjectofthe game is to lose as little money and gain as much money as possible. The player turns a cardselectedfromanyoneofthedecks,andeitherwinsorlosesacertainamountofmoney foreachturn. Whattheplayerdoesnotknowbeforehand,ofcourse, isthatthedecks are rigged. DecksAandBpay$100foreachturnofacard,butdeckAwilloccasionallycost theplayerafewhundreddollars—enoughsothatapurestrategyfromdeckAwilldeplete theirstake—anddeckBwilllessfrequentlypenalizetheplayer$1,250dollars. DecksCand D, on the other hand, pay $50 per turn, with deck C occasionally penalizing the player a small amount, $25or$50or$75, and deck D infrequently penalizing the player $250, but neverenoughtocausealossinthelongrun. Regular players—that is, the control group—typically start offthe gameby trying out cardsfromeachofthefourdecks. Then,luredbythepromiseofalargerpayoff,theyfocus ondecksAandB,untiltheyrealizethisisnotawinningstrategy. Thistypicallyhappens within the first thirty cards. The player then switches to decks C and D, although some risk-takers will stilloccasionallysample cardsfromdecks AandBaswell. This continues onforahundredcards,whichiswhenthecroupier/experimentercallsahalttothetest. 36Becharaetal.(1994). 26 37Players with damage totheir ventromedial prefrontal cortex or their amygdala employ a completely different strategy from the control group. They start off in the same way, sampling the decks, but as the game continues they prefer decks A and B over decks C and D, despite the fact that those decks are designed to bankrupt the player! When the player inevitably goes bankrupt, the experimenter loans them more money. Even frontal patients who describe themselves as “low-risk” will systematically choose decks A and B much more often than regular players who describe themselves as “high-risk”.Without certain emotional faculties, the ability to process risk is clearly impaired. This finding suggeststhatemotionplaysacriticalroleinproducingrationaltrade-offsbetweenriskand reward,whichisthecruxoffinancialdecision-making. Whatweconsidertobe“rational”behavioris,infact,acomplexbalancingactbetween anumber ofcomponents ofthebrain, some hardwired, others moreadaptive, andifthese componentsbecomeimbalanced—eithertoomuchfearortoolittlegreed—weobserve“maladaptiv e”behavior. Therefore,thedefinitionofrationality,anditsopposite,isinextricably tiedtoanindividual’s environment. The greatwhite shark moves throughthewaterwith fearsome grace and efficiency, thanks to 400 million years of natural selection—but take thatsharkoutofwaterandontoasandybeach,anditsflailingundulationswillseemquite irrational! The origins of human behavior are similar, differing only in the length of time wehavehadtoadapttoourenvironment(about2millionyears),andthespeedwithwhich thatenvironmentisnowchanging,thankstotechnologicaladvances. EvolutionarilyadvantageousresponsesbyHomosapiens tothreatsontheplainsoftheAfricansavannah50,000 yearsagomaynotbeaseffectiveindealingwiththreatsontheflooroftheNewYorkStock Exchangetoday. Therefore,weshouldn’tbesurprisedtofindthatthelackofsunlightduringwintermonths tendstodepressstock-marketprices(Kamstra,Kramer,andLevi,2003),thattraderswho exhibittoolittleortoomuchemotionalresponsetendtobelessprofitablethanthosewith mid-range sensitivity (Lo and Repin, 2002; Lo, Repin, and Steenbarger, 2005), and that traderstendtomakemoremoneyondayswhentheirlevelsoftestosteronearehigherthan average (Coates and Herbert, 2008). These are just a few examples from the emerging “neuroeconomics”literatureinwhicheconomicbehaviorisbeingreinterpretedfromaneu37Damasio(1994,pp.212–217). 27 rophysiologicalperspective,providingadeeperandricherbasisforunderstandingrationality andirrationality. 7 Sentience Whileneuroscience clearly shows thatthehumandecision-making process isvery farfrom the hyper-rationality ofHomo economicus,the Efficient Markets Hypothesis suggests that thismightnotmattervery much. Consideramodernfinancialmarketwithmanytraders. Ifonetradermakesapoordecisionundertheheatofemotion,anothertraderactingmore rationallyshould seethisasanarbitrageopportunityandmake aneasyprofit. Ofcourse, weknowthatthisidealdepictionofthewisdomofcrowdsdoesnotalwayshappen—entire marketscanbeinfectedwithwhatthenineteenth-centuryjournalistCharlesMackaycalled “the madness ofcrowds”—but itdoes happen farmoreoften thannot. Butwhat ifthere werebiologicallimitstohumanrationalityitself? It’s a truism in freshman economics that price is determined by supply and demand, buteacheconomictransactionhasabuyerandaseller,eachtryingtocometoamutually satisfyingagreementviaJevons’saforementioned“doublecoincidenceofwants”. Ifaseller refuses to lower the asking price to a level abuyer wishes to bid, no transaction will take place. Thatmightbearationaldecision ontheseller’s part. Ontheotherhand,itmight reflectalackofawarenessofwhatthebuyeriswillingtooffer. Awell-functioningmarket’s price-discoveryprocessrequiresparticipantstoengageinacertaindegreeofcause-and-effect reasoning: “If I do this, then others will do that, which means I should...”. This chain of logic presumes that individuals have what psychologists call a “theory of mind”—the abilitytounderstandanotherperson’smentalstate. Tounderstandwhy,considerthemost basic form of bilateral negotiation between a buyer and a seller; even the simplest backand-forthprocess ofprice discovery requires thatthebuyer understand themotives ofthe seller,andviceversa. Infact,tocomputetheequilibriumprice—ashypothesizedbyrational expectationsandefficientmarketstheory—requiresanunendingrecursivechainofreasoning, asifbuyerandsellerweretrappedinahallofmirrors: thesellerknowsthatthebuyerknows that the seller knows that the buyer knows that the bid is too high, etc. In other words, market equilibrium requires arather sophisticated theory ofmind, and presumably a high 28 levelofabstractthought. Intheearly1990s,achancediscoverybyagroupofresearchersattheUniversityofParma 38ledbyGiacomoRizzolattishowedthatperhapsthe“theoryofmind”wasnotveryabstract atall,buthardwiredintothestructureofthebrainitself.Usingrecordingmicroelectrodes generationsmoreadvancedthantheonesusedinOldsandMilner’sexperiment,Rizzolatti andhisgroupfoundtherewerespecificneuronsinthemacaquemonkeybrainthatresponded to“mirrored”motionsinothers. Forinstance,acertainneuroninthepremotorcortexwould firewhenamacaquegraspedanobjectaswellaswhenanexperimentergraspedanobject. Thiswasdirectphysicalevidencethatthemacaquecouldunderstandtheactionsofothersin termsofitsownexperience,evenacrossspecies! Inshort,themacaquehadabasic“theory ofmind”hardwiredintoitsneurophysiology. 39Thisdiscoveryof“mirrorneurons”wasentirelyunexpected. Whilesomeneuroscientists hadjokinglyspokenof“grandmotherneurons”,neuronsthatwouldfirewhenindividualssaw theirgrandmothers,noneurologistexpected abasicsysteminthebrainforunderstanding thebehaviorofothersintermsofone’sownphysicalactions. Infact,thediscoverywasso outofleftfieldthattheprestigiousscientificjournalNature declinedtopublishRizzolatti’s manuscriptbecauseitseditorsbelieveditlacked“generalinterest”.Thisrejectionnotwithstanding,i nashorttimeRizzolattiandhisteamdetectedmirrorneuronsinhumansaswell, notthroughtheuseofmicroelectrodes,butthroughtheuseofpositronemissiontomography (PET), which showed neural activity in the analogous areas ofthe human brain as in the macaqueinresponsetomirroredbehavior. Likeourevolutionarycousins,wehumanshave neuronsthatautomatically“lightup”insympathytotheactionsofothers. Nowincontrasttothecommonneuroscientificapproachofdeterminingthefunctionof partsofthebrainbystudyingthebehaviorofindividualsinwhomsuchpartsaredamaged, inthecaseofmirrorneurons,theapproachhasbeenreversed. Weknowwhattheneurons do,butwedon’tyetknowhowtheyaffectbehavior. Onehypothesis,proposedbyRizzolatti and others, is that a deficit in the brain’s mirror mechanism may be involved in autism spectrumdisorder,thatcomplexsyndromeoflearning,social,communicative,andemotional deficits. People with autism often have difficulty in understanding other people’s motives 38DiPellegrinoetal.(1992). 39RizzolattiandFabbri-Destro(2010). 29 40and,therefore,connectingsocially,suggestingtheyhaveanundevelopedtheoryofmind,as theBritish neuroscientist SimonBaron-Cohenbelieves.Here, however, we don’thave to lookforspecific neurologicalcase studies amongautistic children. Every oneofushas, as children,passedthroughlifestageswhereourowntheoriesofmindwereundeveloped. It is strange to think that at some point before the age of four, we were not able to understandthatanotherperson,perhapsaparent,couldbelievesomethingthatweourselves knewwasnottrue. Asadults,ofcourse,mostofusarecomfortablewiththeideathatother peoplemightbemistaken. Forthoseofuswhoareparents,theknowledgethatachildunder theageoffourismentallyincapableofunderstandingthisisvaguelycomforting,particularly whenwearefacedwithwhatlookslikeotherwiseunreasonablebehavior. However, bythe timemostchildrenreachtheageoffour,theyareabletodealwithwhatpsychologistscall “first-order false belief”. Sentimentally, we might pinpoint that age as the time when we learnourparentsaren’tinfallible,butinreality,that’stheageourbrainshavedevelopedto thepointwherewecanunderstandthatotherpeoplecanbefallible. It’sanimportantstep onthepathwaytoafull“theoryofmind”. fact, afour-year-oldmightbe abletounderstand astatement like, “Alanthinks his Christmaspresentisinredwrapping,butthepresentisreallyinthegreenwrapping”. But atypicalfour-year-oldwouldnotunderstandastatementlike,“BethanythinksAlanthinks hisChristmaspresent isblue,andAlanthinkshisChristmas presentisred,butit’sreally green”. Theabilitytounderstandasecond-orderfalsebelief,insteadoffollowingnaturally andrecursivelyfromtheabilitytounderstandafirst-orderfalsebelief,takesafewmoreyears to develop. In general, a seven-year-old can understand a story with a second-order false belief. Thismeanstheirtheoryofmindisrichenoughnotonlytomodelanotherperson’s mentalstate,butalsotomodelanotherperson’smodelofaperson’smentalstate. Afouryear-oldcanseeonemirrordeepintothehallofmirrorsofintention,whileaseven-year-old canseetwomirrorsdeep. 41In How far does this hall of mirrors extend? We might suspect, on purely theoretical grounds, that the potential for infinite regress is present in humans, even if rarely used. After all, the English language can support infinite levels of clauses in its grammar, as in 40Baron-Cohen(1989). 41PernerandWimmer(1985). 30 42thenurseryrhyme“Thisisthecatthatkilledtheratthatatethemaltthatlayinthehouse thatJackbuilt”,andsoon. Ontheotherhand,wemighttrytoconstructamentalexperimentaboutathird-orderfalsebelief—Cla ytonthinksthatBethanythinksthatAlanthinks etc.—andcometotheconclusionthatit’sratherdifficult. Infact,psychologicaltestshave shown that normal adults start making significant errors when answering questions about thefifth-ordertheoryofmind. This hasimplications fortheassumption ofhuman rationalityin theEfficient Markets Hypothesis. Itisnotverydifficulttoconstructascenariowherecorrectknowledgeregarding another individual’s intentions five layers removed from a given transaction has economic implications, whether in a complicated mergers and acquisitions deal, in the terms of an exotic financial derivative, or even in the picks and trades of the NFL draft. But if it’s impossibleforallbutaveryfewchessgrandmasterstoholdsuchachainofintentionsasa singlethought—impossibleinthesamewaythatayoungchildliterallycannotunderstand thathisparentdoesnotknowwherehisblanketis—howcananinvestoralwaysactrationally tomaximize hisorherprofit? Alternatively, iftheinvestorfailstoactrationally,howcan otherinvestorsknowtheyaretakingsuccessfuladvantageofthefailure? Thismightinvolve asixth-ordertheoryofmind. Whilethearbitragemechanismcancorrectmisjudgments, it reliesontheabilityofinvestorsinthemarkettorecognizewhenacorrectjudgmentbythe markethastakenplace. Insomecases,thisexpectationissimplyunrealistic. 8 Interactions Althoughneurosciencehashadmanybreakthroughsinthelastfewdecades,oneofthemost importantquestionsabouthumancognitionhasyettobeanswered: howdotheindividual components of the brain interact to produce observed human behavior? We now know a great deal more about how fear and greed are physiologically generated, but what can we say abouthow an individual will respond toa20%decline inhis retirement portfolio? Despitethefactthatthefight-or-flightresponsemaybetriggeredbysuchanevent,notall individualswillreactinthesamemanner—somemaypanicandswitchtheirportfoliotocash immediately; others may notreactatall. Can neuroscience provide anyinsight into these 42Kinderman,Dunbar,andBentall(1998). 31 individual differences and the underlying mechanisms by which such heterogeneity arises? Fromtheeconomist’spointofview,thesekindsofquestionsarethemostrelevant;theyare alsothemostdifficulttoanswerfromtheneuroscientificperspective. Whilewedon’tyethaveacompletetheoryofhowthebrainworks,thereareafewobservationsthat hintathowthevariouscomponentsofthebraininteract. Thefirstobservationis thatnotallneuralcomponentsarecreatedequal. Fromanevolutionaryperspective,certain componentsaremucholderthanothersandarefoundinmanyspeciesinadditiontoHomo sapiens. Therefore, these commoncomponents aremorelikely toengageinfunctions that arecriticalforbasicsurvivalacrossallspecies. Forexample,painreceptorsexistinvirtually allmammalsandreptiles;hencepainavoidanceandfearconditioningisequallyubiquitous andobviouslycriticalforsurvival. Thisuniversalityimpliesacertainpriorityinitsimpact onbehavior: painavoidanceandfeartrumpallotherneuralcomponentsundersufficiently threateningcircumstances,astheyshould. Whilea20%declineinone’sretirementportfolio mightnotleadtothesameresponseacrossadiversepopulationofinvestors,aragingfirein acrowdedtheaterwill. 43However, thebehaviorofHomo sapiens canbeconsiderablymoresubtle,asillustrated bytheremarkablestoryofthe27-year-oldmountainclimberAronLeeRalston,whoseordeal waschronicled inthegrippingfilm127 Hours. OnApril26,2003,Ralstonwasclimbinga 3-footwidecrevasseinBluejohnCanyoninaremoteregionofsoutheasternUtahwhenan 800-poundboulderslippedandpinnedhisarmtothewallofthecrevasse. Hewastrapped inthecrevasseforfivedays,andhefinallyescapedbyamputatinghisrightarmbelowthe elbowwithadullknife. ThisstoryisincrediblebecausewerecognizethatRalstonvoluntarily inflicted extraordinarypainonhimself,indirect contradictiontoourmostbasicinstinct 43To appreciate the magnitude of the pain Ralston underwent, the following is a short summary of Ralston’s self-amputation written by a mountain-climbing blogger, Shane Burrows (http://climbutah.com/Roost/bluejohn2.htm). WARNING:Squeamishreadersshouldreadnofurther: Ralstonpreparedtoamputatehisrightarmbelowtheelbowusingtheknifebladeonhismultitool. Realizingthatthebladewasnotsharpenoughtocutthroughtheboneheforcedhisarm againsttheboulderandbrokethebonessohewouldbeabletocutthroughthetissue. First he brokethe radius bone, whichconnects the elbowto the thumb. Within a few minutes he crackedtheulna,theboneontheoutsideoftheforearm. Nextheappliedatourniquettohis arm. He then used his knife blade to amputate his right arm below the elbow. The entire procedurerequiredapproximatelyonehour. For those interested in the gory details, an even more graphic description is provided by Ralston (2004, pp.281–285). 32 of pain avoidance. How was he able to accomplish this feat? Presumably, he was able to overridehispain-avoidancecircuitrybycreatinganalternatescenarioinhismindthatwas considerablymorerewarding—despitethefactthatitincludedthepainfulamputation—than dyingaloneinthecrevasseonthatday. 44Ourcapacitytocreatecomplexscenarios,purefigmentsofoursubstantialimaginations, isoneofthemostimportantevolutionary advantageswe’ve developed, anditseems tobe unique to our species. The portion of the brain responsible for these complex thoughts is knownastheprefrontalcortex,andwhilesimilarstructuresdoexistinothermammals,Homo sapiensseemstohavethelargestandmosthighlyconnectedversion.45Neuroscientistshave shown thatmany oftheuniquely human traits such aslanguage, mathematical reasoning, complex planning, selfcontrol, anddelayed gratificationoriginateintheprefrontalcortex. Forthisreason,thisregionissometimesreferredtoasthe“executivebrain”. LiketheCEO of a well-run company, the prefrontal cortex is responsible for developing a vision for the organization, monitoring the performance of the various divisions and subordinates, and making resource-allocation decisions that weigh the costs and benefits of each competing division’s goals so as to maximize the chances of achieving the overall objectives of the organizationwhileprotectingitfromcurrentandpotentialthreats. Thiscorporatehierarchy isnotsimplyausefulanalogy—it’sactuallypartofourneurophysiology.This“commandand-control center” was the region of the brain destroyed in Phineas Gage’s unfortunate accident,withpredictableconsequences. Theexecutivefunctionsthathumanbrainspossessallowustoengageinfarmorecomplex behaviors than otherspecies. A simple manifestation ofthis difference is the factthat we can more easily predict the behavior of other animals than those ofhumans. Greatwhite sharkscircletheirpreybeforestriking,Canadiangeesemigratesouthduringthewinter,and ocean-dwelling Pacific salmon return to freshwater rivers to lay their eggs. While humans exhibitcertainpredictabletraitsaswell(asignificantfractionofNewEnglandersalsomigrate southforthewinter!),thenumberofpossiblebehaviorsgeneratedbytheprefrontalcortexis exponentiallygreater,simplybecauseofourabilitytoimagineandchoosefromamultitudeof hypotheticalrealities. Manyofthesealternaterealitiesarehighlyelaboratewhat-ifscenarios 44Schoenemannetal.(2005)andSmaersetal.(2011). 45Botvinick(2008). 33 46thatcanmoveustodoextraordinarythings. AccordingtoAronRalston,itwasthefollowing hypotheticalrealitythatallowedhimtodotheunthinkable: A blond three-year-old boy in a red polo shirt comes running across a sunlit hardwoodfloorinwhatIsomehowknowismyfuturehome. Bythesameintuitive perception, I know the boy is my own. I bend to scoop him into my left arm, using my handless rightarmtobalance him, and we laughtogetherasIswing him up to my shoulder... Then, with a shock, the vision blinks out. I’m back in the canyon, echoes of his joyful sounds resonating in my mind, creating a subconscious reassurancethatsomehowIwillsurvive thisentrapment. Despite havingalreadycometoacceptthatIwilldiewhereIstandbeforehelparrives, nowIbelieveIwilllive. Thatbelief,thatboy,changeseverythingforme. Ralston was not married or engaged at the time, and had no children. In August 2009, RalstonmarriedJessicaTrusty,andtheirfirstchild,Leo,wasborninJanuary2010. The prefrontal cortex is a remarkable piece of neural machinery that, in the blink of an eye on an evolutionary time scale, has allowed humans to dominate their world and spreadtovirtuallyevery typeofenvironment onthisplanetanditsmoon. Theprefrontal cortexistheclosestthingtorationalexpectationsandHomoeconomicusthatthebrainhas to offer to economists. If agents maximize expected utility subject to budget constraints, or optimize portfolios via quadratic programming, or engage in strategic subterfuge in a dynamicbargainingcontext,theywillbeusingtheprefrontalcortextodoso. Butlikeanyorganofanylivingbeing,therearelimitstoitscapabilities. Asimpressive anduniqueasthehumanprefrontalcortexis,itcan’toperateinstantaneouslyorindefinitely. In fact, in certain circumstances, it doesn’t operate at all. For example, individuals who faint when confronted with shocking news do so through a sudden loss of blood pressure thatshuts down theprefrontalcortex, causing themtoloseconsciousness. Aless extreme illustration of the limitations of the prefrontal cortex is “decision fatigue”, a phenomenon recently documented among a group of judges presiding over parole hearings for Israeli prisoners. During each day of hearings, there were two food breaks that divided the day into three distinct sessions, and researchers found a striking pattern over these sessions: the judges rendered favorable paroledecisions about65%ofthe time atthe startofthese sessions, but the percentage would systematically decline to nearly 0%by the end ofeach 46Ralston(2004,p.248). 34 session.4748Itappearsthatdifficult decisions canbementally taxinginsome manner, soas thesesessionsworeon,thejudgesbecamemoreinclinedtoavoidsuchdecisionsbydenying parole. However,afterthefoodbreaks(alate-morningsnack,andthenalunchbreak),the judgeswererefreshedandreadytoresumetheircomplexdeliberations;henceparoleratesat thebeginningofthefollowingsessionwereconsiderablyhigher. Thefactthattheincreased paroleratesfollowedfoodbreaksisconsistentwithrecentfindingsthatglucosecanreverse theeffectsofdecisionfatigue.Apparently,itreallyistruethatoneshouldnevernegotiate onanemptystomach! 49AswiththosecorporateCEOswholeadtheircompaniesastray,therearemanypathsto failure. Earlybehavioralmodelsofeconomicchoicerecognizedthesepathologiesandmodeled theireffectsexplicitlytoproducemorerealisticconsumersavingandspendingpatterns,such asthe“behaviorallife-cyclemodel”ofHershShefrinandRichardThaler.50Theseinsights led to a significant innovation in retirement savings plans, pioneered by Shlomo Benartzi andThaler—the ideaofallowingparticipants to“optout”insteadofaskingthemto“opt in”, and reducing thenumber ofchoices so they don’tover-diversify intoinvestments that theydon’treallyunderstandorwant.51Theseseeminglysuperficialchangescanhavehuge positive impact on the participation rateof401(k) plans, which everyone agrees is agood thing. Inoneempirical study, participationratesforthestandardopt-inplanwas around 20% after three months of employment and increased gradually to 65% after 36 months; withautomaticenrollment,theparticipationrateofnewemployeesjumpedimmediatelyto 90%, and the fact that participation increased to 98% after 36 months suggests that few individualsoptedout.Notonlydidthissimplechangeincreasetheparticipationrate,it alsocausedemployeestojoinsooner,whichobviouslybenefitslong-termwealthcreation. 52These examples highlight the complexity and subtlety of Homo sapiens, but they also offerhopethatwecanonedaydevelopamorecompleteunderstandingofhumanbehavior thatintegrateseconomics,psychology,andneuroscienceinmutuallybeneficialways. 47SeeDanziger,Levav,andAvnaim-Pesso(2011). 48Tierney(2011). 49ShefrinandThaler(1988). 50BenartziandThaler(2004). 51MadrianandShea(2001). 52Lo(2010). 35 9 PolicyImplications Althoughtheperspectiveoutlinedinthischapterhasbeenlargelyqualitative,nevertheless itdoesofferseveralpracticalimplicationsforpolicymakersfocusingonfinancialreformand systemicrisk. 53Oneimmediateimplicationisthatindividualbehaviorisacomplicatedanddynamicmedley ofseveral decision-making neuralcomponents, including primitive hardwired responses such as fight-or-flightandmore refined processes such as logicaldeliberationandstrategic planning. Assumingthatindividualsorpopulationsalwaysbehaveinonlyonemannerorthe otheristoosimplistic andmay leadtoineffective orcounterproductive policies. Financial markets and their participants are rarely always rational, nor are they always emotional. Instead, they engage in both types of mental processes and are constantly adapting and evolvingtonewsetsofcircumstances. Underthis“AdaptiveMarketsHypothesis”,manyof thetenetsofmarketefficiencyandrationalexpectationsmaynotholdatalltimes,butthey doserveasusefulbenchmarksthatrealitymayeventuallyapproximateundercertainconditions.Inp articular,ifenvironmental conditionsarerelatively stable, thentheprocessof naturalselectionwilleventuallyallowmarketparticipantstosuccessfullyadapttosuchconditions,af terwhichthemarketwillappeartobequiteefficient. However,iftheenvironment is unstable, then market dynamics will be considerably less predictable as some “species” lose their competitive edge to others, and the market may appear to be quite inefficient. Indeed,theevolutionarytheoryof“punctuatedequilibrium”—inwhichinfrequentbutlarge environmentalshockscausemassiveextinctionsfollowedbyaburstofnewspecies—maybe justasrelevanttoeconomiccontexts. Ifpunctuatedequilibriaalsocharacterizesfinancialmarkets,thenpoliciesdesignedunder theassumptionsofrationalitywillbeinappropriateduringperiodsoffinancialdistress,and policiesdesignedtodealwithperiodsofdistresswillbeinappropriateduringperiodsofcalm. TheAdaptiveMarketsHypothesissuggeststhatthemostdurableformofregulationisone thatadaptstochangingenvironmentsandpopulations. Countercyclicalcapitalrequirements isoneexample,buttherearemanyotherpossibilitiesforrevampingexistingregulationsto bemoreresponsivetocurrentsystemicexposures. 53Lo(1999,2004,2005). 36 Anotherimplicationoftheneuroscience perspective isthatthereisabiologicallymandatedhierarchyofthecomponentsofthebrainthatshouldberespect ed. Fear,particularly fearoftheunknown,overridesmostotherdecision-makingcomponents,andoncetriggered, thiscircuitcanbeverydifficulttointerrupt. Centralbankersarenostrangerstothisconcept,whichliesattheverycoreofabankrunandoftherais ond’ˆetreofthecentralbankas lenderoflastresort. Butitappliesmuchmorebroadly;hencepolicymakerswoulddowellto focusmoreonclear,accurate,timely,andregularcommunicationwiththepublicthroughout periodsofsignificantturmoil,irrespectiveofthecause. Onlythroughsuchtrustedcommunicationcanfearbesuccessfullymanagedand,ultimately,elimin ated. FDRwasmoreright thanheknewwhenhesaid,“Theonlythingtofearisfearitself”,butheshouldhaveadded that fear is, indeed, a fearsome force of nature that should be greatly feared and actively managed. 54If the active management of fear involves greater communication and transparency, a prerequisiteisthecollectionanddisseminationofinformationregardingsystemicrisk—itis atruismthatonecannotmanagewhatonedoesnotmeasure. Therefore,thestartingpoint foranyseriousdiscussionofmacroprudentialpolicy-makingandsystemicriskmanagement mustbetherawdataonwhichriskmeasuresarebased. Ofcourse,financialdataareoften quite sensitive, and individual and institutional privacy must be guaranteed. Fortunately, measures of systemic risk can be derived without infringing on such privacy because they aggregateinformationoverallfinancialinstitutions. Afterall,theverymeaningofsystemic riskinvolvestheentirefinancialsystem;henceaggregationshouldservetoprotecttheprivacy ofindividualsundermostcircumstances.Thebenefitsofpublicizingsuchmeasurescould be as significant as the air-quality measures published by the Environmental Protection Agency or the hurricane warnings issued by the National Weather Service. In bothcases, it’sonlythroughtheconstantfeedbackofthesepublishedindicatorsthatweknowhowto change ourbehavior accordingly, i.e., by imposing more stringent auto-emission standards ororderingevacuationsofareasinthepathofthehurricane. Theimportanceofmeasurementgoeshand-in-handwiththeexecutivefunctionofdelayed gratificationandpainavoidance. Anindividualorinstitutioncanbeexpectedtovoluntarily 54Inaddition,moresophisticatedmethodsofpreservingprivacysuchastheencryptionalgorithmsofAbbe, Khandani,andLo(2011)maybeimplementedinsituationsinvolvingparticularlysensitiveinformation. 37 reduce or discontinue an otherwise currently pleasurable or profitable activity under only twoconditions: thechangemayresultinevengreaterpleasureorprofitlater,orthechange mayreducethelikelihoodofpaininthefuture. Absentbothoftheseconditions,theneural incentives to reduce risk are also absent; hence the role of publicizing risk measures is to provide all parties with the appropriate information on which they can weigh the fear of future losses against the pleasure of current gains. As Damasio’s elegant explication of rationalityshows,onlythroughtheproperbalanceoffear,greed,andotheremotionaldebits andcreditscanwemakegooddecisions. 55Thebehavioralfeedbackloopcreatedbyaccuratesystemic riskmeasuresisarelatively simple example of how we adapt to changing environments; a more sophisticated version involvesdefinitiveforensicanalysesofprioreventsthatleadustochangeourbehavior. Perhaps the best illustration of this type of learning behavior is the National Transportation SafetyBoard(NTSB),theindependentinvestigatoryagencychargedwiththetaskofanalyzingalltra nsportationaccidents. Intheevent ofanairplanecrash,theNTSBassembles a seasoned team of engineers and flight-safety experts who are immediately dispatched to thecrashsitetoconductathoroughinvestigation,includinginterviewingwitnesses,poring overflightlogsandmaintenancerecords, siftingthroughthewreckagetorecover theflight recorderor“blackbox”,and,ifnecessary, literallyreassembling theaircraftfromitsparts soastodeterminetheultimatecauseofthecrash. Onceitsworkiscompleted, theNTSB publishesareportsummarizingtheteam’sinvestigation,concludingwithspecificrecommendation sforavoidingfutureoccurrencesofthistypeofaccident. Thereportisentered into asearchabledatabasethatisavailabletothegeneralpublic,andthishasbeenoneofthe majorfactorsunderlyingtheremarkablesafetyrecordofcommercialairtravelintheUnited States. Financialblowupsare,ofcourse,considerablylessdire,generallyinvolvingnolossoflife. However, astheFinancialCrisis of2007–2009morethanamply illustrated, thedisruption toeconomiclifecanbedevastatinginitsownright,andwithfarbroaderandlonger-lasting impact than a plane crash. For these reasons, an independent organization dedicated to investigating, reporting, and archiving the “accidents” of the financial industry may yield significantsocialbenefitsinmuchthesamewaythattheNTSBhasimprovedtransportation 55Seehttp://www.ntsb.gov/ntsb/query.asp. 38 safetyenormouslyforallairtravelers. Bymaintainingteamsofexperiencedprofessionals— forensicaccountants,financialengineersfromindustryandacademia,andsecuritiesandtax attorneys—thatworktogetheronaregularbasistoinvestigatethecollapseofeverymajor financialinstitution,a“CapitalMarketsSafetyBoard”(CMSB)wouldbeabletodetermine quicklyandaccuratelyhoweachcollapsecameabout,andtheresultingreportswouldbean invaluable source ofideas forimproving financialmarkets andavoidingsimilar debacles in thefuture. It is unrealistic to expect that market crashes, panics, collapses, and fraud will ever becompletely eliminatedfromourcapitalmarkets, butwe shouldavoidcompoundingour mistakes by failingtolearnfromthem. Amoreinformedinvesting publicwillbetheonly meansofconqueringourfearsandreestablishingtheleveloffaithandtrustthathasmade U.S.financialmarketsamongthemostliquidandefficientintheworld. 10 Conclusion OneofthemostsignificantconsequencesoftheFinancialCrisisof2007–2009istherealization thatthe intellectual framework ofeconomics andfinance is incomplete inseveral respects. While the Financial Crisis has exposed some of the limitations of neoclassical economics, critiquesoftraditionaleconomictheoryhavebeenaccumulatingfromwithintheprofession forquitesometime. Theconflictbetweentherationalexpectationsparadigmofeconomics andthemanybehavioralbiasesdocumentedbypsychologists, behavioraleconomists, sociologists,andneuroscientistshasbeenhotlydebatedfordecades. Rationalexpectationsand its close cousin, the efficient markets hypothesis, have come under fire recently because of theirapparentfailureinpredictingandexplainingthecurrentfinancialcrisis. Some of this criticism is undoubtedly misplaced populist anger atthe life-altering economicconsequences oftheburstingofthehousingbubblein2006,anditsknock-oneffects on the financial system, employment, and real economic growth in its aftermath. In such an emotionally charged atmosphere, it is easy to forget the many genuine breakthroughs thathaveoccurredineconomicsoverthelasthalf-centurysuchasgeneralequilibriumtheory,gamet heory,growththeory,econometrics,portfoliotheory,andoption-pricingmodels. Butanyvirtuecanbecomeavicewhentakentoanextreme. Thefactthatthe2,319-page 39 Dodd-Frankfinancial reformbill was signed into law on July 21, 2010—sixmonths before the Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission submitted its January 27, 2011 report, and well before economists have developed any consensus on the crisis—underscores the relatively minorscientificrolethateconomicshasplayedinrespondingtothecrisis. ImaginetheFDA approvingadrugbeforeitsclinicaltrialsareconcluded,ortheFAAadoptingnewregulations inresponsetoanairplanecrashbeforetheNTSBhascompleteditsaccidentinvestigation. Therearelegitimateargumentsthattherigorousandinternallyconsistenteconomicmodels of rational self-interest—models used implicitly and explicitly by policymakers, central bankers,andregulatorstoformulatepolicy,manageleverage,andreininrisk-takinginthe economy—are deficient. Even the most sophisticated stochastic dynamic general equilibrium models did not account for the U.S. housing market boom and bust, nor were they richenoughtocapturetheconsequencesofsecuritization,creditdefaultinsurance,financial globalization,andthepoliticaldynamicsunderlyingFannieMaeandFreddieMac. 56However,weshouldn’tbetooquicktodismissthepositiverolethatmarketshaveplayed, certainly throughout history but even during the buildup to the crisis. In an April 2006 publicationbytheFinancialTimes,reporterChristineSeniorfiledastoryontheenormous growthoftheCDOmarketinEuropeoverthepreviousyears,quotingNomura’sestimateof $175billionofCDOsissuedin2005. WhenaskedbySeniortocommentonthisremarkable growth,CianO’Carroll,EuropeanheadofstructuredproductsatFortisInvestments,replied, “You buy a AA-rated corporate bond you get paid Libor plus 20 basis points; you buy a AA-rated CDO and you get Libor plus 110 basis points”.Did investors ever ask why bondswiththeidenticalratingwereoffering90basispointsofadditionalyield,andwhere thatyieldmighthavebeencomingfrom? EvenattheheightoftheCDOmarket,itseems that the crowd was still quite wise. It may not have been the disciples of the Efficient MarketsHypothesisthatweremisledduringthesefrothytimes,butmorelikelythosewho wereconvincedtheyhaddiscoveredafreelunch. Rather than discarding rationality altogether, a more productive response may be to confront the inconsistencies between economic models of behavior and those from other disciplines—and attempttoreconcile them andimprove ourmodels intheprocess. While frustrating,contradictionsoftenpresentopportunitiesfordevelopingadeeperunderstanding 56Senior(2006). 40 57ofthephenomenainquestion. Inparticular,neuroscience,psychology,anthropology,sociology,andeconomicsallintersectwithr especttohumanbehavior,andwhenthesedisparate fieldssharethesameobjectofstudy,theirrespectivetheoriesmustbemutuallyconsistentin theirimplications. Forexample, neurophysiologicalmechanisms ofriskprocessingmustbe consistent with psychological experiments involving human subjects choosing among risky alternatives;otherwise,flawsexistinoneorbothofthesebodiesofknowledge.Byreconcilingtheinc onsistencies andcontradictions between disciplines, we candevelop abroader anddeeperunderstandingofHomosapiens. Thisapproachhighlightsthevalueof“consilience”,atermreintroducedintothepopular lexicon by the great evolutionary biologist E. O. Wilson (1998), who attributes its first usetoWilliamWhewell’s 1840treatiseThePhilosophyofthe InductiveSciences,inwhich Whewell wrote: “The Consilience of Inductions takes place when an Induction, obtained fromoneclass offacts, coincides withanInduction, obtainedfromanotherdifferent class. ThisConsilienceisatestofthetruthoftheTheoryinwhichitoccurs”. Inthischapter,I hopetohavefacilitatedtheconsiliencebetweenfinancialeconomicsandtheneurosciences. Fromtheneurosciencesperspective,itisnotsurprisingthattherehavebeen17bankingrelated national crises around the globe since 1974, the majority of which were preceded by periods of rising real-estate and stock prices, large capital inflows, and financial liberalization. Extended periods ofprosperity act as an anesthetic in the human brain, lulling investors, business leaders, and policymakers into a state of complacency, a drug-induced stuporthatcausesustotakerisksthatweknowweshouldavoid. Inthecaseofthe ¨uberfraudsterBernardMadoff,seasonedinvestorswereapparentlysuckedintothefrauddespite theirbetterjudgmentbecausetheyfoundhisreturnstootemptingtopassup. Inthecaseof subprimemortgages,homeownerswhoknewtheycouldnotaffordcertainhomesproceeded nonetheless,becausetheprospectoflivinglargeandhome-priceappreciationwastootemptingtop assup. Andinvestorsinmortgage-backedsecurities,whoknewthattheAAAratings weretoooptimisticgiventheriskiness oftheunderlyingcollateral,purchasedthesesecuri57Of course, in many cases, implications may not overlap. The particular biochemical structure of the neurotransmittersinvolvedinfearlearninghasnodirectbearingonthe behavioraloriginsoftime-varying stockmarketvolatility,socheckingforconsistencybetweentheformerandthelatterisunlikelytoyieldnew insights. Butforthoseareasinvolvingfundamentaldriversandmechanismsofhumanbehavior,opportunities forconsistencycheckswillariseoften,andweshouldtakeadvantageofthemwheneverpossible. 41 tiesanywaybecausetheyfoundthepromisedyieldsandpastreturnstootemptingtopass up. Ifweaddtothesetemptationsaperiodoffinancialgainthatanesthetizes thegeneral population—includingCEOs, chief risk officers, investors, regulators, andpoliticians—itis easy tosee how tulip bulbs, Internet stocks, gold, real estate, securitized debt, and fraudulent hedge funds could develop into bubbles. Such gains areunsustainable, and once the lossesstartmounting,ourfearcircuitrykicksinandpanicensues,aflight-to-safetyleading toamarketcrash. Thisiswherewearetoday. Likehurricanes,financialcrisesareaforceofnaturethatcannotbelegislatedaway,but wecangreatlyreducethedamagetheydowithproperpreparation. Inthelongrun,more transparencyintothe“shadowbankingsystem”,moreeducationforinvestors,policymakers, andbusiness leaders, andmorebehaviorallyorientedandadaptiveregulationwillallowus toweatheranytypeoffinancialcrisis. Regulationenablesustorestrainourbehaviorduring periodswhenweknowwe’llmisbehave; it’smostusefulduringperiodsofcollectivefearor greed and should be designed accordingly. Corporate governance should also be revisited fromthisperspective—if wetrulyvaluenaysayers duringperiodsofcorporateexcess, then weshouldinstitutemanagementchangestoprotectandrewardtheirindependence. With respect tothe future ofeconomics, E.O. Wilson (1998, p.182)makes athoughtprovokingobservationincomparingtherateofprogressinthemedicalvs. thesocialsciences: Thereisalsoprogressinthesocialsciences,butitismuchslower,andnotatall animatedbythesameinformationflowandoptimisticspirit... Thecrucialdifferencebetweenthetwodomainsisconsilience: Themedicalscienceshaveitandthesocialsciencesdonot. Medicalscientistsbuilduponacoherentfoundationofmolecularandcellbiology. Theypursueelementsofhealth andillnessallthewaydowntothelevelofbiophysicalchemistry... Socialscientistsbyandlargespurntheideaofthehierarchicalorderingofknowledgethat unitesanddrivesthenaturalsciences. Splitintoindependentcadres, theystressprecisioninwordswithintheirspecialtybutseldomspeakthesame technicallanguagefromonespecialtytothenext. Thisisabitterpillforeconomiststoswallow,butitprovidesacleardirectiveforimproving thestatusquo. Althougheconomicsoccupiesanenviablepositionamongthesocialsciences becauseof itsaxiomaticconsistency anduniformity, Homo economicus isafictionthatcannolonger bemaintainedinlightofmountingevidencetothecontraryfromalliedfieldslikepsychology 42 andthecognitiveneurosciences. Fordisciplinesinwhichcontrolledexperimentationispossible,consiliencemaybelesscriticaltopro gressbecauseinconsistenciescanbegeneratedand resolved within the discipline through clever experimental design. Butfordisciplines such asfinancialeconomicsinwhich controlledexperimentation ismorechallenging, consilience is an essential means for moving the field forward. Even in fields where experiments are routine,consilience canspeedupprogressdramatically. Therevolutioninpsychologythat transformedthefieldfromalooselyorganizedcollectionofinterestingandsuggestiveexperiments and hypotheses to a bona fide science occurred only within the last three decades, thankstosynergisticadvancesinneuroscience,medicine,computerscience,andevenevolutionar ybiology. Thiscouldbethefutureofeconomics. If “a crisis is a terrible thing to waste”, then we have a short window of opportunity beforeeconomicrecoverybeginstoweakenourresolvetoreformourintellectualframework and regulatory infrastructure for the better. The fact that time heals all wounds may be goodforourmentalhealth,butitmaynothelpmaintainoureconomicwealth. Policymakers shouldconsidertheparallelsbetweenAronRalston’spredicamentinBluejohnCanyonand thecurrenteconomicchallengestheyface. Whencaughtbetweenarockandahardplace, noonewants todowhat Ralstoneventually did; in fact, ittookhimfive days tocome to his fatefuldecision. The only way toachieve such anextraordinary outcome is todevelop a vision of an alternate reality so compelling that it can justify the magnitude of shorttermpainrequiredtoachieveit. Intheend,thisistheessenceofleadership—tounitethe populationinasharedvisionthatisfargreaterthanwhatindividualscouldachieveleftto theirowndevices. 43 References Abbe, E.,Khandani, A.,andLo,A., 2011,“Privacy-preserving measures ofsystemic risk inthefinancialsystem”,preprint,MITLaboratoryforFinancialEngineering. Baron-Cohen, S., 1989, “ The autistic child’s theory of mind: a case of specific developmentaldelay”,JournalofChildPsychologyandPsychiatry 30,285–297. Baumeister,R.F.,Heatherton,T.F.,andTice,D.M.,1994,Losingcontrol: Howandwhy peoplefailatself-regulation. SanDiego,CA:AcademicPress. Bechara, A., Damasio, A., Damasio, H., and Anderson, S., 1994, “Insensitivity to future consequencesfollowingdamagetohumanprefrontalcortex”,Cognition 50,7–15. Benartzi, S. and Thaler, R., 2004, “Save more tomorrow: Using behavioral economics to increaseemployeesavings”,JournalofPoliticalEconomy 112,S164–S187. Botvinick,M.,2008,“Hierarchicalmodelsofbehaviorandtheprefrontalfunction”,Trends inCognitiveNeuroscience 12,201–208. Breiter, Hans C., Aharon, I., Kahneman, D., Dale, A., and Shizgal, P., 2001, “Functional imaging of neural responses to expectancy and experience of monetary gains andlosses”,Neuron 30,619–639. Brennan,T.andLo,A.,2011,“Theoriginofbehavior”,Quarterly Journalof Finance 1, 55–108. Brown,C.andDinc,S.,2011,“Toomanytofail? Evidenceofregulatoryforbearancewhen thebankingsectorisweak”,ReviewofFinancialStudies 24,1378–1405. Camerer,C.,Loewenstein, G.,andPrelec, D.,2005,“Neuroeconomics: Howneuroscience caninformeconomics”,JournalofEconomicLiterature 43,9–64. Carlsson, A., Lindqvist, M., and Magnusson, T., 1957 “3,4-Dihydroxyphenylalanine and 5-hydroxytryptophanasreserpineantagonists”,Nature 180,1200. Coates,J.andHerbert,J.,2008,“Endogenoussteroidsandfinancialrisktakingonalondon tradingfloor”,ProceedingsoftheNationalAcademyofSciences 105,6167–6172. Cohen,A.andEinav,L.,2003,“Theeffectofmandatoryseatbeltlawsondrivingbehavior andtrafficfatalities”,ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics 85,828–843. Crandall,R.andGraham,J.,1984,“Automobilesafetyregulationandoffsettingbehavior: Somenewempiricalestimates”,AmericanEconomicReview 74,328–331. Damasio,A.R.,1994,Descartes’error: Emotion,reason,andthehumanbrain. NewYork: Putnam. 44 Damasio, A.R., Tranel, D. and Damasio, H., 1991, “Somatic markers and the guidance of behaviour: Theory and preliminary testing”, pp. 217–229, in H.S. Levin, H.M. Eisenberg, and A.L. Benton, eds., Frontal lobe function and dysfunction. New York: OxfordUniversityPress. Damasio, A., Tranel, D., and Damasio, H., 1998, “Somatic markers and the guidance of behavior”,inJenkins,J.M.,Oatley,K.,andStein,N.L.. HumanEmotions: AReader. Oxford: Blackwell,pp. 122–135. Danziger,S.,Levav,J.,andAvnaim-Pesso, L.,2011,“Extraneousfactorsinjudicialdecisions”,ProceedingsoftheNationalAcademyofScienc es 108,6889–6892. DeBecker,G.,1997,Thegiftoffear: Survivalsignalsthatprotectusfromviolence. Boston: LittleBrownandCo. Di Pellegrino, G., Fadiga, L. Fogassi, L., Gallese, V., and Rizzolatti, G., 1992, “Understandingmotorevents: Aneurophysiologicalstudy”,ExperimentalBrainResearch91, 176–180. Eisenberger, N., Lieberman, M. and Williams, K., 2003, “Does rejection hurt? An fMRI studyofsocialexclusion”,Science 302,290–292. Elster, J., 1998, “Emotions and economic theory”, Journal of Economic Literature 36, 47–74. Eslinger,P.andDamasio,A.,1985,“Severedisturbanceofhighercognitionafterbilateral frontallobeablation: PatientEVR”,Neurology 35,1731-1741. Espinosa-Vega,A.,Kahn,C.,Matta,R.,andSol´e, J.,2011,“Systemic RiskandOptimal RegulatoryArchitecture”,InternationalMonetaryFundWorkingPaperWP/11/193. Farmer,C.,Lund,A.,Trempel,R.andBraver,E.,1997,“Fatalcrashesofpassengervehicles beforeandafteraddingantilockbrakingsystems”, AccidentAnalysisandPrevention 29,745–757. Finger,S.,1994,OriginsofNeuroscience: AHistoryofExplorationsintoBrainFunction. NewYork: OxfordUniversityPress. Grossberg, S. and W. Gutowski, 1987, “Neural dynamics of decision making under risk: Affectivebalanceandcognitive-emotionalinteractions”,PsychologicalReview94,300– 318. Harlow, J.M., 1974,“Recovery aftersevere injurytothehead”inVanderKloot,W.G., Walcott, C., and Dane, B.. Readings in Behavior. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston,pp. 291–309. Huizinga, H.andLaeven, L., 2010, “Bankvaluationandregulatory forbearanceduringa financialcrisis”,EuropeanBankingCenterDiscussion PaperNo. 2009–17. Available atSSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1434359. 45 Jevons,W.S.,1871,Thetheoryofpoliticaleconomy. London: Macmillan. Kamstra,M.,Kramer,L.,andLevi,M.,2003,“Winterblues: Aeasonalaffectivedisorder (sad)andstockmarketreturns”,AmericanEconomicReview 93,324–343. Kapp, B.S., Frysinger, R.C., Gallagher, M., andHaselton, J.R.,1979,“Amygdala centralnucleus lesions: effects onheartrateconditioningintherabbit”, Physiology and Behavior 23,1109–17. Keynes,J.M.,1936,Thegeneraltheoryofemploymentinterestandmoney,republishedin 1960. NewYork: Harcourt,BraceandCo. Kinderman,P.,Dunbar,R.,andBentall,R.P.,1998,“Theoryofminddeficitsandcausal attributions”,BritishJournalofPsychology 89,191–204. Kindleberger, C., 1978, Manias, panics, and crashes: A history of financial crises. New York: BasicBooks. Kl ´ ’uver,H.andBucy,P.,1937,“Psychicblindness”andothersymptomsfollowingbilateral temporallobotomyinrhesusmonkeys”,AmericanJournalofPhysiology119,352–353. Knutson, B. and Bossaerts, P., 2007, “ Neural antecedents of financial decisions”, The JournalofNeuroscience 27,8174–8177. Kuhnen,C.M.andKnutson,B.,2005,“Theneuralbasisoffinancialrisktaking,Neuron 47,763–770. LeDoux,J.E.,1996Theemotionalbrain: Themysteriousunderpinningsofemotionallife. NewYork: Simon&Schuster. Lo, A., 1999, “The three P’s of total risk management”, Financial Analysts Journal 55, 13–26. Lo, A., 2004, “The adaptive markets hypothesis: Market efficiency from an evolutionary perspective”,JournalofPortfolioManagement30,15–29. Lo,A.,2005,“Reconcilingefficientmarketswithbehavioralfinance: Theadaptivemarkets hypothesis”,JournalofInvestmentConsulting7,21–44. Lo,A.,2010,“acompletetheoryofhumanbehavior”,AmericanEconomicAssociation,Ten YearsandBeyond: EconomistsAnswerNSF’sCallforLong-TermResearchAgendas. AvailableatSSRN:http://ssrn.com/abstract=1889318 Lo, A. and MacKinlay, C., 1999, A non-random walk down wall street. Princeton, NJ: PrincetonUniversityPress. Lo,A.andRepin,D.,2002,“Thepsychophysiologyofreal-timefinancialriskprocessing”, JournalofCognitiveNeuroscience 14,323–339. Lo, A., Repin, D. and Steenbarger, B., 2005, “Fear and greed in financial markets: An onlineclinicalstudy”,AmericanEconomicReview 95,352–359. 46 Loewenstein, G.,2000,“Emotionsineconomictheoryandeconomicbehavior”,American EconomicReview 90,426–432. Madrian,B.,andShea,D.,2001,“Thepowerofsuggestion: inertiain401(k)participation andsavingsbehavior”,QuarterlyJournalofEconomics 116,1149–1525. Montague,P.R.andBerns,G.S.,2002,“Neuraleconomicsandthebiologicalsubstratesof valuation”,Neuron 36,265–284. Olds, J., andMilner, P., 1954,“Positive reinforcement producedby electrical stimulation ofseptalareaandotherregionsofratbrain”,JournalofComparativePhysiologyand Psychology 47,419–427. Perner, J. and Wimmer, H., 1985, ““John thinks that Mary thinks that...” Attribution of second-order beliefs by 5- to 10-year-old children”, Journal of Experimental Child Psychology 39,437–471. Peters,E.andP.Slovic,2000,“Thespringsofaction: Affectiveandanalyticalinformation processinginchoice”,PersonalityandSocialPsychologyBulletin 26,1465–1475. Ralson,A.,2004,Betweenarockandahardplace. NewYork: AtriaBooks. Reinhart,CarmenM.,andKennethS.Rogoff,2009,Thistimeisdifferent: Eightcenturies offinancialfolly. Princeton,NJ:PrincetonUniversityPress. Rizzolatti, G. and Fabbri-Destro, M., 2010, “Mirror neurons, from discovery to autism”, ExperimentalBrainResearch 200,223–237. Rolls,E.,1990,“atheoryofemotion,anditsapplicationtounderstandingtheneuralbasis ofemotion”. CognitionandEmotion,4,161–190. Rolls,E.,1992,“Neurophysiologyandfunctionsoftheprimateamygdala”,inJ.Aggelton (ed.),theamygdala: Neurobiologicalaspectsofemotion,memory,andmentaldysfunction,pp.143–166. NewYork: JohnWiley&Sons. Rolls,E.,1994,“atheoryofemotionandconsciousness,anditsapplicationtounderstanding the neural basis of emotion, in M. Gazzaniga (ed.), The cognitive neurosciences, pp.1091–1106. Cambridge,MA:MITPress. Rolls,E.,1999,Thebrainandemotion. Oxford,UK:OxfordUniversityPress. Sacks,O.W.,1974,Awakenings. GardenCity,N.Y.: Doubleday. Saver,J.L.andDamasio,A.R.,1991,“Preservedaccessandprocessingofsocialknowledge inapatientwithacquiredsociopathyduetoventromedialfrontaldamage”,Neuropsychologia 29,1241–1249. Schoenemann, T., Sheehan, M., and Glotzer, D., 2005, “Prefrontal white matter is disproportionately larger in humans than in other primates”, Nature Neuroscience 8, 242–252. 47 Senior,C.,2006,“CDOsexplodeaftergrowinginterest”,FTMandate April. Shefrin,H.andThaler,R.,1988,“Thebehaviorallife-cyclehypothesis”,EconomicInquiry 26,609–643. Smaers, J., Steele, J., Case, C., Cowper, A., Amunts, K., and Zilles, K., 2011, “Primate prefrontalcortexevolution: Humanbrainsaretheextremeofalateralizedapetrend”, Brain,Behavior,andEvolution 77,67–78. Sobel, R. and Nesbit, T., 2007, “Automobile safety regulation and the incentive to drive recklessly: EvidencefromNASCAR”,SouthernEconomicJournal 74,71–84. Tierney,J.,2011,“Doyousufferfromdecisionfatigue?”,NewYorkTimes,August17. Wicker, B., Keysers, C., Plailly, J., Royet, J.-P., Gallese, V., and Rizzolatti, G., 2003, “Both of us disgusted in my insula: The common neural basis of seeing and feeling disgust”,Neuron 40,655–664. Wilson,E.,2000,Consilience: Theunityofknowledge. NewYork: AlfredA.Knopf. Williams,R.W.andHerrup,K.,1988,“Thecontrolofneuronnumber”,AnnualReviewof Neuroscience,11,423–453. Wright,P.,He,G.,Shapira,N.A.,Goodman,W.K.,andLiu,Y.,2004,“Disgustandthe insula: fMRIresponsestopicturesofmutilationandcontamination”,NeuroReport 15, 2347–2341. Zajonc, R., 1980, “Feelingandthinking: Preferences need noinferences”, American Psychologist 35,151–175. Zajonc,R.,1984,“Ontheprimacyofaffect”,AmericanPsychologist 39,117–123. 48