Regional Trading Arrangements, Developing Countries and Deep Integration …or lessons from EU integration for LDCs …or implications for EU-LDC integration …or implications for the EU-ACP EPAs Michael Gasiorek Centre for the Analysis of Regional Integration at Sussex (CARIS) The EU “model” of integration • EU model: – shallow + deep integration single market – importance of competition and regulatory harmonisation – + priority given to economic convergence via • structural funds, • protection of key sectors (agriculture, textiles etc), • programs encouraging / allowing labour mobility • Note: – the EU model and advances in it has always been based on both economic and political imperatives. – the EU model is not simply a model of economic liberalisation. The reality has been much more complicated 2 EU as a good “reference model”? • For the transition economies? – the answer appears to be yes (FDI, trade, regulatory convergence etc) + adhesion has allowed them to adjust to the structural changes implied by “globalisation” (structural funds, migration etc) • South-South integration? – There are examples of EU style models eg. CARICOM / CSME, ECOWAS, but in reality much of the integration is largely shallow. • For EU-South integration. – The BIG difference here is that the model “worked” for the countries which were either members of the EU or were due to become members ie the transition economies. When adhesion is not on the agenda the viability of the model needs to be looked at more carefully. 3 Why sign an RTA with the EU? • RTA’s at a minimum involve the elimination of border barriers = shallow Integration. • As is well known the first order impact of this will depend on the balance of trade creation and trade diversion. • Empirical evidence (CGE & PE models, Sussex Framework) provides a pretty unanimous view on this: – Typically middling – high tariffs, very high NTBs with high peaks. – scope for trade creation relatively limited (eg. based on share of imports from EU + on degree of overlap in partner countries); – scope for trade diversion relatively high (again based on shares of trade from ROW countries, on degree of similarity in imports from ROW and EU, and on the number of industries where the EU can be seen as a sole supplier. – Therefore net effect very likely to be small if not negative 4 Ethiopian imports by source 100% 90% 24% 24% 27% 24% 21% 25% 29% 80% 70% 60% 50% 40% 12% 3% 10% 5% 5% 30% 20% 41% 27% 2% 6% 5% 6% 31% 14% 2% 10% 6% 7% 36% 7% 2% 7% SA+UAE+Yemen 12% Japan 14% China 25% 15% 2% 8% 8% 5% 4% 4% 7% 9% 5% 7% 9% 8% 31% 30% 31% 29% 2000 2001 2002 2003 23% 10% Rest of the World Neighbors USA EU 27 0% 1997 1998 1999 5 ECOWAS imports by source 100% 90% 25.3% 24.8% 4.5% 3.1% 1.9% 1.4% 8.4% 2.4% 4.1% 1.9% 11.6% 28.6% 28.4% 9.0% 3.0% 6.4% 3.1% 10.1% 5.2% 1.7% 4.8% 3.4% 80% 70% 60% 12.7% 50% 16.9% RoW US India China RoSSA 40% ECOWAS 30% 51.0% 20% 46.7% EU-15 39.8% 39.7% 2002 2004 10% 0% 1997 2000 6 why sign an EU-South RTA? • If effect is small / negative (+ if regionalism undermines multilateralism), why should LDCs sign RTA’s with the EU? So, other possible motivating factors include: – Maintain / make legally binding (as opposed to optional/ reversible as under GSP and EBA) existing preferential access to EU markets. – “Dynamic gains”: economies of scale, pro-competitive effect, technology transfer, FDI… Note: more likely to occur with “deep” integration: i.e. elimination of non-tariff impediments to trade / segmentation of markets. – As a means of locking in / legitimising domestic reforms – As a means for obtaining more assistance / financial aid from the EU. • Is any of the above enough to conclude that LDCs should seriously consider an RTA with the EU? 7 Re. Preferential access: • Given erosion of preference margins how significant is this in reality? – A key part of the “development” strategy of the EU towards LDCs is via the offering of preferential access to their markets. As the preference margins are eroded more thought / emphasis should be given to alternative ways of supporting development. • Small preference margins, however, can be significant in highly competitive markets. – there is a need for a clearer understanding of the sectors / products / countries for whom the margins really matter & why, and of the possible impact of preference erosion. • Making preference margins legally binding potentially important as it reduces uncertainty which can stimulate greater investment etc. However, in practice how often are these withdrawn? 8 Re: Dynamic gains + deep integration: Policy Areas Actions to be undertaken Standards: (SPS, TBT) harmonisation, certification, accreditation, MR. Investment rules on investment caps, removal of capital market restrictions, right of establishment IPR Patent legislation Trade facilitation Improvements in customs procedures, port / infrastructure facilities etc. Trade defence Reduction in protectionist use of anti-dumping, safeguard clauses etc Services Liberalisation of service provision; labour mobility Government procurement Allow for non-discriminatory open competitive tendering + dispute resolution Competition policy Legislation + regulatory action where required. 9 Sources of deep integration gains: • Technology spillovers (investment) • Increased FDI (role of investment rules, government procurement, competition policy, IPR) • Improved access to DC markets (eg. through improved standards regime, improved rules of origin, customs procedures) • Elimination of wasteful rent seeking (cf. government procurement) • Smithian specialisation gains, e.g. local economies of scale arising from specialising in different parts of the value chain (arising from common standards + preferential market access) • Externalities (standards, legal system, services, transport infrastructure) 10 Re: Locking in domestic reforms: • Signing agreements with legally binding provisions both with regard to – (a) trade liberalisation (tariffs, quotas etc), – (b) areas of deep integration can help to accelerate / facilitate the introduction of much needed domestic reforms. • e.g. EU-India - Indian’s appear to be primary demandeurs of the proposed FTA and much of the motivation appears to be to lock in domestic reforms. • Certain key reforms (eg. trade facilitation, application of international standards, government procurement rules) likely to apply ergo omnes to all trading partners. • Importance of the locking in of domestic reforms should not be underestimated 11 Re: aid / assistance from the EU. • Clearly an objective of LDCs re. the EPA negotiations. • From the EC point of view problematic as – (i) institutionally DG trade negotiates economic agreements, and DGDev deals with development assistance; – (ii) conceptually EC is strongly against the linkage of the two. • Re (ii). Fundamental misconception in the EC approach which seems to view the trade aspects of development as being about market access issues (ie the remit of DG trade), and therefore largely about border barriers. • For many LDCs the positive linkage between trade and development is to do with: – a) liberalising access to own markets + impediments to market access in the EU (standards, ROOs etc, EU subsidies) – b) supply side constraints in their own markets. – c) institutional constraints in their own economies. 12 Re: aid / assistance from the EU. • If the EU is serious about development it ought to be serious about linking trade agreements with trade related issues arising from (a), (b) and (c) above. – i.e. link trade agreements with trade related assistance which may require some form of conditionality. – Conditionality a sensitive topic. However need not be “imposed” but can arise from mutual identification of needs and sequencing of reforms which imply actions by both parties. – Also raises issues of “policy space”. • A la Rodrik countries need “policy space” to develop institutions suitable to their circumstances • but equally policy space can be used as an excuse not to engage in uncomfortable policies. – Therefore what is required is a careful balancing act between the two. – Trade related assistance should therefore focus on improving domestic conditions, improving access to EU markets + supporty fotr the adjustment costs (eg. fiscal transition programs) 13 ways forward…? • key constraint for many LDC’s is the lack of investment – changing the investment climate and the levels of investment is therefore absolutely crucial. • No point in engaging in shallow/deep integration unless country is “ready” in terms of: – physical infrastructure: roads, transport facilities, warehousing facilities, port facilities, customs procedures, telecoms etc. – institutional infrastructure: eg. financial and legal institutions – + some means of compensating the losers • Investment in these areas should be of the highest priority • “absorption capacity” v the need for more financing? • For many LDCs this will require technical & financial assistance trade related aid 14 And what else? • However, hard to develop long term competitive industries behind high tariff / non-tariff barriers. • engaging in trade liberalisation with themselves + the world at large important… eventually. • May be easier to achieve (politically & economically) regionally distortions and hence lower welfare gains. • the big gains will come from: – (a) much needed trade related domestic reforms + infrastructure (physical and institutional) upgrading – ie the deep integration elements outlined above; – (b) the locking in of those reforms; – (c) the likelihood that this will generate greater investment flows • This more likely to be achievable regionally regional integration with the EU could well be an important positive step for LDCs. • HOWEVER: important that the institutions / policies pursued by LDCs are appropriate to their needs. Eg. upgrading standards may give access to EU markets, but may not be desirable domestically; EU-style competition policy may not be appropriate etc. 15 Priorities First: – – – – Investment: policies + finance Infrastructure (physical + institutional) upgrading; trade facilitation Removal of developed country market access barriers (NTB’s, rules of origin) And only then… – – – Start to remove tariffs in domestic markets: regionally with the EU multilaterally Improve access to DC markets by upgrading standards capabilities where appropriate Competition policy Finally… – – – Government procurement IPR Trade defence 16 Conclusions: • EU experience successful: – has allowed for both shallow and deep integration + presence of explicit policies to encourage convergence – That has only been possible in the presence of an appropriate institutional and physical infrastructure. • For many LDCs that does not exist. for RTAs to be appropriate they have to find ways of delivering on: – Institutional / infrastructure upgrading – Convergence / mitigating against the adjustment costs implied by the policy process. • This can only happen if the agreements are trade-plus • And will require commitments and policy actions on the part of both the EU and partner countries. 17