Does Purchase Without Search Explain Counter Cyclic Pricing? January 18, 2015 Abstract Basic economic theory tells us to expect that an increase in demand should lead to an increase in price. However, studies have found the opposite trend in the prices of seasonal goods, such as canned soup. I propose an explanation of this phenomenon: consumers are more likely to purchase without search in low demand periods, reducing the gains of temporary price reductions, and decreasing estimated price sensitivity. Purchase without search is consistent with consumers using shopping lists to make their purchase decisions before observing prices. I test this explanation using a novel dynamic, structural inventory model where consumers make decisions on whether to search, which reveals price promotions, and which products to purchase given their search decision. I find that consumers with no inventory search for soup 39% of the time in winter, compared to 23% in summer. This causes price elasticities that are more than 64% larger in winter then they are in the summer. I find that the dominant cause of seasonal search is seasonal price variation, rather than seasonal consumption utility. 1 Introduction Basic economic theory tells us to expect that an increase in demand should lead to an increase in price. However, studies have found the opposite trend 1 in the prices of seasonal goods, such as beer, cheese, crackers, tuna, and my focal category of canned condensed soup, where prices have been observed to decrease in periods of high demand. This phenomenon has been termed “counter-cyclic pricing”. In this paper, I propose that counter-cyclic pricing is partially a reaction to seasonal changes in consumers’ propensity to make purchase decisions without searching the category. For example, shoppers who use a shopping list may choose both the variety and quantity of a good to purchase before observing prices at the store. An increase in purchases without search will increase average prices because non-searching consumers will not react to discounts, and so holding a sale will simply decrease the price that these consumers pay. I posit that consumers make a higher proportion of their purchases without search in low demand periods due to two seasonal changes in search incentives. First, the average purchase size is smaller, and so the expected savings resulting from finding a lower price are lower. Second, because the depth of discount is smaller in low demand periods, there is less reason to search for lower prices, which amplifies the first effect. Firms may react to this change in search behavior by offering larger discounts in high demand season. If only a portion of consumers search in each period, then firms can increase profits by offering stochastic discounts. More price sensitive consumers will be more likely to search and buy the cheapest product, while less price sensitive consumers will be more likely to pay full price. The cost of holding such promotions are the people who would have bought at 2 full price, but instead received a discount. In the low demand period, there is less search amongst those who buy, and therefore the relative cost of a price promotion is higher. Alternatively, an increase in search likelihood in high demand season could directly lead to larger discounts if firms are setting prices by measuring local price elasticities. Increasing promotional depth could result in a feedback loop by increasing search likelihood in turn, in which case the observed pricing strategy may in equilibrium. This paper estimates the consumer side of the model, while controlling for firms pricing strategy. Studying this phenomenon calls for a dynamic structural consumer inventory model for three reasons. First, the structural model weights the two seasonal changes in search incentives according to their value to consumers. This is a more restrictive approach than a reduced form model which might allow for search to be any combination of these factors. Second, due to the presence of counter cyclic pricing, the two changes in search incentives are correlated. A dynamic consumer inventory model can structurally account for both of these factors, and will discern the impact that each of these factors have on consumer search. Third, many seasonal products, including canned soup, are storable. Consumers may take advantage of temporary price reductions by “stocking up” for future consumption. In this case, a static model would overestimate price sensitivity because it would misinterpret inter-temporal substitution for an overall increase in demand. Studies have found that static models may overestimate price elasticities by as much 3 as 30% Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006). Furthermore, consumer inventories provide useful variation in search incentives because consumers with large inventories will be less likely to search. Several other explanations of this phenomenon have been put forward in the literature. While these explanations are contributors to counter-cyclic pricing in other contexts, they not fully explain the phenomena in the category of canned soup. Warner and Barsky (1995) first observed counter-cyclic pricing in retail and apparel stores, and proposed that it was caused by increased increased inter-store competition. However, in the case of consumer packaged goods, the potential savings are much smaller, which may make the cost of interstore price comparisons prohibitive. Chevalier et al. (2000) find counter cyclic pricing trends in consumer packaged goods, and show that these pricing trends are consistent with a loss-leader strategy, where the retailer lowers the price of goods to attract consumers to their store. However, in order to induce consumers to visit the store, the store Lal and Matutes (1994) must inform consumers of the lower prices through advertising, otherwise there is a hold-up problem. As such, loss leadering can explain all the featured promotions, but none of the non-featured promotions which account 71% of all promotions in my data. In a re-analysis of the data in Chevalier et al. (2000), Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006) find a seasonal trend in the aggregate price sensitivity of consumers, and argue that prices are higher during low demand periods because aggregate price sensitivity is lower. They propose several explanations of 4 this trend in price sensitivity. This paper compliments there findings. Where Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006) discover the trend in price sensitivity, this paper presents a new, search-based explanation of the trend. One of the explanations provided by Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006) was that changes in price sensitivity are caused by consumer heterogeneity, which was formalized in Guler et al. (2014)1 . In this model, there are consumers have either a “high” and “low” valuation of the product, and during low demand season the “low” types drop out of the market, leaving only the less price sensitive “high” types. This explains both counter-cyclic pricing and seasonality in estimated price sensitivity. However, the data I analyze supports the search explanation in three ways. First, I find that the seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity does not dissipate when controlling for consumer heterogeneity using a proxy. Second, I find that consumers making larger purchases have a higher estimated price sensitivity. In the heterogeneity explanation consumers buying large quantities would be more likely to be “high” types, and therefore should have a lower estimated price sensitivity. Finally, I fit a structural dynamic models routed in each explanations, and find the search model fits the data better despite having fewer parameters. Consumers strategically purchasing without observing prices has important implications beyond counter-cyclic pricing. Retailers can change the frequency of consumer search by altering their pricing strategy. For example, rational consumers will respond to a reduction in price variation by 1 Bayot and Caminade (2014) empirically tests a similar model 5 searching less frequently, which may reduce their estimated price sensitivity. Counter-cyclic pricing and seasonality provides a unique opportunity to study strategic search because it provides exogenous variation in search incentives throughout the year. This variation allows me to demonstrate strategic consumer search, which practitioners can account for when designing promotional strategies. The results also provide a structural explanation to the findings of Mela et al. (1998), who show that over time, consumers exposed to an increase in promotional depth become more price sensitive. The structural framework developed here can allow other researchers and practitioners to control for this effect when designing pricing schemes. The structural model is motivated by four descriptive analyses of a panel data on canned soup purchases. First, I find in my data that the concentrated soup industry, exhibits counter-cyclic pricing. Second, I replicate the findings of Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006) by showing a significant seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity. Third, I find some evidence that consumers occasionally purchase without search by showing that purchase quantity increases estimated price sensitivity. This may be because consumers who purchase small quantities are less likely to have searched, and thus more likely to purchase without search. Fourth, I find that the seasonal trend in aggregate price sensitivity positively correlates with seasonal trends in both overall volume sold and price variation. Both seasonality and price variation serve as proxies for search likelihood if consumers are strategically searching. Estimating this model using standard dynamic methods presents a com6 putational challenge because seasonal shifts in consumption utility, price expectations, and search probabilities require an expanded state space. The inclusion of these trends in the model necessitates that I solve for expected discounted payoffs separately for each seasonal period, which increases the size of the state space by a factor of 52, one for each week of the year. To allow the seasonal period to be added to the state space at no additional computational cost, I use the Cyclic Successive Approximation Algorithm of Haviv (2015). This paper fits a dynamic consumer inventory model, following Erdem et al. (2003), and Hendel and Nevo (2006). By assuming consumers do not observe prices of all products in each period, I follow the price consideration model of Ching et al. (2009), and the structural search models presented in Seiler (2013), and Honka (2012). However, in those models, consumers must observe prices before making a purchase. In allowing consumers to selectively ignore price information, I follow the econometric framework of Mehta et al. (2003), and the descriptive evidence of Ray et al. (2012) and Murthi and Rao (2012). Specifically, in my model, consumers respond to an increase in price variation by searching more frequently. Consumers can choose whether to search, in which case they react to prices, or to purchase without search, in which case they are not price sensitive. In this respect, the estimated model can be considered a structural, dynamic implementation of the models in Bucklin and Lattin (1991) and Katz (1984), that allows for the size of the “planned” and “opportunistic” segments to endogenously depend on search 7 incentives. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: in Section 2, I describe the data set and report summary statistics; in Section 3, I present descriptive and static evidence consistent with the existence of counter-cyclic pricing and seasonal trends in purchase without search; in Section 4, I detail the dynamic, structural inventory model of the concentrated soup industry which allows consumers to purchase without search; in Section 5, I outline the estimation procedure; in Section 6, I present the results of the estimation; and in Section 7, I conclude. 2 Data This project used the panel data in the “IRI Marketing Data Set” Bronnenberg et al. (2008). Panel data on consumers in Eau Claire, Wisconsin and Pittsfield, Massachusetts is reported for 30 categories over the seven years from January 1st, 2000 to December, 31st 2006. I focus on the purchases of concentrated soup to study counter-cyclic pricing trends for four reasons. First, the concentrated soup category clearly exhibits strong seasonality, with purchase volume rising dramatically in the winter. Second, the category exhibits counter-cyclic pricing trends. Third, in the data I analyze, concentrated soup is highly concentrated, with Campbell’s having more than a 84% market share, and the remainder being a private label. This simplifies the pricing problem the retailer and manufacturer face. 8 Fourth, concentrated soup is purchased almost exclusively in 10.75 oz. cans, which are typically consumed in one sitting. This limits consumer inventories to a discrete number of cans, which simplifies the construction of the dynamic model. The data set initially has 10,157 panelists. I analyze a single store to ensure that the price distribution is constructed accurately. Accurately estimating the price distribution is important because consumers partially base their search decision on it. However, I use all purchase data when constructing consumer inventories to ensure that my sample limitation does not bias the estimated inventories. I choose the store with largest number of concentrated soup purchases in the sample, located in Pittsfield, Massachusetts. My dataset is comprised of the 3,045 panelists make purchases at this store. The panel is unbalanced: participants participate for an average of 3.04 years. The data was collected in two ways: For 87% of panelists, purchases were recorded electronically when the panelist used a loyalty card at check out. In addition to using the loyalty card, 2% of panelists used a “key”, which allowed them to electronically scan their own purchases. 10% of panelists switched from using a key to using a loyalty card over the course of the sample. Consumers purchase concentrated soup corresponding to 116 Universal Product Codes (UPC) in this panel data. I only observe the price of a UPC in weeks where a purchase is made. To ensure that the price series for each UPC I analyze can be accurately extracted from the data, I focus on the top 9 ten best selling UPCs, which represent 57% of observed sales. For each week, I identify the price of each UPC by looking at the dollars spent and the units purchased by panelists. The non-discounted price of each UPC is not explicitly observed. I calculate the non-discounted price in two ways. First, I treat price increases as permanent, which is consistent with the observed price series. Second, I consider any price that persists for 5 weeks to be the permanent price. The market shares and summary statistics of these UPCs are presented in Table 1. The week-to-week price of each flavor changes in 22% of weeks. UPCs tend not to go on sale at the same time: 49% of weeks where discounts are available have only 2 or fewer UPCs discounted. This variation in prices, across weeks and across varieties, creates the incentive to search: consumers who search can purchase one of the few discounted UPCs. Consumers will buy multiple UPCs in 17% of weeks. UPC Number 15100000011 15100001251 15100001261 8849999857472 15100001031 15100001541 8849999857432 15100001051 8849999857515 15100001231 Corresponding Flavor Tomato Chicken Noodle Cream of Mushroom (1) Cream of Mushroom (2) Cream of Chicken (1) Chicken and Stars Cream Of Chicken (2) Chicken and Rice Tomato (2) Vegetable Beef Market Share 32% 23% 13% 8% 5% 4% 4% 3% 3% 3% Average Price 0.67 0.81 0.92 0.71 1.17 1.19 0.69 1.22 0.5 1.23 Discount Frequency 13% 13% 10% 45% 15% 12% 39% 5% 33% 2% Table 1: Flavor Summary Statistics 10 Average Discount 0.15 0.25 0.24 0.14 0.49 0.39 0.18 0.44 0.07 0.42 3 Static Evidence In this section, I provide some descriptive evidence suggesting that countercyclic pricing is caused by seasonality in purchase without search. This will highlight trends in the data that allow me to identify the parameters of the dynamic model, and motivate its structure. 3.1 Seasonality and Counter Cyclic Pricing Counter-cyclic pricing denotes the simultaneous presence of three patterns in the category sales data: seasonal demand trends, seasonal pricing trends, and a negative correlation between these two trends. One might expect soup to be consumed more often during cold weather, or to help soothe a sore throat, both of which are more common in the winter months. This trend is typified by the sales data presented in Figure 7, where the demand for soup is highest during the winter and lowest during the summer. I found this trend to be statistically significant by regressing average weekly sales onto a 4-degree polynomial based on the time of year (Table 2, Column 1). Accurately estimating underlying seasonality requires controlling for price promotions. Seasonal promotional trends may amplify or cause the observed seasonal demand trends because increased demand is a natural consequence of reduced prices. I focus on price promotions, rather than permanent price changes, because permanent price changes are both rare 2 Permanent price changes occur in less than 2% of periods. 11 2 and highly corre- lated across UPCs. I treat these price changes as an inflationary factor that affects both concentrated soup and outside goods. The seasonal promotional trend in the category is statistically significant (Table 2, Column 4), and can be seen in Figure 7, which plots the average discount over the course of the year. In contrast to quantity demanded, the average discount is lowest during the summer months and highest during the winter months. To demonstrate the correlation between underlying demand and prices, I construct a descriptive estimate of the underlying demand from the polynomial in Table 2, Column 3. The relationship between this measure of underlying demand and the average discount offered by the retailer in each week is shown to be positive and significant (Table 2, Column 5), which is consistent with counter-cyclic pricing. 3.2 Seasonality in Estimated Price Sensitivity Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006) found that counter-cyclic pricing is induced by a simultaneous trend in consumer price sensitivity. They observe a reduction in aggregate price sensitivity in low demand periods. I find evidence of this trend in the IRI data by using a logit model to predict consumers’ flavor decisions over the course of the year. Hendel and Nevo (2006) show that if a shopper’s consumption does not depend on the flavor purchased, then the flavor decision in a dynamic inventory model simplifies to a logit model, which can be estimated by using static maximum likelihood. I use this model 12 Table 2: Descriptive Regression Results Average Weekly Units Sold (1) Week In Year - Linear Week In Year - Quadratic Week In Year - Cubic Week In Year - Quartic (2) (3) (4) 0.005 (0.003) −0.0005∗∗ (0.0002) 0.00002∗∗ (0.00001) −0.0000001∗∗ (0.0000001) 1, 277.373∗∗∗ (166.187) −13.192 (8.790) −0.408 (0.666) 0.034∗ (0.019) −0.0004∗∗ (0.0002) 1, 008.639∗∗∗ (153.465) −8.599 (9.263) −0.895 (0.700) 0.049∗∗ (0.020) −0.001∗∗∗ (0.0002) Discount Discount Reduced Form Demand Constant R2 369.495∗∗∗ (36.214) 0.234 196.062∗∗∗ (8.173) 0.140 350.319∗∗∗ (34.380) 0.317 0.019 (0.012) 0.058 (5) 0.0001∗∗∗ (0.00004) 0.046∗∗∗ (0.006) 0.034 to identify flavor preferences and estimate price sensitivity over the course of the year. Suppose that the utility gained for purchasing a product of flavor ft is given by: αst pf t + α2 p2f t + ηf + εf t where αst is the price sensitivity in seasonal period st , pf t is the price of flavor f at time t, ηf is the flavor dummy, and εf t is an IID shock with a type-1 extreme value distribution. Then, assuming consumers are utility maximizing and comparing the market shares of each flavor in each period, we have 2 eαst pf t +α2 pf t +ηf P (f |p, s) = P α p 0 +α p2 +η 0 . e st f t 2 f 0 t f f 0 ∈F 13 where P (f |p, s) is the market share of flavor f conditional on purchase. This equation can be estimated using maximum likelihood. I approximate the seasonal price coefficient αst with a 4-degree polynomial based on time of year. Consistent with Nevo and Hatzitaskos (2006), I find a statistically significant seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity that is high during winter and low during summer (Figure 7)(Table 3, Column 1). I propose that this seasonal trend is caused by seasonal search patterns, which would cause each consumer to appear more price sensitive when search incentives are high. This trend is not explained by Warner and Barsky (1995), because the change in estimated price sensitivity is observed when comparing the alternatives at a single store, rather than the alternatives between stores. An alternative explanation of this trend appears in Guler et al. (2014), who explain the phenomenon by suggesting that the price sensitivity is due to consumer heterogeneity. That is, during high demand season, price sensitive consumers enter the market. To test if this would explain the observed trend in price sensitivity, I split the consumers in my sample into high and low price sensitivity segments using a median split based on a proxy3 . I then re-estimated the above analysis while allowing each segment to have a different baseline price sensitivity. If the dominant cause of seasonality in price sensitivity was heterogeneity, then controlling for heterogeneity should mute the observed seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity. I find that 3 I proxied the price sensitivity of each consumer by calculating how likely they were to choose the lowest priced can of soup when purchasing. Consumers who are more price sensitive should be more likely to select the lowest priced can of soup 14 the trend in price sensitivity persists, and is of a similar magnitude when controlling for this heterogenity: estimated price sensitivity seasonally shifts by −1.28 when I don’t control for seasonality, and seasonally shifts by −1.236 when I do (Table 3, Column 3). Alternatively, a seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity could be due to a non-linear price response. If consumers become are more price sensitive when there are larger discounts, then they will be more price sensitive in the winter when discounts are large. To account for this possibility, I allow the response to prices to be nonlinear throughout by including a quadratic term (α2 above). The seasonality in price sensitivity persists when controlling for a non-linear response to prices. 3.3 Purchase Without Search Purchase without search cannot be directly identified because I do not observe whether shoppers check prices in any given period. However, I do observe three patterns in the data supporting the existence of purchase without search. The more frequently consumers purchase without search, the lower their estimated price sensitivity will be, because consumers need to observe prices in order to react to them. Therefore, if consumers strategically decide to sometimes purchase without search, then factors that affect the likelihood that search occurred, such as search incentives or search costs, will affect estimated price sensitivity. I find that three such factors have a significant effect on estimated price sensitivity: aggregate demand, promotional depth, 15 and number of units purchased. First, if consumers search strategically, they are more likely to choose to observe prices when there are larger incentives to do so. Consumers would then be more likely to search when they have a larger expected purchase size because a lower price would yield greater expected savings. Because the number of consumers in the panel is constant over the course of the year, this would induce a correlation between estimated price sensitivity and expected aggregate demand in that time of year. Using the estimated price sensitivity in Table 3, Column 2, I estimate this correlation to be -0.592 (p > 0.0001). Second, consumers who search strategically would also be more likely to search when there they expect larger promotions, because they want to take advantage of bigger discounts. This would induce a correlation between average promotional depth and estimated price sensitivity. Consistent with purchase without search, I find that the seasonal trend in estimated price sensitivity is significantly correlated with the trend in average promotion depth estimated in table 2, Column 4 (cor = −0.326, p < 0.01859). Third, consumers are more likely to purchase a large quantity of soup when they’ve found a good discount. If they’ve found a good discount, and can change their purchase decision based on that discount, they must have checked prices. This leads to a correlation between search likelihood and the number of units purchased. Since search likelihood correlates to with both estimated price sensitivity, and units purchased, if consumers sometimes purchase without search there should be a relationship between the number of 16 units purchased and estimated price sensitivity. I test for this by separately calculating market shares for single unit and multiple unit purchases, and comparing how these market shares react to price changes. I then repeat the estimation in the previous section, but allow price sensitivity to change if the consumer purchases multiple units. I find that buying multiple units increases estimated price sensitivity by 1.58 (Table 3, Column 2). This result is maintained when I also control for the proxy for price sensitivity (Table 3, Column 5). Furthermore, I reran all of these analyses while controlling for seasonal UPC preferences, and while allowing for a more flexible response to price changes by using a 4-degree polynomial. All the reported trends hold and have a similar magnitude. Table 3: Reduced Form Results Price Price×Week Price×Week2 Price×Week3 Price×Week4 (1) (2) (3) (4) −7.6853∗∗∗ (0.0001) −0.2007∗∗∗ (0.0001) 0.0214∗∗∗ (0.0009) −0.00063∗∗∗ (0.0000) 5.63 × 10−6∗∗∗ (5.14 × 10−7 ) −6.8224∗∗∗ (0.0108) −0.2031∗∗∗ (0.0259) 0.0195∗∗∗ (0.0031) −0.0005∗∗∗ (0.0001) 4.67 × 10−6∗∗∗ (1.05 × 10−6 ) −1.5838∗∗∗ (0.0271) −7.0261∗∗∗ (0.267) −0.1632∗∗∗ (0.0003) 0.0186∗∗∗ (0.0009) −0.0006∗∗∗ (0.0000) 5.01 × 10−6∗∗∗ (5.23 × 10−7 ) −5.7127∗∗∗ (0.0000) −0.1843∗∗∗ (0.0000) 0.200∗∗∗ (0.0007) −0.0006∗∗∗ (0.0000) Multi-Unit Purchase×Price Price Sens Consumer×Price −1.3732∗∗∗ (0.0000) −1.5051∗∗∗ (0.0001) −1.1361∗∗∗ (0.0000) 9.3843∗∗∗ (0.001) −0.2320∗∗∗ (0.0000) 9.5457∗∗∗ (0.0000) Price Sens Consumer× Multi-Unit Purchase Price2 9.5177∗∗∗ (0.0002) 9.9329∗∗∗ (0.0102) UPC Fixed Effects Omitted. 17 3.4 Evidence of Stockpiling Consumers can stockpile canned soup easily because it will not spoil for a long time (over a year), and because the packaging allows easy stacking. Hendel and Nevo (2006) shows that if consumers stockpile, then estimating a static model will lead to biased price elasticities. These storage dynamics are what necessitate the dynamic model. To confirm that consumers are stockpiling in this category, I look for a relationship between the number of units a consumer purchases, and the time until their next purchase. If consumers are stockpiling, then a consumer buying a large number of units may delay their next purchase. I find that each additional can of soup purchased delays the next purchase by 2.3 days4 when controlling for seasonality (Table 4). 4 Model I model purchases in the concentrated soup industry using a dynamic, structural, inventory model. The model is dynamic because shoppers make decisions while taking into account price expectations, consumption probabilities, and inventories in the subsequent periods. Each week, consumers make decisions in four sequential stages: search, quantity, flavor, and consumption. In the search stage, consumers first exogenously decide whether they will visit the store in the current period. If 4 From the regression in table 4, Column 2 each unit purchased delays the next purchase by 0.328 weeks. 18 Table 4: Interpurchase Time Regressions Interpurchase Time (Weeks) Units Purchased (1) (2) 0.345∗∗∗ (0.086) 0.328∗∗∗ (0.086) Week 0.187 (0.225) Week2 −0.019 (0.018) Week3 3.195 × 10−2 (5.08 × 10−4 ) Week4 −1.24 × 10−7 (4.78 × 10−6 ) Constant Observations R2 15.557∗∗∗ (0.293) 16.316∗∗∗ (0.866) 27, 325 0.001 27, 325 0.003 consumers don’t visit the store, they go straight to the consumption stage. If they do visit the store, they then decide whether to search the category before making their quantity and flavor decisions. If the consumers search, they incur a search cost but observe the prices of all varieties. If consumers do not search, they instead make their quantity and flavor decisions while assuming there are no price promotions. In the quantity stage, consumers decide on the quantity they want to purchase. When making this decision, consumers take into account the amount of soup in their inventory, and how likely they are to consume soup in this seasonal period. Consumers can (and frequently do) choose to purchase no soup in this stage of the model. In the flavor stage, consumers sequentially decide which flavors they will 19 purchase. In other frameworks, these decisions are made at the same time as the quantity decision. However, the formulation used has two important properties. First, it allows consumers to purchase different varieties in a single period, which to my knowledge has not been possible in previous inventory models, and is a feature of the canned soup industry. Second, it allows me to estimate the flavor fixed effects separately from the dynamic model. 5 Finally, in the consumption stage, soup is consumed from consumer inventories. The probability that the consumer wants a can of soup varies by time of year because soup is a seasonal good. I outline the model in the following three steps. First, I define the utility that a consumer receives in each stage of the model. Second, I define the expected discounted payoffs and Bellman equation for the problem, which are used to calculate the likelihood. Third, I formally define the choice that a consumer makes in each stage, solve for the probability of any particular choice, and calculate the expected discounted payoffs the consumer receives during the current stage, any remaining stages, and all subsequent periods. 4.1 Flow Utility Consumers receive utility based on their decisions in each of the four stages of the model. For notational convenience, I omit the time subscript t from 5 One additional assumption required here is that consumers observe the prices of the cans of soup they purchase, and put back any cans that have had a large price increase. This could happen as they put the can in their cart, or at check out. This does not affect the estimation because firms are never observed to do this, but it does explain why firms don’t set arbitrarily high prices if consumers sometimes purchase without checking prices. 20 all variables. 4.1.1 Search Stage Consumers visit the store with exogenous probability Pv (s), where s is the seasonal period. If consumers visit the store, then the utility they receive during the search stage is specified as: us (r; εs , ε0s ) = 1(r = 1)(−ρ + εs ) + 1(r = 0)(ε0s ) (1) where r is an indicator variable that equals 1 if the consumer searches and is 0 otherwise, ρ is the search cost, εs and ε0s are random shocks that have an IID type-1 extreme value distribution with standard deviation σεs . 4.1.2 Quantity Stage Consumers receive the following utility for purchasing q cans of soup − uq (q, → εq ) = ηq + εq (2) where q is the number of cans of soup purchased, ηq is a quantity fixed effect, and εq is an IID shock a type-1 extreme value distribution with standard deviation σεq . For each can purchased, the consumer selects a flavor in the next stage of the model, which is where flavor preference and prices directly impact utility. As shown in the section on the decision at the quantity stage, prices will impact the quantity purchased. 21 4.1.3 Flavor Stage Consumers receive the following utility for purchasing a can of flavor f soup as their w purchase. 2 uf (fw ; p, − ε→ fw ) = α1 pfw + α2 pfw + ηfw + εfw (3) where fw is the flavor chosen for purchase w, − ε→ fw is a vector of shocks, α1 and α2 are price sensitivity parameters, p is a vector of prices, pfw is the price of flavor fw , ηfw is a flavor fixed effect, and εfw is an IID shock with a type-1 extreme value distribution with standard deviation σεf . I use a quadratic response to prices to account for the possibility that the seasonal variation in price sensitivity is caused by a non-linear response to price changes, as discussed previously. 4.1.4 Consumption Stage In the consumption stage, consumers will attempt to consume soup up to their randomly distributed desired consumption d, which is assumed to have a geometric distribution with a probability parameter of Pd (s). Consumers can only consume soup from their total available inventory after purchases, which is the sum of their initial inventory i and their purchase quantity q. Consumers receive the following utility for this consumption: uc (c) = k × c 22 (4) where k is the utility received per can of soup consumed, and c is the quantity of soup consumed. Seasonal variation in consumption is modelled through variations in Pd (s) throughout the year. Note that consumption utility only depends on the number of cans consumed, and not the flavor of those cans. Instead, flavor preferences are modelled in the purchase decision with a fixed effect. This assumption allows me to separate the flavor decision from dynamic considerations because the flavor decision now only affects the static utility in the purchase stage. This reduces the size of the state space because only the total number of cans of soup in inventory need to be tracked from period to period, rather than the number of cans of each flavor. 4.2 State Variables and Value Functions The model has two persistent state variables: seasonal period, and inventory level. In the model, the seasonal period affects the probability of visiting the store, the probability of consumption, and price expectations. The seasonal period is a cyclic state variable that represents the time of year, which updates deterministically as follows: st+1 = s + 1 if s < |S| = 1 if s = |S| 23 where |S| is the total number of seasonal periods. The deterministic updating of this state variable allows me to apply the cyclic successive approximation algorithm of ?, which removes the computational burden of adding this state variable to the dynamic model. This algorithm reduced the cost of solving for the value function by a factor of 52. The inventory levels are increased through purchase, and decreased through consumption: it+1 = it + qt − ct At any point, consumers can have at most imax cans of soup in their inventory. In the model inventory level affects the need for purchase. If a consumer has canned soup in inventory, they are more likely delay their purchase until they find a price promotion. Because consumers are forward looking, they consider how their decisions impact their expected discount future utility. Formally, consumers seek to maximize their expected discounted utility in each period. Let Ω be a vector of all of the transient state variables − εq , − ε→ Ω = (Pv (s), εs , ε0s , p, → fw , Pd (s)), and let a be the vector of the actions a consumer can take a = (r, f, q, c). I define the total utility that a consumer receives in period t as u(a, s, i, Ω). Note that consumers do not observe all the state variables simultaneously; each of the IID shocks and the desired consumption are revealed in their respective stage in the model. Consumers make their decisions to maximize their total expected discounted payoff given starting persistent states s and i, which can be conveniently expressed in the 24 following integrated Bellman equation: V (s, i) = E(max u(aτ , sτ , iτ , Ωτ ) + δE(VΩ (st+1 , it+1 , Ωt+1 )|s, i, Ω)) a (5) where δ is the discount factor. This integrated Bellman equation will allow me to solve for the value function, which is required to estimate the model. The formal derivation of the consumer decisions at each stage and the overall likelihood are derived in an online appendix. 5 Estimation 5.1 Identification I provide an informal discussion of the identification of the parameters of the model by going backwards through the stages of the model. In the consumption stage, I identify consumption probability by time of year Pd (s) by the seasonal variation in overall purchase quantity. Consumers should try to keep their inventories low because of the discount factor, and because they want to be able to take advantage of future sales. After controlling for price variation, consumers should then purchase more soup when their consumption probability is high. The utility of consuming a can of soup k is identified by the aggregate number of purchases consumers make. The more soup consumers purchase, the higher the consumption utility they receive. In the flavor stage, the flavor fixed effects ηf are identified by comparing 25 the sales of different flavors when they are not discounted. As discussed in the next section, the relative market shares of undiscounted flavors will identify the flavor fixed effects. The price sensitivity parameter α can be identified by investigating flavor choices in purchases that are very likely to have been searched: for example, consumers who purchase 4 cans of soup during winter. As search probability goes to 1, the flavor decision becomes a standard logit choice model, and we can identify the price sensitivity by how the market share of each flavor reacts to changes in price. In the quantity stage, the variation in the quantity shock σq is identified by the relationship between discounts and purchase quantity. If discounts have a large role in determining purchase quantity, then random shocks play a relatively smaller role, and so σq will be smaller. The quantity fixed effects represent consumers’ preference for buying ηq different numbers of cans. This is identified by the frequency of purchase sizes. For example, this parameter captures that consumers prefer to buy cans of soup in even numbers. In the search stage, the parameter ση represents the week to week variation in search costs, and is identified using the correlation of seasonal trends in price sensitivity with seasonal changes in consumption probability and price expectations. If price sensitivity has a close relationship with search incentives, then ση will be small, and if price sensitivity does not react to changes in search incentives, then the decision is more random and so ση will be large. The search cost ρ shifts the probability of search across the entire year, and is identified by comparing each purchase to both an unsearched 26 purchase, and a searched purchase. Several parameters in the model are not directly identified, and must be set at fixed levels. Because this is a utility model, the parameters are only identified to a multiplicative and addititive constant. As a result, I normalize the standard deviation of the flavor shock σf to 1. Similarly, I normalize the utility of purchasing one can of the most popular flavor to 0. Neither the discount factor nor price expectations are not identified in the dynamic model. I set the weekly discount factor to .99 per week. I set the largest possible inventory, imax , to be 4. The model is estimated on weekly data, with seasonal periods |S| numbering 52. Price expectations are also not identified in the data. I assume that consumers draw from the empirical distribution of prices within a month of the current week. That is, a consumer in the first week of July will have a price distribution based on the observed prices between the first week in June and the first week in August in any year. 5.2 Estimation Assumptions To ensure inventories are unbiased, I initialize consumers as starting with 0 inventory, and remove the first year of data as ’burn-in’. I also remove records where consumers don’t purchase canned soup for a full year. While it is theoretically possible to estimate the desired consumption probability Pd (s) for each seasonal period s, this would result in a large increase in the parameter space, and there likely isn’t the data to identify each Pd (s) separately. To 27 accommodate this, I assume a functional form for Pd (s) based on four parameters which represent consumption probability every three months: Pd (1), Pd (14), Pd (27), and Pd (40). I then assume that Pd (s) is a linear combination of the two closest parameters. For example, the consumption probability in week 3 would then be P3 (3) = Pd (1) + 3 (Pd (14) 13 − Pd (1)). The advantage of this specification is threefold. First, it drastically reduces the number of consumption probabilities to estimate. Second, the resulting parameter estimates are easily interpretable. Third, it allows for consumption probabilities to change smoothly across and between years. The weakness of this specification is that it imposes that the largest and smallest consumption probability will occur in week 1, 14, 27, or 40. The UPC fixed effects are estimated statically by comparing the market shares of products that are not on discount. The details of this estimation are provided in an online appendix. 6 6.1 Results Dynamic Estimation Results The results of the dynamic model are presented in Table 5. 6.1.1 Search Stage Consumers in the search stage first exogenously decide to visit the store, which varies based on the seasonal period. I find that the probability of visiting this store tends to increase over the course of the year, with the 28 exception of a drop in August. One would expect that a decrease in the probability of visiting a store would lead to an increase in stockpiling behavior because consumers will have to wait longer before they restock their inventory. Search costs are found to be positive at 1.6409. In dollar terms, the search cost is equivalent to a discount of $.0369. Search probability varies substantially over the course of the year. Search is highest in late November, when a consumer with no inventory will search 38.8% of the time, and is at its lowest in mid-summer, when consumers only search 23.1% of the time (Figure 7). Seasonal changes in the expected gains of search, which vary between 6.02 in late November and 2.25 in mid-summer for a consumer with no inventory, drive this variation in search. Changes in price expectations and in expected purchase size drive the shift in expected gains. 6.1.2 Flavor and Quantity Stage The variance of the shock in the quantity stage, σq , is estimated to be 9.097, and is large compared the variance in the flavor stage (which is normalized to 1). The more variant the shock, the smaller the impact of the terms in other stages. Therefore, the large value of σq reflects that price changes have a much larger effect on the flavor decision than on the quantity decision. That is, consumers who observe a sale are much more likely to change the flavor they buy, than to increase the number of cans they purchase. The large zero purchase fixed effect η0 reflects that consumers generally do purchase 29 soup on a week to week basis. The fixed effects for multiple cans show that consumers strongly dislike buying 3 cans of soup as the fixed effect for 3 cans is near that of 4 cans, possibly because it is an uneven number. the effect of prices was found to be negative and convex 6.1.3 Consumption Stage As expected, consumption probability over the course of the year shows strong seasonality. Consumers are most likely to consume in soup near the end of the year, where consumption probability reaches 27.5%. Consumption is only half as likely during the summer, bottoming out at 12.8%. This seasonal trend in consumption probability largely mirrors the seasonal trend in overall units purchased (cor=.798 , p < .001). However, the consumption probabilities from the dynamic model give some insights that aggregate purchases alone do not. For example, the dynamic model finds that consumption probability actually increases over the course of the last quarter, while the overall units purchased decreases. This is because consumers stockpile soup during the fall to consume during the winter. The magnitude of the consumption utility k is comparable to the magnitude of the zero purchase fixed effect η0 . So long as the can is consumed within 4.143 weeks6 , the consumer will gain utility from the purchase. 6 Calculated as log(η0 )−log(k)) log(.99) 30 6.1.4 Purchase Without Search and Counter-Cyclic Pricing The seasonality in consumer search leads to seasonality in price elasticity. For example, the price elasticity of the most popular UPC varies from −6.34 in the middle of summer, to −9.20 at the end of November (Figure 7). If firms partially base their prices on consumer price elasticity, then counter-cyclic pricing will arise as a reaction to this change in search behavior. The most prominent alternative explanation of this trend in price elasticity is consumer heterogeneity, as presented in Guler et al. (2014). In this model, consumers can be segmented into “High” and “Low” types. “High” types have a higher valuation of soup, and are less price sensitive. During low demand season, the low types drop out of the market, leaving only the “High” type consumers. This explains both counter-cyclic pricing and the seasonality in price elasticity. This explanation was partially ruled out by the reduced form test in Section 3.2. To further test the heterogeneity explanation in this data set, I fit a second dynamic consumer inventory model where consumers always search (similar to previous inventory models), and price sensitivity varies seasonally (using the same functional form as consumption probability). This model is consistent with the heterogeneity explanation, where the consumer base becomes more price sensitive during the high demand periods. Comparing the fit of the two models, the search model obtains a substantially better likelihood then the seasonal price sensitivity model, with fewer parameters. This is noteworthy because the search model is in some 31 sense more restrictive: it can only capture trends in price sensitivity that correlate with changes in search incentives. However, the search model endogenously captures three price sensitivity trends within each purchase: that consumers are more price sensitive when they have bought multiple units, that consumers who have inventory will be less price sensitive in their flavor decision7 , and that the seasonal trend in price sensitivity is muted when consumers have inventory. In particular, the increase in price sensitivity when buying multiple units is inconsistent with the heterogeneity explanation, which would predict that those who buy multiple units are more likely to be “High” types, and so should be less price sensitive. 6.2 6.2.1 Counterfactual Simulation Determinants of Search To find out whether seasonality in consumption utility or price variation cause the seasonal variation in search, I recalculated search probability in two counterfactuals based on the estimated parametrization: one where the consumption probability is constant and set to the average consumption probability, and another when price expectations are constant over the course of the year. Figure 7 shows the resulting search probabilities. I find that seasonal search patterns are still prevalent in both cases. When 7 In previous inventory models, consumers with inventory have a higher price elasticity in the quantity decision, but would not have a higher elasticity in the variety decision within purchase as all prices are observed 32 price expectations are constant, the search probabilities for a consumer with no inventory varies by 54% over the course of the year. When purchase probabilities are constant, the search probabilities for a consumer with no inventory varies by 42% over the course of the year. Because more seasonal variation in search is maintained when price expectations are constant and consumption probability is seasonal, I conclude that the primary cause of seasonal search patterns is seasonal consumption utility, though both factors play a role. 6.2.2 Effect of a Change of Promotional Strategy In a second counterfactual experiment, I demonstrate how changes in promotional strategy affect consumer search probabilities. To do this, I simulate consumer search probabilities when a firm increases the overall promotional depth by 25%. This increase leads to an increase in the probability of consumer searches by as much as 7% during November. This in turn increases the overall price elasticity by up to 6% (Figure 7). 7 Conclusions This paper tests whether purchase without search could explain countercyclic pricing. I find that including purchase without search in a structural model of canned soup purchases will lead to seasonally varying price elasticities. This is due to a seasonal trend in price sensitivity that is significantly 33 Search Cost ρ Search Stage log(Search Variation) log(σs ) Seasonal Price Sensitivity 1.6409∗∗∗ (0.547) 1.6230∗∗ (0.724) - −42.0534∗∗∗ (6.8252) Price Sensitivity α Flavor Stage Search Model - Price Sensitivity Period 1 −8.5074∗∗∗ Price Sensitivity Period 14 −8.6754∗∗∗ Price Sensitivity Period 27 −7.272∗∗∗ Price Sensitivity Period 40 −8.1605∗∗∗ Quadratic Price Sensitivity α2 −67.1986∗∗∗ (13.309) −11.0442∗∗∗ Zero Purchase Fixed Effect η0 97.4815∗∗∗ (25.683) −67.3231∗∗∗ (11.820) −147.3935∗∗∗ (30.459) −200.5633∗∗∗ (39.819) 2.2079∗∗∗ (0.356) 0.2756∗∗ (0.133) 0.2030 (0.140) 0.1288∗∗∗ (0.051) 0.2401∗∗∗ (0.002) 101.6260∗∗∗ (9.922) 14.7213∗∗∗ Two Can Purchase Fixed Effect η2 Three Can Purchase Fixed Effect η3 Four Can Purchase Fixed Effect η4 Quantity Stage log(Purchase Variation) log(σq ) Consumption Prob Period 1 Pd (1) Consumption Prob Period 14 Pd (14) Consumption Prob Period 27 Pd (27) Consumption Prob Period 40 Pd (40) Consumption Stage Consumption Utility k −1.2763 × 105 Log-Likelihood −9.5084∗∗∗ −21.2134∗∗∗ −28.4546∗∗∗ 0.4451∗∗∗ 0.2822∗∗∗ 0.1973∗∗∗ 0.1338∗∗∗ 0.2344∗∗∗ 13.0166∗∗∗ −1.3161 × 105 Table 5: Dynamic Estimation correlated with both aggregate demand and average promotional depth. If firms set their prices by measuring the response to sales, then these trends lead to counter-cyclic pricing. I find that the search model presented here fits the data better than a traditional inventory model with seasonal price elasticity. There are limitations to the approach here. First, I did not fit a firm side model to the data. Second, I did not directly compare the im- 34 pact of purchase without search with the impact of other explanations of counter-cyclic pricing, such as loss leader pricing, and consumer heterogeneity. Purchase without search could be working in tandem with these other effects, and future work might compare the relative magnitudes. The dynamic consumer inventory model presented here has three innovations unique to structural models. First, it allows consumers to make purchase decisions without observing prices at the store. Second, it allows consumers to purchase multiple flavors in each period. Third, it maintains the ability to estimate flavor fixed effects separately from the dynamic model. Fitting the model required two assumptions because both the discount factor and consumer price expectations are not identified. Though the seasonal trend in price sensitivity was also found in the static estimation, the results of the dynamic model could change here if these terms were identified. The estimated model also provides insight into consumer behavior. I find that consumers’ probability of search systematically varies throughout the year, peaking at 27.5% in the winter and bottoming out at 12.9% in the summer. This variation in search leads to price elasticities that vary by 64% by season. The dominant cause of seasonal search was found to be seasonal consumption utility. However, the firms’ own pricing strategy can affect consumer search probabilities, and hence their price elasticity. For example, if promotional depth is increased by 25%, consumers with no inventory will be up to 7% more likely to search in the winter, which leads to price elasticity increase of 6%. 35 An immediate follow-up to this paper would measure the relative impact of several possible causes of counter cyclic pricing, including purchase without search, heterogeneity, loss leader pricing, and a non-linear response to prices. Another follow-up could implement a firm side model. Given the results presented in this paper, firms would want to reduce the size of their promotions to limit consumer search. However, this would be balanced by the desire for price discrimination. Investigating how firms can make this trade-off, which could be done in the framework presented here, may allow more effective promotional strategies. The fact that consumers may learn the firms pricing strategy over time may complicate this question. References Bayot, D. and J. Caminade (2014). Popping the cork: Why the price of champagne falls during the holidays. Available at SSRN 2455962 . Bronnenberg, B., M. Kruger, and C. Mela (2008). Database paper-The IRI marketing data set. Marketing Science 27 (4), 745–748. Bucklin, R. and J. Lattin (1991). A two-state model of purchase incidence and brand choice. Marketing Science 10 (1), 24–39. Chevalier, J., A. Kashyap, and P. Rossi (2000). Why don’t prices rise during periods of peak demand? Evidence from scanner data. American Economic Review . 36 Ching, A., T. Erdem, and M. Keane (2009). The price consideration model of brand choice. Journal of Applied Econometrics (4686). Erdem, T., S. Imai, and M. Keane (2003). Brand and quantity choice dynamics under price uncertainty. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 5–64. Guler, A. U., K. Misra, and N. Vilcassim (2014). Countercyclical pricing: A consumer heterogeneity explanation. Economics Letters 122 (2), 343–347. Haviv, A. (2015). Removing the Computational Burden of Adding Cyclic Variable to Structural Dynamic Models. Hendel, I. and A. Nevo (2006). Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior. Econometrica 74 (6), 1637–1673. Honka, E. (2012). Quantifying search and switching costs in the us auto insurance industry. Available at SSRN 2023446 . Katz, M. L. (1984). Price discrimination and monopolistic competition. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 1453–1471. Lal, R. and C. Matutes (1994). Retail pricing and advertising strategies. Journal of Business, 345–370. Mehta, N., S. Rajiv, and K. Srinivasan (2003). Price uncertainty and consumer search: A structural model of consideration set formation. Marketing science 22 (1), 58–84. 37 Mela, C., K. Jedidi, and D. Bowman (1998). The long-term impact of promotions on consumer stockpiling behavior. Journal of Marketing Research 35 (2), 250–262. Murthi, B. and R. C. Rao (2012). Price awareness and consumers use of deals in brand choice. Journal of Retailing 88 (1), 34–46. Nevo, A. and K. Hatzitaskos (2006). Why does the average price paid fall during high demand periods? Ray, S., C. Wood, and P. Messinger (2012). Multicomponent Systems Pricing: Rational Inattention and Downward Rigidities. Journal of Marketing 76 (September), 1–17. Seiler, S. (2013, September). The impact of search costs on consumer behavior: A dynamic approach. Quantitative Marketing and Economics, 155–203. Warner, E. and R. Barsky (1995). The timing and magnitude of retail store markdowns: evidence from weekends and holidays. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (2), 321–352. 38 (a) Seasonality in Demand (b) Seasonality in Pricing (c) Estimated Price Sensitivity By Time Of (d) Probability of Consumption by Time of Year Year 39 (e) Estimated Search Probability (f) Estimated Price Elasticity (g) Determinants of Search (h) Increased Promotional Depth Figure 1: Counterfactuals 40 8 Online Appendix - Likelihood Derivation 8.1 Decision at the Consumption Stage To solve the model, I work backwards through the stages in each period. To make the consumption decision, consumers will try to consume soup up to their level of desired consumption d, which is stochastic. Therefore, c = min(d, i + q). (6) This leads to the following consumption probabilities P (d = c) = (1 − Pd (s))Pd (s)c if d < i + q (7) c P (d = c) = Pd (s) if d = i + q. To solve for the decisions in the previous stages, I need to combine the expected value of the consumption stage, and the expected discounted payoffs in all future periods, which I define as Vc (s, i, q): i+q−1 Vc (s, i, q) = X ! c0 (1 − Pd (s))Pd (s) (kc0 + V (s, i + q − c0 )) +Pd (s)i+q (k(i+q)+V (s, 0)). c0 =0 (8) 8.2 Decision at the Flavor Stage Because consumers track and make consumption decisions based on how many cans of soup are in their inventory, and not the flavor of those cans, the 41 flavor decision only affects the payoffs in the current period. This simplifies the decision at the flavor stage to a static decision. Consumers must decide on a flavor for each can that they decide to purchase in the quantity stage. If consumers have searched, they will have observed prices, and so when choosing which flavor to purchase as can w the consumer solves: arg maxα1 pfw + α2 p2fw + ηfw + εfw . fw (9) which leads to the following choice probabilities: e P (fw |p, r = 1, s) = α1 pf +α2 p2 fw +ηfw w σε f P e α1 pf 0 +α2 p2 0 +ηf 0 f σε f (10) f 0 ∈F where F is the full set of flavors. If consumers do not search, they use the non-discounted prices, pbfw t , to make their flavor decision: arg maxα1 pbfw + α2 pb2fw + ηfw + εfw . fw (11) which leads to the following choice probabilities: 2 eα1 pbfw +α2 pbfw +ηfw P (fw |p, r = 0, s) = P α pb 0 +α pb2 +η 0 . e 1 f 2 f0 f (12) f 0 ∈F Note that a consumer who is buying two or more cans can choose to 42 purchase multiple flavors, which is observed in the data. The specification here allows the flavor fixed effects to be estimated in a static way, which is described in an online appendix. When making the purchase decision, consumers take into account the expected utility they will receive during the flavor stage. In the case that the consumer searches, this expectation is −→ → (uf (fw ; p, εfw )) E− ε− fw = εf × log( X e α1 p bf +α2 p b2 fw +ηfw w εf ). (13) f 0 ∈F In cases where the consumer does not search, → (uf (fw ; p E− b, − ε→ fw )) = log( ε− fw X e b2 α1 p bf +α2 p fw +ηfw w εf ). (14) f 0 ∈F 8.3 Decision at the Quantity Stage During the quantity stage, consumers choose their purchase quantity to maximize the utility in this stage, the expected utility in the flavor and consumption stage, and the expected utility in all future periods. The εfw are not observed when consumers make their quantity decisions, so consumers calculate the expected value of the flavor utility for each additional can, conditional on the observed prices if they searched, and the non-discounted prices if they did not. Consumers who search select their 43 purchase quantity by solving: arg maxηq + εq + q × Eε−−f→ (uf (fw ; p, − ε→ fw )) + Vc (s, i, q) w (15) q In cases where consumers do not search, p is not observed, and so consumers use the most likely prices pb to make their quantity decision. → (uf (fw ; p b, − ε→ arg maxηq + εq + q × E− fw )) + Vc (s, i, q) ε− fw (16) q − Integrating over → εq , I can calculate the probability of the consumer choosing any purchase size as: → ε− ηq +εq +q×E− → (u (fw ;p,− fw ))+Vc (s,i,q) ε− fw f σq P (q|r, p, s, i) = e imax P−i e −−→))+V (s,i,q) ηq +εq +q×E− → (u (fw ;p,ε c fw ε− fw f σq . (17) q 0 =0 To solve for the decision in the search stage, I need to combine value of the purchase stage, consumption stage, and the expected discounted payoffs in all future periods, which I define as Vq (s, i, q): imax X−i Vq (s, i, r = 1) = log( → ηq +εq +q×E− ε− → (u (fw ;p,− fw ))+Vc (s,i,q) ε− fw f σq e ) (18) q 0 =0 imax X−i Vq (s, i, r = 0) = log( e −−→))+V (s,i,q) ηq +q×E− → (u (fw ;p,ε c fw ε− fw f σq q 0 =0 44 ) (19) 8.4 Decision at the Search State When making the search decision, consumers compare the expected discounted value of searching with the expected discounted value of making their purchase decision without search. Because they make the search decision before observing prices, the expectation is taken over prices to calculate the expected benefit of search. The search decision is then max l(r = 1)Vq (s, i, r = 1) − ρ + εs ) + l(r = 0)(Vq (s, i, r = 0)ε0s ) (20) r∈{0,1} which leads to the following search probability: e P (r = 1|s, i) = e Vq (s,i,r=1)−ρ σs Vq (s,i,r=1)−ρ σs +e Vq (s,i,r=0) σs . (21) This gives the overall expected value for the search stage, the purchase stage, and the consumption stage Vs (s, i): V (s, i) = ση × Ep (log(e Vp (s,i,r=1)−ρ ση +e Vp (s,i,r=0) ση )). After calculating the value function V (s, i) using the Bellman equation 5, I use V (s, i) to solve for Vp (s, i, q), and Vc (s, i, q). With these values in hand, I calculate the joint probabilities P (r, f, q, c|s, i) = P (r|s, i)P (f |r, s, i)P (q|f, r, s, i)P (c|q, s, i). 45 Each of these terms can be calculated using 7, 10, 12, 17, 21. 9 Online Appendix: Static Estimation 9.1 Static Estimation The specification of the flavor utility allows the flavor fixed effects to be estimated separately from the dynamic model. Consider the flavor choice probabilities in the case of consumer search 10 and no consumer search 12. Suppose there are no price promotions in the set of flavor Fnp . Search does not affect choices between options in this set because there are no price promotions for search to reveal. In this case, the choice probabilities simplify to P (fw |p, r = 0, s, fw ∈ Fnp ) = eηfw P η 0. ef f 0 ∈Fnp By comparing the market shares of the non-discounted flavors in each week, we can estimate the fw by maximizing the following log-likehood: X X eηfw max Nf 0 ,t × log( P ηf 0 ) fw e t∈T f 0 ∈F np,t f 0 ∈Fnp,t where T is the set of all time periods in the data, and Nf,t is the number of cans of flavor f purchased in week t, and Fnp,t is the set of non-discounted flavors in week t. This static estimation reduces the parameter space of the far more bur- 46 densome dynamic model. Estimating this static model takes a few minutes, whereas estimating an additional 9 parameters in the dynamic model would take many hours. The cost is that this estimation only uses 80% of the available data as it removes discounted flavors. I also estimate the probability of visiting a store in each seasonal period Pv (s) directly from the data as store visits are each observed. 9.2 Static Results In the flavor stage, the effect of prices was found to be negative and convex. The flavor fixed effects were estimated separately from the dynamic model, and the result of the static estimation of the flavor fixed effects (relative to the most popular UPC) are presented in Table 6. The magnitude of these fixed effects generally corresponds to their respective market share. The two exceptions to this are “Cream of Chicken (2)” and “Tomato (2)”, which were less popular than their market share would suggest. This is likely due to their inflated market share from frequent sales. 47 Chicken Noodle −0.3214∗∗∗ (0.0145) Cream of Mushroom (1) −0.9141∗∗∗ (0.0181) Cream of Mushroom (2) −1.5913∗∗∗ (0.0233) Cream of Chicken −1.7408∗∗∗ (0.0251) Chicken and Stars −1.8959∗∗∗ (0.0257) Cream of Chicken (2) −2.1591∗∗∗ (0.0301) Chicken & Rice −1.9235∗∗∗ (0.0254) Tomato (2) −2.4300∗∗∗ (0.0347) Vegetable Beef −1.9079∗∗∗ (0.0257) Table 6: Static Estimation - Flavor Fixed Effects 48