International Accounting Standards Board Comments on Exposure Draft ED/2010/1 Measurement of Liabilities in IAS 37 April 7, 2010 Dear Sir or Madam, As part of their Accounting Theory class, students at the University of Manitoba and I discussed the merits and pitfalls we saw in the Proposed Amendments to IAS 37. Our comments relate to the following four areas, which will be discussed in turn: 1) Measuring the contingent liability as the expected value of future cash outflows; 2) The measurement of outflows at the price at which an outside contractor would perform the service; 3) The mechanisms by which risk would be taken into account; and 4) The distinction between future events that should or should not be taken into account when assessing the liability. Briefly, we agreed with the Board’s treatment of the first two points, and disagreed with the latter two. Our major points are as follows: 1. Measuring the contingent liability as the expected value of future cash outflows We are in agreement with the Board’s conclusions that current practice should be clarified to recommend that entities measure the contingent liability as the expected value of future cash flows. This is the most conceptually correct measure for decision makers to use when assessing the future cash flows of the entity. We do not feel that the calculations are too complex. We understand that some decision makers could be confused by an expected value that is unlikely to be the actual realized value of the cash flows. However, if various contingent liabilities are aggregated this would not even be discernable to users. Furthermore, we suggest later (in issue 3), that the range of outcomes also be disclosed to users which will help them to understand the relationship between the expected value and the individual possible outcomes. Students also noted, however, that in some industries it may be overly difficult to perform an expected value calculation. In particular, many people feel quite comfortable identifying the minimum, maximum and most likely losses, but it may be very difficult and highly subjective to attach the probabilities to the outcomes required for the expected value calculation. We believe the Board should give consideration to whether it would be preferable in such a case to a) arbitrarily attach equal weights to the minimum, maximum and most likely losses and proceed with the expected value calculation; b) accrue the most likely loss; or c) disclose only, on the basis that the expected value is not measurable. 2. The measurement of outflows at the price at which an outside contractor would perform the service We agree with the Board’s views that measuring outflows for services at the price at which an outside contractor would perform the service is likely to reduce divergences in practice, thus improving comparability and reliability. Conceptually, we see that building a profit margin into these numbers is effectively taking into account an opportunity cost to the entity of deploying resources to satisfy these obligations rather than the entity’s usual pursuits. While this is somewhat new to GAAP as opportunity costs are theoretical costs, we see this as being consistent with new revenue recognition standards and conceptually reasonable. 3. Mechanisms by which risk would be taken into account We agree that providing information about risk is important to decision makers. We disagree with the recommendation that the amount of the liability be adjusted to reflect this risk for several reasons: First, risk is generally captured by the standard deviation of the distribution of outcomes. It is not statistically valid to change the mean (expected value) of the distribution as a means of capturing the standard deviation. That being said, one could argue that the committee is advocating an “expected utility” equivalent. For example, I might feel that while the expected value of a bet where I have a 10% chance of receiving $1,000 and a 90% chance of receiving nothing is $100, its equivalent value to me is the same as $85 for sure. That is, the expected value is adjusted to reflect the disutility of risk. There are two main difficulties of this approach. First, risk preferences are individual, so management of the entity may price risk differently than the financial statement users would. Secondly, from prospect theory, it is not clear that adding risk to a liability increases it, rather than decreases it. If people are asked to choose one option from Menu A, and one option from Menu B: Menu A: Menu B: Receive $100 for sure OR Give up $100 for sure OR 90% chance of 0, 10% chance of $1000 90% chance of 0, 10% chance of $1000 Many people will reliably pick the sure thing from Menu A, but the risky choice from Menu B. That is, with respect to losses, many people are risk SEEKING, so they may perceive a liability as being LESS onerous if there is a range of outcomes. This would argue for subtracting a risk adjustment from the expected value of the liability otherwise determined, rather than adding an adjustment. Perhaps similarly, it seems unintuitive to adjust a discount rate for risk by lowering it (which will give a higher liability value) rather than raising it. Finally, given that the adjustments seem quite arbitrary and not grounded in statistical reasoning, we feel that they would give unwarranted latitude to management to determine the amount of the liability, with little recourse for the auditors to disagree. As a result, we believe it would be preferable to recommend that entities disclose the range of outcomes to allow users to assess the risk and adjust the liability according to their own risk preferences. We also feel that this would be the preferable treatment as it would provide information to decision makers that would not otherwise be discernable. 4. The distinction between future events that should or should not be taken into account when assessing the liability As a group, we did not understand the distinction between future events that should be taken into account (those that might affect the outflow of resources required to fulfill the present obligation) versus those that should not be taken into account (those that change the nature of the obligation by changing, discharging or creating a new obligation). As an illustration, the Board suggested that management could consider advances in technology but not changes in legislation. The purpose of contingent liabilities is to enable an assessment of future cash flows, and the Board, in its basis for conclusions states that “the management of an entity knows more than the capital providers about the uncertainties surrounding a liability. So capital providers benefit from knowing the amount at which the management of an entity quantifies the entity’s obligations”. We did not understand the benefit of excluding the impact of certain future events and not others, and in fact thought that management may be better able to reliably assess future legislation more easily than future technology. We also were not confident that we would be able to sort other illustrative examples into the proper categories (those that change the amount of the cash flows versus those that change the obligation). Is the purpose of these provisions, and their support from respondents in the original exposure draft, to relieve entities of the obligation to consider future legislation on their current liabilities? If so, we believe that should simply be stated. If the purpose is in fact to make a general distinction between events that affect an assessment of cash flows versus events that change or discharge current obligations or create new obligations, we felt that we would be well served with more extensive explanations and more illustrations of the concept. We wondered if, for example, the Board would really wants to separate future events that either create or discharge a liability, from events that change a liability (i.e., it changes the cash flows attached to the liability). We would find that understandable – to summarize, it would involve changing events that “those that change the nature of the obligation by changing, discharging or creating a new obligation” to events that “those that change the nature of the obligation by changing, discharging or creating a new obligation We hope that you find these comments to be useful in your deliberations, and we thank you for the opportunity to respond to the exposure draft. Please do not hesitate to contact me if you require any further clarification or elaboration. Sincerely, Janet Morrill, Ph.D., C.A, C.G.A., I. H. Asper School of Business and students listed below: Ritchie Arthurson Michael Lindenburg Joseph Sitholé Lee Clement Sarah Norget Ying Tang Kyle Hirschfeld Michelle Pelech Melissa Yamada Nikita Klassen Jaclyn Sault Xiyin Li Anthony Sawatzky Yuhui Li Komaljeet Sidhu