The Price of Purity Brokerage as Consecration in the Market for Modern Art Fabien Accominotti∗ Columbia University This article proposes a structural approach to consecration, and uses this approach to solve an empirical puzzle in the sociology of markets. Markets for novel and unique goods are often seen as privileged settings for the powerful influence of market intermediaries. Yet economic sociologists have repeatedly failed to observe any impact of art market brokers on the value of the artists they distribute. This puzzling finding, I argue, arises from a misconception of what brokerage does to economic products. While market intermediation is usually thought to act through two social processes of valuation – certification, or the signaling of underlying quality, and qualification, or the establishment of specific quality criteria – I suggest that it also influences value through consecration, or the conferral of relational purity. This approach fills a gap in economic sociology, which lacks a distinct definition of consecration. It also suggests a network-based strategy for capturing consecration empirically. I finally show that brokerage as consecration, not certification or qualification, is indeed how art market intermediaries shape the value of their artists. The empirical focus is on the market for modern art in early twentieth-century Paris – a setting chosen both for its historical significance and its ability to magnify how markets, as social environments, bear on the economic worth of things. ∗ I am particularly grateful to Peter Bearman and Pierre-Michel Menger for their support, and to Jens Beckert, Diana Crane, Thierry Dufrêne, Victor Ginsburgh, Olav Velthuis and Harrison White for their insights and suggestions. For helpful comments on an earlier draft I also thank Paul DiMaggio, Shamus Khan, Uri Shwed and David Stark, as well as participants to the 105th Annual Meeting of the American Sociological Association in Atlanta, to the 22nd Conference of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics in Philadelphia, to the 2012 Max Planck Summer Conference at Northwestern University, and to seminars at Columbia University and CNRS. Mailing address: Fabien Accominotti, Department of Sociology, Columbia University, 501 Knox Hall, 606 West 122nd Street, New York, NY 10027. Email: fa2224@columbia.edu. 1 “Yet what happens here has its counterpart in our own society. A painting by a famous artist sells for many thousands of dollars at a certain time because we have agreed in effect to reduce to the common denominator of economics all products and all goods, even those products which nowadays are increasingly acquiring religious value.” Louis Dumont, Homo Hierarchicus: An Essay on the Caste System “Nothing but their heterogeneity is left to define the relation between the sacred and the profane.” Emile Durkheim, The Elementary Forms of Religious Life Introduction A paradox awaits the sociologist venturing into the study of art markets. Markets for unique goods are usually seen as privileged settings for the powerful influence of market intermediaries: when quality is uncertain, or when it lacks definition altogether, market brokers can play a crucial role in signaling or specifying it, thereby ultimately shaping the prices consumers are willing to pay for products. Products, meanwhile, do not get much more unique than in the market for contemporary art. Yet oddly enough economic sociologists have repeatedly failed to identify any value shaping mechanism involving art market intermediaries. The reputation of art dealers, for example, does not seem to bear any noticeable impact on the prices of their artists. Nor do their promotional campaigns, their experience in business, or their commitment to more highbrow forms of artistic production. And this gets even more perplexing, as dealers, artists, and sociologists themselves nonetheless continue to regard intermediaries as the makers or breakers of artistic careers. The present article offers a solution to this puzzle. To this end, it advances a sociology of economic valuation. Specifically, it draws an analytical distinction between three types of processes – certification, qualification, and consecration – whereby markets, as social environments, can affect the value of marketed things. It also suggests that while both certification and consecration have received considerable attention in the literature on markets, economic sociology lacks a distinct approach to consecration. This, I argue, is the reason behind the paradox outlined above. At its core, this article therefore offers a theory of consecration, and a strategy for capturing 2 it empirically. To anticipate, it approaches consecration as the operation whereby intermediaries confer relational purity to products in a web of affiliations (Breiger, 1974). This relational form of purity departs from the ritual purity one can acquire by complying with culturally scripted conducts or established categories (Dumont, 1970; Douglas, 1966; Abbott, 1981; Zuckerman, 1999, 2004). Though the idea of consecration obviously has religious undertones, the approach I propose insists on consecration’s structural features, and makes it identifiable regardless of the mundanity of the setting. As an illustration, the article eventually goes back to the initial problem to show that brokerage as consecration, not certification or qualification, is how art market intermediaries shape the value of their artists. The empirical focus is on commercial galleries distributing modern art in early twentieth-century Paris. Yet the article helps reflect more broadly on how the social wiring of markets bears on the economic worth of things. Social processes of valuation in markets Identifying the social underpinnings of market valuation has long been a key enterprise of economic sociology – and understandably so. The effort, after all, addresses head-on the radiant core of economics, promising to show just how ingrained market value is with social matters. It also involves reflecting on the non-intrinsic, and therefore perhaps questionable, origins of value inequalities across economic entities: there is indeed something troubling to the fact that individuals, firms, or goods of comparable ability or quality may, because of differing social backgrounds or embeddedness, be valued differently. Speaking to these various concerns, social science essentially has two frameworks within which to approach the social drivers of market value. The first, which one can term the quality certification or revelation framework, builds on the premise that the quality of products up for exchange in economic life is often uncertain. When this is the case, other product characteristics may serve as informational cues signaling their underlying quality. Such characteristics can be an individual’s education, the past performance of a firm, or the praise a product receives from experts. They need not be social in a very strong sense – and actually early proponents of this framework can be found within economics itself (e.g. Spence, 1974). In more recent years, however, the idea that the relational and cultural wiring of markets can also work to alleviate quality uncertainty has enriched this 3 approach with a deeper sociological twist. In blurry economic settings, it has thus been found, the popularity of firms with business partners, or the status they acquire from displays of deference by competitors, can help thirdparty customers assess the quality of their products (Podolny, 1993, 2005; Benjamin and Podolny, 1999). Likewise, personal ties underlying market transactions can entail an element of trust, or the disclosure of private information regarding product quality. Customers as a result may prefer to pay a premium for products acquired through socially embedded exchange – so long as this premium does not exceed the costs they would incur to collect equivalent information otherwise (e.g. Geertz, 1978; Uzzi, 1999; Uzzi and Lancaster, 2004; Velthuis, 2005; see also DiMaggio and Louch, 1998). The kind of informational cues certification processes breed on may also be more cultural in nature. Higher prices, for example, are sometimes interpreted by customers as signals of greater quality – this is notably the case with contemporary art (Moulin, 1987; Velthuis, 2005). In a more subtle way, culturally scripted pricing rules can also function to alleviate the sense of uncertainty associated with certain products (Velthuis, 2003). And cultural categories can interact with the certifying work of experts to influence market value, as when entrenched classification systems divert the attention of market analysts from certain firms in an industry (e.g. Zuckerman, 1999, 2004). The certification framework often assumes the correspondence between quality and quality signals to be loose. Informational cues, that is, do not necessarily reflect or reveal quality with great accuracy. This has an important implication, as it helps explain why discrepancies in market value sometimes depart from actual quality differences between economic entities. Yet as the mere possibility of this implication makes clear, a basic tenet of the certification framework is that there exists relative agreement as to what constitutes underlying quality. This is not the case in the second framework, which one may refer to as the quality definition or qualification framework. Most central to this other approach is the notion that the nature of quality can itself be elusive, and should not be taken for granted in the first place. The adoption of certain quality criteria, as a consequence, can have a profound impact on the ultimate value of things. This is perhaps no more obvious than when markets emerge for products which once fell outside the scope of commercial exchange. When it comes to giving monetary value to nature, life, or cadavers for example, the issue is not only to overcome the moral preventions that previously kept them out of the market sphere. Also at stake is the question of what, in these things, will be deemed valuable, or to put it starkly, 4 of what will count (Zelizer, 1979, 1981; Fourcade, 2011; Anteby, 2010). In such markets and others, qualification processes bring answers to precisely that question (e.g. Espeland and Sauder, 2007; Stark, 2009; Beckert and Aspers, 2011). By collectively defining the valuable, they shape economic preferences and quality beliefs, thereby eventually influencing the value of products. Shared understandings of what constitutes quality can thus emerge from interactions between market participants. A startling example is Moshe Adler’s account of superstardom in cultural markets (Adler, 1985). The utility consumers derive from a cultural product, Adler argues, increases when they can discuss it with one another and thus acquire interpretive frames that enhance their appreciation of the product at stake. In Adler’s view, this explains why the demand for performers with already large audiences is more likely to grow even higher over time. In a similar vein, the quality of contemporary art is often constructed through efforts by various market intermediaries to elucidate it to potential collectors. But the social definition of quality can also be more contentious, when fierce struggles oppose various quality principles and resolve in the adoption of the one with the most powerful proponents. Pierre Bourdieu, in his classic account of the market for symbolic goods, offers a distinct elaboration of the latter scenario (Bourdieu, 1993). As a quick overview of the examples above suggests, markets for cultural products have often been used as strategic research sites for identifying social valuation processes. Whether the market for wine, art or music, they indeed typically involve unique or novel goods, the quality of which is often uncertain, or needs to be collectively constructed. It is therefore intriguing that several efforts to observe the impact of such processes on value in what is perhaps the most emblematic of these markets, namely the market for contemporary art, have recently failed. Art market brokers and economic value: previous research and ongoing puzzles The art market often has observers puzzled over the prices works of art sell for. This is certainly the case when auction sales occasionally beat record prices, grabbing headlines. Yet it is also true, in a more subtle though perhaps more revealing way, when a piece that was virtually worthless a couple of years earlier later goes for a noticeable amount. That previously worthless art later sells for high prices is often accounted 5 for by the support it receives from various market intermediaries (e.g. Becker, 1982; Mulkay and Chaplin, 1982; Moulin, 1987; Velthuis, 2005). And what intermediaries do to bolster the value of their products has precisely been analyzed both in terms of certification and qualification. The mere promotion of their artists by intermediaries, typically acting through qualification – or the construction of collector’s preferences – is thus an obvious candidate to explain their impact on prices. In addition, because the quality of contemporary art is often uncertain, intermediaries can provide customers with the kind of quality signals needed to make consumption decisions. These signals may of course come from expert prescribers – such as art critics – or various judgment devices – such as guides or rankings (e.g. Hatchuel, 1995; Bonus and Ronte, 1997; Karpik, 2010). Yet market intermediaries themselves can also act to certify the quality of the products they distribute. Studying the role of talent agencies in the Hollywood film industry, Bielby and Bielby (1999) thus found that representation by an elite agency helps authenticate the quality of screenwriters. Writers with elite representation are therefore more likely to find employment, and earn considerably more on average than equally accomplished writers with nonelite representation. In similar fashion, one may anticipate the reputation of a gallery to convey positive signals regarding the quality of its artists, thereby enhancing their market value over and above other indicators of artistic achievement (Beckert and Rössel, 2004).1 The problem Interestingly, the role of intermediaries in shaping the value of contemporary art has been explored in two recent studies in economic sociology (Rengers and Velthuis, 2002; Beckert and Rössel, 2004; see also Velthuis, 2005). And these studies have come to fairly surprising conclusions, as neither of them could identify any influence of intermediaries on the prices of their artists. Although their empirical settings varied significantly, both articles sought to measure the impact of the certification and qualification work of galleries on the prices of their artists. Beckert and Rössel focused on the certification aspect of the problem, and operationalized the certification power of a gallery through its reputation, as assessed by a panel of experts. Rengers 1 One third mechanism may actually account for the impact of intermediaries on the prices of their artists: they could simply provide artists with better work conditions and thus unleash their potential to produce more valuable art. While this hypothesis is not directly addressed in this article, it is also at the core of Bielby and Bielby’s findings on talent agencies. 6 and Velthuis in contrast measured reputation as the ability of a gallery to have its artists represented by contemporary art museums. In both cases, however, reputation was meant to capture the perceived ability of a gallery to discern artistic quality. Rengers and Velthuis in addition also looked at the qualification work of intermediaries, or in other words at their ability to shape customers’ preferences. They did so through a measure of the number of artists a gallery represents. The lower that number indeed, the more likely each artist is to benefit from the promotional efforts of her gallery. The two studies finally measured prices differently: as selling prices in galleries for Rengers and Velthuis; both in galleries and at auctions for Beckert and Rössel. In the latter case, and as far as the effect of gallery reputation on prices was concerned, the findings were consistent across measures of prices.2 As a matter of fact, neither article could isolate a specific impact of galleries on the prices of their artists. Once various characteristics of artists were adjusted for (in particular their career length and assessed quality, or expert recognition, as measured through the consensus of art critics) the mere reputation of their market intermediaries brought no significant premium in their prices. More precisely, Beckert and Rössel observed that, if anything, gallery reputation had a negative impact on prices, whether measured in galleries or at auctions (Beckert and Rössel, 2004, 44-45).3 Rengers and Velthuis did not find a significant effect of gallery reputation either. Actually, among all characteristics pertaining to galleries, only age – or experience in business – had a small, positive influence on the prices of artists. Rengers and Velthuis thus concluded that “apparently, galleries are not able to add economic value themselves”. In other words, “the fact that [certain] galleries sell [more] expensive works has more to do with the artists they represent than with their own characteristics” (Rengers and Velthuis, 2002, 18-24). These findings are doubly puzzling. On the one hand they indeed challenge our sociological understanding of the role intermediaries play in uncertain markets. More importantly, however, they also contradict the vision that gallery-owners and artists themselves have of the operation of the art market. In the remainder of his account of the contemporary art world, 2 Beckert and Rössel’s gallery prices were collected in a number of Berlin and Leipzig galleries in the early 2000s. Rengers and Velthuis’ prices instead came from a much more comprehensive database, reporting the actual selling price of over 16,000 works of art by 2,400 artists in 230 Dutch galleries between 1992 and 1998. As far as gallery prices are concerned, then, the findings by Rengers and Velthuis are certainly more trustworthy. 3 This impact was not statistically significant, however, and the authors do not further comment on it. 7 Velthuis (2005) thus shows that the ability to enhance artists’ prices is actually key to how dealers judge their performance in that market. Yet as evidenced by the results above, he does not clearly identify where that ability comes from. Can we reconcile the observed lack of influence of galleries on prices with the notion that market intermediaries act as certifiers and qualifiers of the products they distribute? Several explanations in cultural economics have sought to go down this path. They are surveyed critically below. As they are found wanting, the next section introduces a different mechanism whereby certain galleries do influence the value of artists – in line with the vision of art market actors. Candidate explanations In a highly stylized, game-theoretical model of the primary art market, Schönfeld and Reinstaller (2007) thus suggest that a gallery’s higher reputation should have a negative impact on the prices of its artists. In order to increase their market share and profit, they argue, galleries could indeed seek to attract customers by cutting prices. Rival galleries however would then likely react by lowering their own prices in turn, and ultimately this undercutting spiral could generate a “signal of instability increas[ing] the uncertainty in the market and undermin[ing] its proper functioning. Therefore, according to Schönfeld and Reinstaller, it is a good strategy for galleries to set prices [from the outset] in a way that does not allow their rivals to profitably undercut them” (Schönfeld and Reinstaller, 2007, 146). At this “undercut proof equilibrium”, the authors eventually show, the prices of high reputation dealers should be lower than those of their low reputation counterparts.4 In a slightly different vein, one could explain the puzzling relationship between prices and gallery reputation by building on Podolny (1993)’s account of competition in the investment-banking market. Similar to high-status banks, who can obtain their inputs at lower costs, reputed intermediaries may also be able to put less money on the table to secure access to the work of a given artist. They could then pass on these lower costs to the prices they charge to customers – thereby profitably enhancing their market share. One would thus predict a negative impact of the reputation of galleries on 4 That price variations can hurt the functioning of the market by increasing consumer uncertainty is also central to Velthuis’s account of dealers’ pricing scripts (Velthuis, 2003). Actually Schönfeld and Reinstaller present their model as an economically grounded explanation for such scripts. 8 the prices of their artists. These explanations nonetheless have two major weaknesses. They first suggest that the prices of products should negatively correlate with the reputation of market intermediaries. They are therefore relatively ill-suited to the findings by Rengers and Velthuis or Beckert and Rössel that the reputation of galleries has no significant impact on the prices of their artists. In addition, they ultimately rest on the reintroduction of price competition in the primary art market. This puts them at odds with both qualitative and quantitative accounts suggesting the existence of a downward price rigidity in that market – a reluctance of dealers, in other words, to decrease prices – and portraying dealers as price, rather than profit, maximizers (Velthuis, 2005; Hutter et al., 2007). Moving forward Contrary to these various attempts, this article does not try to explain the lack of influence of galleries on prices. Instead, it further specifies the role they play, arguing that earlier studies did not fully capture what dealers do for their artists. More precisely, I suggest that brokerage can enhance the economic worth of products by positioning them relative to one another in a web of status-conferring affiliations. The process I propose thus goes further than the previous two in disconnecting the social aspect of value from the intrinsic properties of economic entities. In contrast to both certification and qualification, where value emerges from the interplay of social factors with product features, here the mere position of products in a web of affiliations directly translates into economic value. To put it in Dewey’s terms, social embeddedness is no longer a means for the evaluation or appraisal of economic entities. Rather, it becomes an object of prizing (Dewey, 1939). That the relational status of economic entities can bear on their economic worth is hardly a new idea. In fact, classic work in the sociology of markets has shown how the status firms derive from one another in an industry can influence the value of their products (Podolny, 2005; Benjamin and Podolny, 1999). As mentioned earlier, however, this line of work generally regards relational status as a signal of quality. It remains, in other words, within the bounds of the quality certification framework. As a consequence, I here argue, it unnecessarily narrows our sociological understanding of status. Research on status as a “prism” of the market (Podolny, 2001) essentially implements a classic definition of status as popularity among peers, or deference received from them (e.g. Homans, 1951; Blau, 1964). And it does so for good reasons: firms, after all, are probably better equipped than 9 customers to evaluate the quality of their peers, and one may legitimately regard the deference they display to competitors as a signal of the latter’s quality. Yet precisely because it frames status as a quality signal in the first place, this approach also tends to obliterate another aspect of status, and therefore fails to observe an important process of social valuation possibly at play in markets. Beside its dimension of popularity and deference indeed, status in the social sciences has also long been viewed in terms of relational purity (e.g. Marriott, 1959, 1968; DiMaggio, 1982). In this alternate view, status does not emerge from one’s popularity with others, however weighted by the social worth of one’s endorsers. Instead, it has its roots in the selectness of one’s social affiliates, or said otherwise in the purity provided by one’s lack of ties to status-threatening alters. This observation thus makes room for two forms of status in markets, which for the sake of clarity one may refer to as popularity and relational purity. Do these two forms of status have independent effects on value in markets? Do they, in other words, underlie distinct social valuation processes? This article shows this to be the case. It also argues that the notion of relational purity, as applied to market intermediaries and the objects they distribute, provides the analytical leverage to isolate a mechanism of social valuation previously under-identified in the economic sociological literature – namely consecration. It thus puts a name on the form of valuation associated with status as relational purity. Consecration: theory and analytical strategy Research on cultural valorization has repeatedly highlighted the importance of consecration processes, whereby “some individuals or objects are collectively identified as worthy of veneration and esteem, whereas others are not” (Allen and Parsons, 2006, p. 809; see also Bourdieu, 1993; Heinich, 1996; Corse and Griffin, 1997; Dowd et al., 2002; Allen and Lincoln, 2004; English, 2005). Consecration, in this tradition, is usually seen as a selection process performed by an authoritative body, according to rigorous procedures, and with an eye to identifying objective differences between the individuals or objects that are selected and the ones that are not (Allen and Parsons, 2006).5 This characterization may in effect suffice to empirically identify most 5 In their study of cultural consecration in baseball, for example, Allen and Parsons illustrate how induction into the Baseball Hall of Fame obeys these various criteria. 10 consecration projects. In light of the two frameworks outlined earlier, however, one may wonder whether it does not too readily conflate consecration with another social valuation process. If indeed consecration amounts to the scrupulous selection, by a legitimate entity, of individuals or objects of outstanding merit, it does not seem much different from quality certification by authoritative experts. Is consecration then just another word for certification – or, for that matter, for the kind of social valorization associated with one’s endorsement by numerous others? Quite to the contrary, I here argue that it captures a process analytically different from, though oftentimes incidental to, these other valuation mechanisms. To put things simply, the selection procedure through which some individuals or objects are identified as worthy of esteem while others are not usually entails two closely intertwined processes. The most obvious is indeed a certification or endorsement process, applying to those individuals or objects that are selected. Just as important, however, is the concomitant operation whereby selection draws a line between the individuals that are selected and the ones are not. Selection therefore does not only alter our perception of each single individual by touching them or not, and by bestowing upon the chosen the authority of the selector. It also does so by reconfiguring the whole set of individuals into a heterogeneous one, carving out two exclusive and hierarchically ordered regions in the population – two regions whose relation, in other words, is not unlike Durkheim’s vision of the relation between the sacred and the profane (Durkheim, 1965). Through their affiliation with one or the other of these regions, the relational identity of individuals is redefined: selected individuals are made similar to one another and overtly different from non-selected ones, and vice versa. As far as the impact of this redefinition on the value of individuals or objects is concerned, I propose to refer to this second aspect of selection, and to it only, as consecration. Empirically, it may be hard to parse out what, in the impact of selection on value, owes to certification and what to consecration proper. One reason – which may also explain their frequent confounding in the literature – is that consecration often goes unnoticed, to the benefit of other valuation mechanisms. Commenting on the selection process involved in rites of institution, Bourdieu thus remarks that “by solemnly marking the passage over a line which establishes a solemn division in the social order, rites draw the attention of the observer to the passage [that is, to the certification of the individual’s quality], whereas the important thing is the line.” (Bourdieu, 1991, p. 118). More annoyingly, however, in many an instance the two processes occur jointly, and can simply not be disentangled in empirical data. 11 The selection of a writer to a prestigious prize, for example, may entail both consecration – the writer now ranks among the prize’s laureates – and certification of the quality of her work. And it would be quite straightforward to measure the specific impact of the award on, say, the value of her subsequent publishing contracts: one could for example compare these contracts with those of counterparts of equal reputation or talent, but who failed to earn the prize. Yet because the award simultaneously grants certification and consecration, one would be hard-pressed to single out the contribution of each in the emergence of a value difference between the laureate and her peers. If one is to properly identify the effects of consecration, one therefore needs to separately capture an authority’s certification power and its propensity to consecrate. As far as the former is concerned, it does not seem unconceivable to approach it through certain observable attributes, such as the expertise and reputation of the selecting entity, or the average quality of the individuals it selects. The challenge, then, lies in the identification of a distinct measure of consecration power – that is, of one’s ability to establish a clear line between the individuals one selects and the ones one does not. To devise that measure, I suggest we take advantage of the fact that empirical settings often display more than one selecting authority, and that individuals need not be selected by one of them only. When this is the case, the relational purity of selecting entities effectively captures their consecration power. Consider for example the selection of artists by galleries in the market for contemporary art – an empirical case I will return to shortly. From an analytical standpoint, consecration here occurs through the line an authoritative gallery draws between the individuals it decides to represent and the individuals it does not. In practice, however, some of the artists chosen by gallery a may also deal with gallery b, thereby weaving cross-cutting ties between the two houses, and symbolically connecting the artists in and outside a. It thus becomes apparent how two equally authoritative galleries can consecrate to a greater or lesser extent: this happens when the boundary between the artists one gallery respectively selects and rejects is blurred by the presence of cross-cutting ties with another gallery. In Figure 1 below, for example, a’s consecration power is greater than that of equally authoritative a1 , whose artists are partly shared with b. We may in fact go one step further, if we assume that most galleries somehow have to share artists with others – if only because artists have a career, hence a track record of other galleries by whom they have been previously selected. For gallery a, then, choosing to represent certain artists 12 B A1 A Figure 1: Consecration power as boundary enforcement also amounts to drawing a divide between the galleries b it accepts to share artists with, and the galleries c with whom it does not. When deciding on its portfolio of artists, in other words, a simultaneously reconfigures the set of other galleries into a dual structure, and assumes a position on one side of that structure (see the left panel in Figure 2). This position we can equivalently describe in terms of consecration power or relational purity. The divide a introduces between other galleries (and between associated sets of artists) can indeed be more or less clear-cut. It is blurred, in particular, when the galleries a coopts also coopt other galleries whom a does not coopt. In the terms I have used earlier, a’s position then carries less consecration power. Two galleries a and a1 , in other words, have greater or lesser consecration power if they have greater or lesser relational purity, or engage in relations with respectively pure and impure galleries – that is, with galleries who themselves connect only to galleries a and a1 deem worthy enough to deal with, or to galleries outside the realm of a and a1 (see respectively the left and right panels in Figure 2). Thus conceived, relational purity essentially offers a measure of consecration power. C C D A A1 B B Figure 2: Consecration power as boundary enforcement or relational purity 13 The remainder of this article builds on this property to show that consecration is indeed how brokerage impacts value in the art market. The definition of purity it uses, it should be noted, departs from the idea of purity as the rejection of economic motives deemed impure, in contrast to merely artistic ones for example Bourdieu (1993). Contrary to that approach, purity here does not rest on the conformity of one’s actions or decisions with an external guiding principle – or the avoidance of another. Rather, and in accordance with the notion that consecration simultaneously generates the social positions it also affiliates individuals with, purity here is essentially a self-referential dimension, capturing an authority’s ability to enforce the symbolic boundaries it has itself contributed to define. To illustrate the impact of consecration on the economic worth of artists, I first show that art market intermediaries do indeed line up in a status hierarchy ordered by degrees of relational purity. I then proceed to measure the specific impact of their consecration power on the economic value of artists. Case and method The empirical setting this article focuses on is the French market for modern art in early twentieth-century Paris. The reasons for choosing this case are both historical and methodological. Up until the Great Depression indeed, Paris was not only a prominent center of artistic creativity. It was also the core of the worldwide market for the work of living artists. Like no other city, it attracted a dense crowd of talents. And perhaps nowhere else were the careers of these artists as systematically processed by a vivid population of galleries (e.g.Gee, 1981; see also Ring, 1931). Two features in particular make the period and locale valuable for studying the role of art market intermediaries in shaping the value of artists. Due to their concentration in a small number of neighborhoods, first, contemporary art dealers typically knew each other and each other’s distribution decisions closely – an aspect that surfaces time and again in dealers’ memoirs and testimonies (e.g. Blot, 1934; Granoff, 1949; Loeb, 1946; Ring, 1931; Vollard, 1936; Weill, 1933). They were thus prone to managing their portfolios of artists relative to one another, a process I have put at the core of the idea of consecration. Second, the period was also one of high distrust in the ability of academic institutions to successfully sanction the quality of contemporary artists. The growingly dysfunctional academic system and its yearly Salon, slowly glut- 14 ted with an oversupply of young talents, had ceased to play this role over the second half of the nineteenth century (White and White, 1965; Green, 1987; Mainardi, 1993; Jensen, 1994; Galenson and Jensen, 2002). Other, independent salons mostly served to launch the careers of new artists (Gee, 1981). And with few exceptions, museums were not given much credit when it came to selecting and rewarding talented modern artists. As a consequence, an active population of galleries and critics gradually took over the role of public institutions as brokers between artists and collectors, and as authorities defining artistic quality.6 Could that population of galleries also have been a source of consecration for artists? In line with the analytical strategy laid out above, I address this question by asking whether the network of cross-representations of artists in Parisian galleries displayed a structure akin to the ones sketched out in Figure 2. If this was the case – that is, if in that network galleries clearly lined up according to a principle of greater or lesser relational purity – then the market can be deemed to have provided a breeding ground for consecration processes. Identifying the respective position of galleries in that structure should therefore also provide a measure of the consecration power they wielded. Rather than directly devising a measure of each gallery’s consecration power, I thus adopt a two-step approach, first describing the general organization of the market in an effort to assess its overall propensity to sustain consecration processes. This initial step is designed to address a shortcoming frequently associated with research on networks as prisms through which third parties can gauge the status of market actors. For ties and affiliations to work as prisms indeed, they need to be fairly easily interpreted by observers. Studies of networks as the prisms of markets, however, rarely ascertain the interpretability of relational patterns to potential beholders. In contrast, I here assess this overall interpretability by first fitting a blockmodel to the network of cross-represen-tations of artists by Parisian art dealers. This essentially isolates sets of galleries similar to one another as far as their ties to counterpart galleries are concerned. Most importantly, the stochastic blockmodeling technique I implement also provides information on the clarity of the underlying relational data (Nowicki and Snijders 2001; see Appendix A). It thus indicates whether dealers (or sets of structurally equivalent dealers) indeed arranged according to a principle of greater or lesser relational purity. The data I build on report representation of artists in Parisian galleries 6 On that matter, see the opinions collected in Charensol (1996 [1925]). 15 in season 1928-29, for which the documentation is most systematic. The population of galleries is defined through a conventional criterion, though it eventually includes most modern art dealers active in Paris at the time. Specifically, a gallery is included if it exhibited at least one living painter, either on permanent or temporary display, over the season of interest. There were 120 such galleries. Two sources then permit reconstructing the lists of artists exhibited on a permanent basis by these galleries.7 Over the season at stake, 665 painters are thus regarded as represented permanently by at least one of the 120 dealers – an average of about 16 artists per gallery. Socioeconomic data were further collected on both galleries (opening date; capital; form of business operation; participation as expert to auction sales for modern painting at Paris auction house, Hôtel Drouot; documented purchases of modern artists at Drouot; publishing activity; and geographic location) and artists (socio-demographic characteristics; stylistic affiliation; and prices at Drouot in 1928-29).8 This information provides guidance to analyze the blockmodel below. The blockmodeling procedure is described in Appendix A. Table 1 displays the image-matrix of the blockmodel best suited to the network of cross-representations. It reports the average number of artists shared by two galleries in the various positions of that blockmodel, thereby offering a summary view of the cross-representation network. Thus, two dealers in position 1 share on average 1.6 artists, and dealers in position 1 typically share 1.4 artists with dealers in position 2. The few galleries excluded from the analysis at earlier stages because they did not share enough (position 7) or any (position 8) artists with other galleries (see Appendix A) are not shown. Table 2 reports the means of various socioeconomic variables for galleries in each of the eight positions. The selected blockmodel suggests a clear-cut structure in the network of cross-representations across galleries. Two aspects are specially worth noting. First, one needs to emphasize the centrality of position 6 galleries in the cross-representation network (highlighted through dark-shaded cells in Table 1). This centrality essentially arises from the high number of artists these galleries claim to represent: 33.4 on average, as opposed to a more 7 See La Semaine à Paris, published weekly over the period, and Fage (1930, 132-151). The two sources generally agree on the artists represented by various galleries. When this is not the case, however, artists mentioned by one source only were added to the list of artists represented by a gallery. 8 Systematic business data come from Registre du Commerce de la Seine, Archives de Paris, série D33U3. For information regarding sales and prices at Drouot see Lang (1918-1929) and Gee (1981). 16 17 1.6 1.4 0.1 0.1 0.1 0.9 Position 1 Position 2 Position 3 Position 4 Position 5 Position 6 Position 1 4.5 0.2 0.9 2.0 3.0 - Position 2 5.1 0.4 1.2 3.3 - - Position 3 2.1 0.3 0.5 - - - Position 4 0.6 0.2 - - - - Position 5 8.3 - - - - - Position 6 Table 1: Average number of artists shared by two galleries in the various positions of the selected blockmodel. Light-shaded cells indicate the status hierarchy discussed in the text. Dark-shaded cells highlight the strong ties of merchant dealers with dealers of any other position. Positions 7 and 8 (see Appendix A) are not shown. 18 15 24 16 18 18 13 7 120 3 4 5 6 7 8 All 11 1 2 Number of galleries in the position Position 1920 1927 1926 1923 1918 1922 1921 1919 1897 Average opening date 543,600 (39) 200,000 (1) 290,000 (2) 325,000 (8) 210,300 (4) 63,300 (3) 813,800 (8) 344,000 (5) 1,070,000 (8) Average capital and (number) of incorporated businesses 16.2 5.8 6.1 33.4 8.9 12.5 18.5 20.9 10.6 Average number of artists on permanent display 1876 1883 1885 1877 1881 1880 1884 1865 1844 Average date of birth of artists in a gallery 80.0 100 91.2 82.4 88.2 87.9 92.1 64.1 24.2 Average percent of a gallery’s artists alive in 1929 Table 2: Socioeconomic characteristics of galleries in the various positions of the selected blockmodel 4,185 114 3,202 4,553 1,424 4,880 3,273 6,305 8,237 Average price of a gallery’s artists (francs for 100 cm2 of oil on canvas) manageable 13.1 in galleries of other positions.9 Their geographical location and opening date do not clearly distinguish position 6 dealers, neither do the socioeconomic or stylistic characteristics of the artists they distribute. Another striking feature, however, tells them apart: they take intensive part as buyers in Hôtel Drouot’s auction sales. Among the forty-five dealers documented to have bought modern work at Drouot over the 1920s, thirteen (or 29%) are thus sorted in position 6 – which only makes up for 15% of the 120 galleries. In all likelihood, then, position 6 galleries do not really represent the 33.4 artists they claim to exhibit on a permanent basis. Rather, they merely can have access to their work, either through the auction market or through second-hand purchases. Their market role, in other words, departs from that of entrepreneur-dealers concerned with the promotion of a small number of carefully selected artists on the primary market. Various pieces of evidence instead suggest seeing them as trader-dealers operating on the secondary market (Moulin, 1987). Putting position 6 aside, however, cross-representations across galleries do indeed delineate a structure analyzable in terms of varying consecration power. More specifically, the pattern of ties between galleries of positions 1 to 5 displays the formal features of a status hierarchy – highlighted through light-shaded cells in Table 1 – ordered by degrees of relational purity. Position 1 dealers thus typically cross-represent artists with other dealers in position 1 and with galleries in position 2, yet not with those in positions 3 to 5. This takes on particular significance if one also notes that position 1 dealers can typically be regarded as the most established. As indicated in Table 2, they have generally been in business for a longer time, their capital is higher, and the artists they represent are on average both older and more expensive that those in the galleries of other positions. Information on their location further suggests that position 1 galleries cluster in more prestigious Parisian neighborhoods. The relational boundary between galleries of positions 1 and 2 on the one hand and positions 3 to 5 on the other can thus be seen as introduced by galleries whose authority and prestige are highest. This boundary is in turn enforced with varying strength by the dealers of position 1 and those of position 2. The latter indeed share artists with galleries in positions 3 and 4, while the former do not. Meanwhile, the selection decisions of position 2 galleries, whose socioeconomic characteristics signal as fairly established, also introduce a second boundary, between galleries of positions 3 and 4 on the one hand, with whom they share artists, and 9 Differences in means across positions reported in this section are all significant according to appropriate tests. 19 galleries of position 5, with whom they do not. Position 3 and 4 dealers, finally, are the only ones to significantly cross-represent artists also featured in position 5. As far as their selection decisions were concerned, then, Parisian galleries in the 1920s did in fact delineate a status hierarchy based on degrees of relational purity. The market as a whole was thus prone to sustaining consecration processes. The method I have used to uncover it, in addition, permits locating each gallery in that purity hierarchy. It thereby provides a hand on their consecration power. As compared to galleries’ ability to certify and define quality, did that power indeed influence the prices of artists? And does that help us better understand what market intermediaries do to the products they distribute? The price of purity Data Auction prices of artists as an indicator of value To answer these questions, I here turn to prices of artists at Paris most important auction house, Hôtel Drouot, in the late 1920s. Such prices may not be in total accordance with prices charged by galleries, yet they are probably a fair indicator of what I am after here, namely the economic value of an artist as determined by the supply of and demand for her works. Various pieces of evidence thus suggest that there existed a strong correlation between gallery and auction prices. In addition, modern art auction sales had become established enough at Drouot by the end of the 1920s that they probably offer a more reliable barometer of the economic value of artists. Historical evidence supporting these arguments is developed at greater length in Appendix B below. I model the selling prices at Drouot, over the season 1928-29, of artists represented permanently in Paris galleries at the same period. Prices are compiled from the last volume of Lang (1918-1929), which records all art sales held at Drouot over the period. In the following analyzes, sales of paintings are the only ones considered. Since I am interested in artist- and gallery-related rather than technique-related predictors of value, this focus has no dramatic consequences on the analysis.10 I thus use information on 10 Paintings form the bulk of the works by modern artists sold at auctions throughout the 1920s. They are also the ones for which Lang most systematically reports size, a most valuable piece information when it comes to modeling variations in prices. 20 the sales of 1,196 paintings by 173 unique artists with permanent gallery representation in 1928-29. Auction prices are modeled using hierarchical models, which permit appropriately adjusting for the effects of predictors operating at various levels. Sales of individual artworks are indeed nested at the level of artists. As sales are observed at auctions, however, they cannot be considered to nest at the level of galleries. Gallery-related characteristics are therefore passed on to the artists these galleries represent. It should also be remembered that artists can be featured by several galleries. When this is the case, gallery-level variables are expressed at the artist level as scores – that is, as the average of the values they take in the various galleries representing the artist. Finally, two separate series of models are fit below. The first series does not adjust for the past prices of artists, in line with both Rengers and Velthuis (2002) and Beckert and Rössel (2004). While this allows for a better comparison with these authors’ findings, it also leaves open the possibility that the observed effects of gallery characteristics may arise from a selection scenario whereby dealers with higher reputation, for example, would merely choose to represent artists on the basis of their higher past prices. To rule out this scenario, I thus fit a second series of models, where past prices are included as an additional predictor of 1928-29 prices. Measuring consecration power Since I am mostly concerned with the role of intermediaries in shaping the economic value of artists, gallery characteristics are the chief object of interest – and among them consecration power will obviously receive special scrutiny. The latter is here captured as a gallery’s position in the status hierarchy uncovered earlier. That position essentially measures the relational purity a gallery claims for its artists through the shape of its relations with others. Practically, gallery purity is coded as decreasing at a constant rate as one moves down one position in the status order. Thus, galleries have a relational purity of 5 in position 1, 4 in position 2, 3 in positions 3 and 4, and 2 in position 5. The purity of galleries in positions 7 and 8 cannot be directly assessed on the same grounds, since these galleries lack any affiliation to the status hierarchy as presented in Table 1. Position 7 dealers, however, can easily be reintroduced if one slightly loosens the threshold used to approach relations between galleries. When this threshold is set to one rather than two shared artists, and a blockmodel is fit to relations between galleries, 12 out of the 21 13 galleries in position 7 cluster with some of the galleries making up position 5 in Table 1, to form an even lower step in the hierarchy. I therefore give position 7 galleries a status score of just 1. Position 8 galleries are similarly attributed the lowest possible score, on the grounds that they occupy a hardly identifiable position in the market hierarchy. Finally, relational purity is not straightforwardly established for traderdealers (position 6 in Table 1). On the one hand indeed these dealers show artists also represented in both the highest and the lowest steps of the status hierarchy, thereby positioning themselves somewhere in the middle. Yet on the other hand their specific role as trader-dealers mostly operating on the secondary market makes them poor candidates to confer any kind of consecration. To solve this indeterminacy, two specifications of their status were implemented. In the first one, trader-dealers were attributed a middleof-the-range status of 3. In the second, their status was left undefined. Findings did not differ sharply depending on the adopted specification. The results reported below use an undefined status for position 6 galleries. Galleries as certifiers and qualifiers As discussed earlier, a variety of processes involving galleries can contribute to shape the value of artists beyond consecration itself. To disentangle their respective impacts, additional gallery characteristics were introduced as predictors of prices, capturing in particular their role in certifying and defining artistic quality. Various indicators can measure a gallery’s reputation, conceived as its perceived ability to certify the quality of artists. Longevity in business is one, as too many ill-advised representation decisions can entail the demise of a gallery. Whether the gallery’s manager acts as expert at auction sales is another: that one’s expertise is sought after for this job clearly signals one’s recognized ability to assess artistic quality. To find out whether these variables were indeed correlated, and ultimately to build a synthetic index of reputation, I conducted a principal component analysis of gallery-level data (Figure 3). Opening date, incorporation (variable “inc” in Figure 3), and in case a gallery was incorporated its capital in 1928-29, were collected from the Registre du Commerce de la Seine in Paris departmental archives.11 Other variables come from miscellaneous sources: the number of times a gallery’s manager acted as expert at Drouot auction sales in 1928-29 (variable “nbexpert”) was obtained from Lang (1918-1929). Whether a gallery 11 Registre du Commerce de la Seine, Archives de Paris, série D33U3. 22 1.0 had a periodical advertising organ, such as a bulletin or journal, or alternatively published monographs on its artists, is reported in variable “edit”. Finally, the 1928 and 1929 issues of the Bottin mondain, a directory of Paris highly regarded personalities and businesses, were searched for the presence of galleries or dealers (variable “bottin”). Figure 3 displays the first factor map for this set of variables. 0.0 bottin nbexpert inc opening capital -0.5 Dim 2 (16.62%) 0.5 nbpainters -1.0 edit -1.0 -0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0 Dim 1 (36.96%) Figure 3: Principal component analysis of gallery-level variables: first factor map As one can see, longevity in business (the opposite of opening date) strongly correlates with the number of times a gallery’s manager acted as expert at Drouot auctions. These two variables actually contribute the most to the construction of dimension 1 in the factor map. This dimension, therefore, may be regarded as capturing the reputation of dealers. That a gallery’s presence in the Bottin mondain also correlates with dimension 1 further confirms this interpretation. When modeling the impact of galleries on prices, I shall use their score along this dimension as an index of their reputation. Interestingly, capital also strongly correlates with dimension 1 – too strongly indeed to be used as an additional variable in a regression framework. Capital, in the models below, is therefore considered an element of a gallery’s reputation. That a gallery regularly published a journal or monographs – or both – was finally used as a proxy for the promotion it reserved to its artists, and thus for its ability to shape collectors’ preferences through qualification work. As shown in Figure 3 (variable “edit”, the largest contributor to dimension 2), this aspect of the activity of galleries is hardly associated with 23 their reputation. Yet it negatively correlates with the number of artists they represent (“nbpainters”). This dovetails with the notion that publishing captures promotional efforts: the larger the number of artists a dealer has to handle, the less promotion each of them should logically receive. Artists’ and artworks’ characteristics While characteristics of artists and artworks can be regarded as controls used to properly disentangle the role of intermediaries, they are also interesting in themselves. Since all works in the sample were paintings, technique does not intervene here at the work level. The main variable of interest at this level is therefore size. Price is expected to rise with the size of paintings (e.g. Sagot-Duvauroux et al., 1992), yet the strength of this relationship may also differ across artists. For successful artists in particular, whose mere name makes for a larger part of a painting’s price, size should not matter relatively as much. Allowing the slope of the relationship between size and price to vary across painters might therefore help refine the modeling of prices. Artists’ demographics are also expected to impact the selling price of their production. Age (or more generally the number of years elapsed since an artist’s birth) is thus expected to drive prices up, since it is both a signal of quality – artists represented by galleries at later ages have passed a tougher test of time (Hume, 1757) and still managed not to fall into oblivion – and a proxy for the audience of collectors an artist might have been able to build over time (Bowness, 1990). In addition, the death of an artist, which creates an immediate shortage of her available work, should positively influence her selling prices, even when date of birth is adjusted for.12 The number of works of an artist auctioned over the season is further expected to have a depressing effect on prices – in a basic instantiation of the law of supply and demand. One can also anticipate the number of galleries representing an artist to influence prices – albeit not necessarily in a linear way. Being shown by numerous dealers should indeed push prices upward: directly, it increases the likelihood that one’s dealers will show up at auctions to support prices, if need be. Indirectly, it may also bolster the demand for one’s work, since various dealers do not necessarily reach out to the 12 Gender was also included as a predictor, but never found to have a significant effect on prices. This should not however be seen as evidence that being female did not constitute an important liability in the art market. Rather, the absence of significant impact arises from a lack of observations, which in turn points to the fact that very few women made it into the population of artists enjoying gallery representation and regular trading of their work at Drouot at the time. Of the 173 artists with both representation and trading in 1928-29 analyzed below, only 13 were women. 24 same collectors. If too many galleries represent an artist, however, collusion between them might prove tough to maintain, and price competition, which is usually reined in on the primary market, might resurface: dealers unable to sell an artists’ output because it is already available from too many others, will likely engage in undercutting competitors. While this should first drive value down on the primary market, it could also have indirect consequences on prices at auction. Finally, one needs to model the influence of one more variable operating at the artist level – namely the overall perceived quality of an artist’s work, as signaled by the assessments of contemporary critics. To approach this dimension, I here rely on a unique resource. In the fall of 1925, art journal L’Art vivant organized a survey in which 64 art critics, with a wide range of aesthetic inclinations, were asked to name the 10 artists they considered most worthy of entering a projected museum of modern art – since no such museum existed in Paris at the time. The survey results were presented in Charensol (1996 [1925]), and are reported here in Appendix C. While the survey was held in season 1925-26, I assume that the results would not have been greatly different three seasons later. I therefore use the number of votes received by each artist in the survey (variable “votes Art vivant” below) as a measure of their critical recognition. In the market for modern art, critics would typically review exhibitions for newspapers or art magazines. They could also provide forewords to the catalogs galleries issued when showing an artist or a group – and good reviews, or prefaces by important critics, were certainly helpful in getting noticed by potential buyers. As unbiased judges of the quality of artists, however, even the most prominent critics, taken individually, were not necessarily regarded as worthy of unlimited trust. Indeed, as Turpin observed, important conflicts of interest could arise between their role as prescribers and their personal ties to various artists (Turpin, 1929). Using a survey of a wide panel of critics by contrast makes it possible to correct for individual biases. Results Descriptive statistics and correlations for all artist-level predictors, including gallery-related characteristics passed on to artists as scores, are displayed in Table 3 for the 173 artists with auction sales in 1928-29.13 Table 4 reports 13 It is worth noting here that the artists in the analysis are not representative of the overall population of artists with permanent gallery representation in 1928-29. The 173 artists with auction sales in 1928-29 were on average older (47.5 years old vs. 44), were represented by more galleries (6.2 vs. 2.8) and enjoyed better critical acclaim (1.9 votes vs. 25 results as a series of models predicting the logged prices of artworks at auctions that year. Model 1 is an empty model, and models 2 to 4, each including additional predictors, gradually improve the overall fit.14 Model 5 allows the slope of the size predictor to vary across artists. Quite logically, augmenting the models with artworks’ characteristics reduces unexplained variance at the artwork level, and adding artists’ characteristics – or galleryrelated characteristics expressed at the artist level – helps account for artistlevel variance. Altogether, model 4, the most powerful among the first four models, accounts for around 60% of the initial variance in the data, as captured by empty model 1. This full model, in addition, fares better in explaining variance at the artist level (70% of the initial variance explained) than at the artwork level (26%). This likely arises from the relatively small number of predictors introduced at the artwork level. Effects of predictors at the work and artist levels are all significant and in the expected direction, and their magnitude does not differ sharply across models. A painting’s size positively affects its price, although this relationship loosens for artists whose prices are generally higher, as shown by the negative correlation between intercept and size coefficient in model 5. This is in accordance with the notion that successful artists charge a larger part of their prices for their mere name, which a work bears regardless of its size. The age and death of artists also drive prices up, while having more works sold at auction over the season depresses them. Also in line with expectations, representation by a larger number of galleries yields an increase in selling prices, but this positive relationship fades as the number of representing galleries gets larger: the coefficient associated with the squared number of representing galleries is negative. Finally, critical acclaim is positively correlated with price: each extra vote received in the survey by L’Art vivant corresponds to a 13% (e0.12 = 1.13) increase in an artist’s auction prices. Most important to the purpose of this article, however, is the impact on prices of gallery-related characteristics. This is where one gets the traction to decide whether intermediaries indeed influence the economic worth 0.6). They were also featured by galleries with significantly higher reputation, though not with larger advertising resources or higher consecration power. Despite this lack of representativeness, I interpret statistical significance below, because not all artists with similar characteristics as these 173 had works sold at auction in 1928-29. 14 Mean deviance and dic, two measures of fit suited to the evaluation of multilevel models, are displayed at the bottom of Table 4. While they differ slightly – mean deviance is a pure measure of fit, dic assesses a model’s predictive power by correcting for its effective number of parameters – both indicate better fit when taking lower values. Also shown is the variance left unexplained by various models, broken down by level (artworks and artists). 26 27 1. Years elapsed since date of birth 2. Dead 3. Number of works sold in 1928-29 4. Number of galleries representing 5. Number of galleries representing (squared) 6. Votes Art vivant 7. Journal or publisher score 8. Reputation index score 9. Consecration power score Mean SD Min Max 1 1 0.436 0.060 0.080 0.056 0.192 0.014 0.329 0.381 47.61 11.90 22 80 1 -0.048 -0.052 -0.043 -0.107 -0.073 0.160 0.188 0.10 0.31 0 1 2 1 0.482 0.468 0.227 -0.101 -0.036 0.113 6.91 9.33 1 89 3 1 0.930 0.597 -0.064 -0.071 0.109 6.24 7.46 1 44 4 1 0.551 -0.040 -0.047 0.057 94.35 251.73 1 1,936 5 1 0.118 0.081 0.119 1.87 4.21 0 26 6 1 0.287 -0.025 0.08 0.18 0.00 1.00 7 8 1 0.439 0.45 2.32 -1.40 14.00 Table 3: Correlations and descriptive statistics for variables in the analysis (N = 173) 1 3.04 0.94 1.00 5.00 9 Table 4: Multilevel models predicting prices (logged) Predictors 1 2 Model 3 Characteristics of artworks Size (log) – Characteristics of artists Years elapsed since date of birth – – Dead – – Number of works sold in 1928-29 – – Number of galleries representing – – Number of galleries representing (sq.) – – Votes Art vivant – – Characteristics of galleries Journal or publisher – – – Reputation index – – – Consecration power – – – Intercept .59** (.03) 5 .60** (.03) .60** (.03) .62** (.05) .03* (.01) .57* (.25) -.017* (.008) .19** (.02) -.004** (.001) .13** (.02) .02* (.01) .54* (.24) -.018* (.007) .20** (.02) -.004** (.001) .12** (.02) .02** (.01) .56** (.24) -.019* (.007) .20** (.02) -.004** (.001) .12** (.02) .16 (.38) .07* (.03) .20** (.08) .17 (.38) .07* (.03) .20** (.08) 2.34** (.26) 2.10** (.37) 7.19** 2.47** 2.34** (.11) (.28) (.26) Correlation Intercept / Slope of log(Size) 4 – – – – -.95 DIC Mean deviance (-2 loglikelihood) 3,119 3,122 2,825 2,833 2,604 2,657 2,576 2,638 2,550 2,611 Total variance Variance artworks Variance artists N Works N Artists 2.41 0.54 1.87 1,196 173 2.34 0.40 1.94 1,196 173 1.03 0.40 0.63 1,196 173 0.96 0.40 0.56 1,196 173 6.08 0.37 5.62 1,196 173 ** p <.01; * p <.05; standard errors in parentheses. 28 of their products – and if so, how. Models 4 and 5 thus include the three variables designed to test the respective effects of intermediaries’ certification, qualification, and consecration power. As measured through galleries’ promotional resources, qualification does not seem to have a decisive impact on prices: although the coefficient is again in the expected direction – among the artists under consideration, one’s work typically makes around 18% more at auction if one is represented by galleries all having advertising organs, as opposed to galleries all lacking them – statistical significance is poor. In contrast, the reputation of art market intermediaries, capturing their ability to certify the quality of their artists, is clearly associated with higher prices. So is also their consecration power: even when adjusting for artist-related characteristics and for the reputation and promotional activity of galleries, a one-unit increase in one galleries’ consecration power – that is, for an artist, being represented by galleries one step higher in the relational status hierarchy uncovered above – increases prices by about 22%. As far as the influence of intermediaries is concerned, however, one may deem this first series of models unsatisfying. The results reported in Table 4 might indeed stem from a different scenario than the one where galleries causally influence artists’ prices. It could in particular be the case that galleries with higher reputation or consecration power merely pick, among artists with similar characteristics, those whose prices are higher in the first place. The observed association between reputation or consecration power and prices would then arise from upstream selection, not downstream influence. To rule out this selection scenario, I fit a second series of models, featuring past prices of artists as an additional predictor of 1928-29 prices. I thus estimate the net impact, among artists with comparable attributes including previous commercial success, of either being represented one more year by a gallery with certain characteristics, or being picked by one that year. Past prices are measured as the average price per square centimeter sold by an artist at Drouot in 1927-28. This has the downside of sharply decreasing the number of observations, to 796 works by 93 artists whose paintings were sold both in 1927-28 and 1928-29. Table 5 reports descriptive statistics and correlations across predictors for these 93 artists.15 15 Incidentally, all of these artists were alive in 1929, making death an irrelevant predictor here. They were also slightly older on average than the initial 173 (48.5 years old vs. 47.5), garnered more critical acclaim (3 vs. 2 votes), were represented in more galleries (8 vs. 6) and sold more works at auctions in 1928-29 (9 vs. 6). However, none of the differences in means between the two groups is statistically significant at the p <.05 level. Accordingly, the conclusions of the second series of models can be regarded as extensible to the larger 29 The second series of models is presented in Table 6. Not surprisingly, the new explanatory variable, past prices, is highly predictive of 1928-29 prices. The magnitude of the relationship also makes sense: a one franc difference in price per square centimeter in 1927-28 yields a 80% difference in 192829 prices (e0.59 = 1.80). With the average price per square centimeter for the 93 artists around 1.3 franc in 1928-29, this means a difference in the range of one franc that year: artworks one franc higher in 1927-28 were thus also roughly one franc higher in 1928-29. Coefficients of gallery-related predictors can now more safely be interpreted as the causal influence on value of the representation of artists by market intermediaries. Models 6 and 7 here show that galleries with higher promotional resources do not have any noticeable impact on prices. The coefficient is statistically insignificant, and its magnitude is virtually zero. The same is true of galleries with higher reputation – our measure of certification power. For artists previously commanding similar prices, there is no clear-cut gain to being represented one more year by a more reputable gallery, or picked by one that year. The positive relationship observed earlier between prices and galleries’ reputation can therefore be attributed to a selection mechanism, whereby more reputable galleries tend to feature expensive artists. This dovetails with the findings by Beckert and Rössel on the one hand, and Rengers and Velthuis on the other, that the certification power of galleries has no noticeable impact on prices. Consecration power, in contrast, retains most of its impact in models 6 and 7. Among artists with comparable characteristics – including past prices – being represented one more year by a gallery one step higher in the hierarchy based on relational purity, or being selected by one that year, increases prices by about 20% (e0.18 = 1.20). In the absence of observations on representation before 1928-29, one cannot disentangle what in that rise owes to fresh selections by higher status galleries in 1928-29, and what to the continuing effect of earlier selections. In any event, though, the consecration power of galleries does have a clear, large, and positive impact on the prices of their artists. Consecration power also fares better to explain prices than the status of market intermediaries classically approached through their popularity in a deference network. This is the sense of models 8 and 9, which feature measures of status both as popularity and as relational purity. Following in the steps of Podolny (2001), popularity status is here measured as the centrality of a gallery in the network of affiliations across dealers, weighted by group of 173 artists. 30 31 1. Years elapsed since date of birth 2. Number of works sold in 1928-29 3. Number of galleries representing 4. Number of galleries representing (squared) 5. Votes Art vivant 6. Journal or publisher score 7. Reputation index score 8. Consecration power score 9. Bonacich’s centrality score 10. Prices 1927-28 Mean SD Min Max 1 1 0.022 0.076 0.050 0.294 0.119 0.349 0.342 0.024 0.348 48.54 10.09 27 77 1 0.515 0.510 0.236 -0.139 -0.081 0.139 0.187 -0.085 8.559 10.94 1 89 2 1 0.938 0.590 -0.143 -0.149 0.090 0.346 0.350 8.462 9.08 1 44 3 1 0.549 -0.093 -0.104 0.046 0.219 0.248 153 325 1 1,936 4 1 0.114 0.053 0.135 0.235 0.819 3 5.11 0 26 5 1 0.299 0.043 0.009 0.036 0.10 0.20 0.00 1.00 6 Table 5: Correlations and descriptive statistics (N = 93) 1 0.472 -0.041 0.064 0.66 2.39 -1.30 14.00 7 1 0.552 0.197 3.09 0.90 1.00 5.00 8 1 0.172 11.89 4.59 0.00 17.53 9 1 1.45 2.73 0.04 16.00 10 Table 6: Multilevel models predicting prices (logged), including past prices as a predictor Model Predictors 6 Characteristics of artworks Size (log) 7 8 9 .60** (.04) .64** (.05) .60** (.04) .014* (.0073) -.006 (.006) .09** (.02) -.0018** (.0006) .046* (.018) .58** (.08) .016 (.0074) -.006 (.006) .09** (.02) -.0018** (.0006) .044* (.019) .60** (.08) .0139 (.0075) -.006 (.006) .10** (.03) -.0018** (.0006) .047* (.019) .57** (.08) .0149* (.0075) -.006 (.006) .10** (.03) -.0018** (.0006) .044* (.019) .59** (.08) .02 (.32) .055 (.033) .18* (.08) – -.02 (.33) .047 (.034) .18* (.08) – .05 (.33) .049 (.035) .22* (.11) -.01 (.02) -.01 (.33) .040 (.036) .24* (.11) -.01 (.02) 1.06 (.55) .73 (.63) 1.06 (.55) .72 (.64) – -.98 – -.98 DIC Mean deviance (-2 loglikelihood) 1,539 1,605 1,516 1,581 1,533 1,605 1,509 1,580 Total variance Variance artworks Variance artists N Works N Artists 0.61 0.37 0.24 796 93 5.96 0.34 5.54 796 93 0.61 0.37 0.24 796 93 6.12 0.34 5.69 796 93 Characteristics of artists Years elapsed since date of birth Number of works sold in 1928-29 Number of galleries representing Number of galleries representing (sq.) Votes Art vivant Price 1927-28 Characteristics of galleries Journal or publisher Reputation index Consecration power Bonacich’s centrality Intercept Correlation Intercept / Slope of log(Size) ** p <.01; * p <.05; standard errors in parentheses. 32 .64** (.05) the centrality of its affiliates (Bonacich, 1987).16 It essentially captures the quality of a gallery’s artists, as signaled through the willingness of its peers to also represent them. As can be seen from models 8 and 9, this signaled quality does not significantly influence prices.17 Status as relational purity and consecration power, in contrast, retains all of its explanatory power in the two models, strengthening the finding that consecration is indeed how galleries generate value for their artists. Finally, and although they do not directly pertain to the main argument of this research, it is worth commenting on the influence of artist-related predictors in this second series of models. Representation by one additional dealer in 1928-29 thus continues to drive prices up when past prices are adjusted for. This effect now clearly captures what a more widespread gallery representation actually does to the value of artists, either through increased support at the auction house, or through the construction of a larger audience for artists. Among artists with similar prices in 1927-28, older ones also command higher prices at auctions in 1928-29. This is an indication that prices grow with time at a faster pace for older artists than for their younger counterparts – possibly because the mechanisms involved in the causal effect of age are not linear, for example if audiences build over time through a snowballing process, or because new mechanisms, such as the anticipation of death, intervene as age increases. Likewise, critical acclaim also seems to work on the rate of growth of artists’ prices, so that among painters with similar prices in 1927-28, those whose expert evaluation was better in 1925 enjoy even dearer prices in 1928-29. Conclusion and implications The market for modern art in early twentieth-century Paris offers a startling illustration of consecration as a social process of valuation. For Matisse, Pi16 Specifically, status as popularity is here calculated as: S(α, β) = ∞ X αβ κ W κ+1 1, κ=0 where α is a scaling coefficient, β is a weighting parameter, W is the matrix recording affiliation ties between galleries, and 1 is a column vector where each element has the value “1”. S(α, β), then, is also a column vector, the elements of which record Bonacich’s centrality for each gallery in the affiliation network. 17 This is not the case either in models where relational purity is not included among gallery-related variables affecting prices. Such models are available from the author upon request. 33 casso and their peers, art market intermediaries did not merely facilitate the encounter of their artistic output with the demand of collectors. They also actively contributed to the generation of their value. They did so, however, in a way that has generally been under-theorized by economic sociology. Most of our knowledge on social mechanisms of valuation is indeed concerned with two broad types of processes: certification, or the signaling of underlying quality, and qualification, or the social construction and diffusion of criteria for value. Neither of those processes was involved in the production of value by intermediaries in the market for modern art. Their certification power, however approached, did not noticeably influence art prices, and neither did their qualification work. In contrast, consecration power, conceived as the ability of more prestigious dealers to establish clear lines between their artists and others, significantly enhanced the value of artists. This article proposed a theory of consecration as the affiliation of individuals to relationally pure strata in a structure made heterogeneous by the selection decisions of intermediaries. In doing so, it insisted on the structural dimension of consecration. Taking the notion seriously, it revived the Durkheimian insight that the sacred, religious or otherwise, should essentially be defined through its heterogeneity with the profane. In the market for modern art, consecration thus ultimately arose from the structural divides introduced by intermediaries between various sets of artists. This structural approach helped delineate consecration as a specific process of valuation in markets. Empirically, this enabled me to solve a puzzle in economic sociology, by thinking anew about how intermediaries shape the value of the products they distribute. From a more theoretical perspective, it highlighted the difference between consecration proper and the certification mechanism associated with one’s selection by a legitimate or reputed entity. Consecration here departs from the mere signaling of valued properties concurrently entailed by selection. It instead operates through the relational display of differences and identities between various sets of objects or actors. But that concept of consecration also holds insights for advancing our understanding of social valuation more generally (Lamont, 2012). As a matter of fact, it recasts the way we often articulate cultural and structural arguments to account for social status and inequality. Approaches to the cultural origins of social hierarchies classically view the latter as partly rooted in the symbolic scales and boundaries actors routinely deploy to rank and categorize objects, people or groups. Under certain circumstances, such classification processes can result in unequal access to resources across social entities, 34 in the emergence of actual structural boundaries between them, and ultimately in social inequality (Lamont, 1992; Zuckerman, 1999; Tilly, 1998; Lamont and Molnár, 2002; Velthuis, 2005; Pachucki et al., 2007). The concept of consecration I introduced, while not incompatible with this view, illuminates a reverse mechanism for inequality formation. Structural boundaries, it suggests, do not only result from the application of preexisting metrics or categories to the elements of a social system. Conversely, the structural divides observed in a social setting – such as the ones market intermediaries introduced between artists when making distribution decisions – can also shape the overall perception of that setting’s hierarchy. They can, in other words, concatenate into a valuation scale of their own, thereby acquiring a distinct influence on the worth of various social entities. Thus, the relational purity conferred by galleries – a structural form of purity, as opposed to the kind granted by one’s compliance with culturally defined purity principles (e.g. Dumont, 1970; Abbott, 1981) – was here found to bear specifically on the value of artists. At its core, then, the account of consecration developed in this study points to the propensity of social structure itself to act as an independent source of identity for the elements of a social system. This has implications for research at the crossroad of cultural and structural social science that go beyond issues of social valuation and inequality. That observed structural patterns can provide a basis for the cultural constructs we mobilize when interpreting reality already lay at the heart of Durkheim’s account of cognitive categories (Durkheim, 1965; Durkheim and Mauss, 1963), and the idea that our minds internalize external distinctions in the social world is for example pivotal to Bourdieu’s theory of practice (Bourdieu, 1977, 1984). Recent research on the interplay of social and symbolic structures, however, has yet to produce an empirically grounded illustration of that idea (Pachucki and Breiger, 2010). The present article has taken one step in precisely that direction, showing how an observable system of divisions and groupings in the social world can reverberate in the way its elements are apprehended, appreciated, and ultimately valued. There are finally limitations to what this article could achieve in that domain. In particular, while the blockmodeling strategy I deployed made it possible to ascertain the clarity of structural patterns observable in the social world, it did not directly evidence the translation of such patterns into mental structures available for the interpretation and appreciation of social reality. Instead, I had to implicitly posit that translation. If future research on the interaction of social and symbolic structures is to rest on firmer ground, it should strive to test that assumption more systematically. 35 Only then shall we arrive at an empirically sound vindication of old ideas on structural patterns, symbolic structures, and their intricate relationships. 36 References Abbott, Andrew. 1981. “Status and Status Strain in the Professions.” American Journal of Sociology 86:819–835. Adler, Moshe. 1985. “Stardom and Talent.” American Economic Review 75:208–212. Allen, Michael Patrick and Anne E. Lincoln. 2004. “Critical Discourse and the Cultural Consecration of American Films.” Social Forces 82:871–894. Allen, Michael Patrick and Nicholas L. Parsons. 2006. “The Institutionalization of Fame: Achievement, Recognition, and Cultural Consecration in Baseball.” American Sociological Review 71:808–825. Anteby, Michel. 2010. “Markets, Morals, and Practices of Trade: Jurisdictional Disputes in the U.S. Commerce in Cadavers.” Administrative Science Quarterly 55:606–638. Basler, Adolphe. 1926. La peinture: religion nouvelle. Paris: Librairie de France. Becker, Howard S. 1982. Art Worlds. Berkeley: University of California Press. Beckert, Jens and Patrik Aspers (eds.). 2011. The Worth of Goods: Valuation and Pricing in the Economy. New York: Oxford University Press. Beckert, Jens and Jörg Rössel. 2004. “Kunst und Preise: Reputation als Mechanismus der Reduktion von Ungewissheit am Kunstmarkt.” Kölner Zeitschrift für Soziologie und Sozialpsychologie 56:32–50. Benjamin, Beth and Joel Podolny. 1999. “Status, Quality and Social Order in the California Wine Industry.” Administrative Science Quarterly 44:563–589. Bielby, William T. and Denise D. Bielby. 1999. “Organizational Mediation of Project-Based Labor Markets: Talent Agencies and the Careers of Screenwriters.” American Sociological Review 64:64–85. Blau, Peter. 1964. Exchange and Power in Social Life. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Blot, Eugène. 1934. Histoire d’une collection de tableaux modernes : cinquante ans de peinture (1882 - 1932). Paris: Editions d’art. 37 Bonacich, Phillip. 1987. “Power and Centrality: A Family of Measures.” American Journal of Sociology 92:1170–1182. Bonus, Holger and Dieter Ronte. 1997. “Credibility and Economic Value in the Visual Arts.” Journal of Cultural Economics 21:103–118. Bourdieu, Pierre. 1977. Outline of a Theory of Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bourdieu, Pierre. 1984. Distinction: A Social Critique of the Judgment of Tastes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Bourdieu, Pierre. 1991. Language and Symbolic Power. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Bourdieu, Pierre. 1993. The Field of Cultural Production. Columbia University Press. New York: Bowness, Alan. 1990. The Conditions of Success: How the Modern Artist Rises to Fame. London: Thames and Hudson. Breiger, Ronald. 1974. “The Duality of Persons and Groups.” Social Forces 53:181–190. Breiger, Ronald, Scott A. Boorman, and Phipps Arabie. 1975. “An Algorithm for Clustering Relational Data with Applications to Social Network Analysis and Comparison with Multidimensional Scaling.” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 12:328–383. Charensol, Georges. 1996 [1925]. Pour un musée français d’art moderne. Une enquête de L’Art vivant en 1925 . Paris: Réunion des Musées Nationaux & Séguier. Corse, Sarah M. and Monica D. Griffin. 1997. “Cultural Valorization and African-American Literary History: Re-Constructing the Canon.” Sociological Forum 12:173–203. Dewey, John. 1939. Theory of Valuation. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. DiMaggio, Paul. 1982. “Cultural Entrepreneurship in Nineteenth-Century Boston, Part II: The Classifiation and Framing of American Arts.” Media, Culture and Society 4:303–322. 38 DiMaggio, Paul and Hugh Louch. 1998. “Socially Embedded Consumer Transactions: For What Kinds of Purchases Do People Most Often Use Networks?” American Sociological Review 63:619–637. Doreian, Patrick, Vladimir Batagelj, and Anuska Ferligoj. 2005. Generalized Blockmodeling. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Douglas, Mary. 1966. Purity and Danger: An Analysis of Concepts of Pollution and Taboo. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul. Dowd, Timothy J., Kathleen Liddle, Kim Lupo, and Anne Borden. 2002. “Organizing the Musical Canon: The Repertoires of Major U.S. Symphonie Orchestras, 1842 to 1969.” Poetics 30:35–61. Dumont, Louis. 1970. Homo Hierarchicus: An Essay on the Caste System. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Durkheim, Emile. 1965. The Elementary Forms of Religious Life. New York: The Free Press. Durkheim, Emile and Marcel Mauss. 1963. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Primitive Classification. English, James F. 2005. The Economy of Prestige: Prizes, Awards, and the Circulation of Cultural Value. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Espeland, Wendy N. and Michael Sauder. 2007. “Rankings and Reactivity: How Public Measures Recreate Social Worlds.” American Journal of Sociology 113:1–40. Espeland, Wendy N. and Mitchel L. Stevens. 1998. “Commensuration as a Social Process.” Annual Review of Sociology 24:313–343. Fage, André. 1930. Le collectionneur de peintures modernes. Comment acheter, comment vendre. Paris: Les Editions Pittoresques. Fourcade, Marion. 2011. “Cents and Sensibility: Economic Valuation and the Nature of ‘Nature’.” American Journal of Sociology 116:1721–1777. Galenson, David W. and Robert Jensen. 2002. “Careers and Canvases: The Rise of the Market for Modern Art in Nineteenth Century.” NBER Working Paper 9123. 39 Gee, Malcolm. 1981. Dealers, Critics and Collectors of Modern Painting. Aspects of the Parisian Art Market between 1910 and 1930 . New York: Garland Publishing. Geertz, Clifford. 1978. “The Bazaar Economy: Information and Search in Peasant Marketing.” American Economic Review 68, Supplement:28–32. Granoff, Katia. 1949. Histoire d’une galerie. Paris: Galerie Katia Granoff. Green, Nicholas. 1987. “Dealing in Temperaments: Economic Transformation of the Artistic Field in France During the Second Half of the Nineteenth Century.” Art History 10:59–78. Hatchuel, Armand. 1995. “Les marchés à prescripteurs. Crise de l’échange et genèse sociale.” In L’inscription sociale du marché, edited by Annie Jacob and Hélène Vérin, pp. 205–225, Paris. L’Harmattan. Heinich, Nathalie. 1996. The Glory of Van Gogh: An Anthropology of Admiration. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Homans, George C. 1951. The Human Group. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul. Hsieh, Mo-Han and Christopher L. Magee. 2008. “An Algorithm and Metric for Network Decomposition from Similarity Matrices: Application to Positional Analysis.” Social Networks 30:146–158. Hume, David. 1757. Four Dissertations. I. The Natural History of Religion. II. Of the Passions. III. Of Tragedy. IV. Of the Standard of Taste. London: A. Millar. Hutter, Michael, Christian Knebel, Gunnar Pietzner, and Maren Schäfer. 2007. “Two Games in Town: A Comparison of Dealer and Auction Prices in Contemporary Visual Arts Markets.” Journal of Cultural Economics 31:247–261. Jensen, Robert. 1994. Marketing Modernism in Fin-de-Siècle Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Karpik, Lucien. 2010. Valuing the Unique: The Economics of Singularities. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Khaire, Mukti and R. Daniel Wadhwani. 2009. “Changing Landscapes: The Construction of Meaning and Value in a New Market Category – Modern Indian Art.” Working paper, Harvard Business School. 40 Lamont, Michèle. 1992. Money, Morals, and Manners: The Culture of the French and the American Upper-Middle Class. Chicago: The University Of Chicago Press. Lamont, Michèle. 2012. “Toward a Comparative Sociology of Valuation and Evaluation.” Annual Review of Sociology forthcoming. Lamont, Michèle and Virág Molnár. 2002. “The Study of Boundaries in the Social Sciences.” Annual Review of Sociology 28:167–195. Lang, L.-Maurice. 1918-1929. Annuaire des ventes de tableaux, dessins, aquarelles, pastels, gouaches, miniatures. Paris: Maurice L. (11 vol.). Level, André. 1959. Souvenirs d’un collectionneur. Paris: A. C. Mazo. Loeb, Pierre. 1946. Voyages à travers la peinture. Paris: Bordas. Mainardi, Patricia. 1993. The End of the Salon: Art and the State in the Early Third Republic. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Marriott, McKim. 1959. “Interactional and Attributional Theories of Caste Ranking.” Man in India 34:92–107. Marriott, McKim. 1968. “Caste Ranking and Food Transactions: A Matrix Analysis.” In Structure and Change in Indian Society, edited by Milton Singer and Bernard S. Cohn, pp. 133–171, Chicago. Aldine Publishers & Co. Moulin, Raymonde. 1987. The French Art Market. New Brunswick: Rutgers University Press. Mulkay, Michael and Elizabeth Chaplin. 1982. “Aesthetics and the Artistic Career: A Study of Anomie in Fine-Art Painting.” The Sociological Quarterly 23:117–138. Nowicki, Krzysztof and Tom A. B. Snijders. 2001. “Estimation and Prediction of Stochastic Blockstructures.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 96:1077–1087. Pachucki, Mark A. and Ronald Breiger. 2010. “Cultural Holes: Beyond Relationality in Social Networks and Culture.” Annual Review of Sociology 36:205–224. 41 Pachucki, Mark A., Sabrina Pendergrass, and Michèle Lamont. 2007. “Boundary Processes: Recent Theoretical Developments and New Contributions.” Poetics 35:331–351. Podolny, Joel M. 1993. “A Status-Based Model of Market Competition.” American Journal of Sociology 98:829–872. Podolny, Joel M. 2001. “Networks as the Pipes and Prisms of the Market.” American Journal of Sociology 107:33–60. Podolny, Joel M. 2005. Status Signals. A Sociological Study of Market Competition. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Rengers, Merijn and Olav Velthuis. 2002. “Determinants of Prices for Contemporary Art in Dutch Galleries, 1992-1998.” Journal of Cultural Economics 26:1–28. Ring, Grete. 1931. “Der junge Künstler und sein Händler in Paris und Berlin.” Kunst und Künstler 29:179–189. Rosa, Jose A., Joseph F. Porac, Jelena Runser-Spanjol, and Michael S. Saxon. 1999. “Sociocognitive Dynamics in a Product Markets.” Journal of Marketing 63:64–77. Sagot-Duvauroux, Dominique, Sylvie Pflieger, and Bernard Rouget. 1992. “Factors Affecting Price on the Contemporary Art Market.” In Cultural Economics, edited by Ruth Towse and Abdul Khakee, Berlin. Springer. Schönfeld, Susanne and Andreas Reinstaller. 2007. “The Effects of Gallery and Artist Reputation on Prices in the Primary Market for Art: A Note.” Journal of Cultural Economics 31:143–153. Spence, Michael. 1974. Market Signaling: Informational Transfer in Hiring and Related Screening Processes. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Stark, David. 2009. The Sense of Dissonance: Accounts of Worth in Economic Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Tilly, Charles. 1998. Durable Inequality. Berkeley: University of California Press. Turpin, Georges. 1929. La stratégie artistique. Précis documentaire et pratique suivi d’opinions recueillies parmi les personnalités du monde des arts et de la critique. Paris: Editions de l’Epi. 42 Uzzi, Brian. 1999. “Embeddedness in the Making of Financial Capital: How Social Relations and Networks Benefit Firms Seeking Finance.” American Sociological Review 69:319–344. Uzzi, Brian and Ryon Lancaster. 2004. “Embeddedness and Price Formation in Corporate Law Markets.” American Sociological Review 69:319–344. Velthuis, Olav. 2003. “Symbolic Meanings of Prices: Constructing the Value of Contemporary Art in Amsterdam and New York Galleries.” Theory & Society 32:181–215. Velthuis, Olav. 2005. Talking Prices. Symbolic Meaning of Prices on the Market for Contemporary Art. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Vollard, Ambroise. 1936. Recollections of a Picture Dealer. Translated from the Original French Manuscript by Violet M. MacDonald and Now First Published in any Language. Boston: Little Brown. Weill, Berthe. 1933. Pan ! . . . Dans l’œil ! ou trente ans dans les coulisses de la peinture contemporaine. Paris: Librairie Lipschutz. Wheat, Christopher. 2008. “Multimodel Identification of Group Structure in Network Data.” MIT Sloan School of Management Working Paper. White, Harrison C. and Cynthia White. 1965. Canvases and Careers. Institutional Change in the French Painting World. New York: John Wiley & Sons Inc. Zelizer, Viviana. 1979. Morals and Markets: The Development of Life Insurance in the United States. New York: Columbia University Press. Zelizer, Viviana. 1981. “The Price and Value of Children: The Case of Children’s Insurance.” American Journal of Sociology 86:1036–1056. Zuckerman, Ezra W. 1999. “The Categorical Imperative: Securities Analysts and the Illegitimacy Discount.” American Journal of Sociology 104:1398– 1438. Zuckerman, Ezra W. 2004. “Structural Incoherence and Stock Market Activity.” American Sociological Review 69:405–432. 43 Appendix A. Blockmodeling procedure If the relational purity and consecration power of galleries are to influence artists’ prices, the relational pattern of cross-representations across galleries should display a clear structure to observers of the market for modern art. Galleries, in other words, should clearly arrange according to a principle of greater or lesser relational purity. Blockmodeling procedures seem wellsuited to capture this overall arrangement. Yet classic blockmodeling algorithms – such as concor for example (Breiger et al., 1975) – do not provide rigorous measures of the clarity of network patterns I am after here (see Doreian et al., 2005; Hsieh and Magee, 2008; Wheat, 2008). The stochastic approach to blockmodeling introduced by Nowicki and Snijders (2001) overcomes this limitation. Given a set of underlying relational data and a number of structural equivalence positions, it uses a simulation approach to determine the probability that two individuals belong to the same position, and the probability distribution of relations across positions. Most critically, it also offers various statistics for identifying the blockmodel – if any – that best captures the structure of the underlying data. This permits ascertaining both whether the observed network displays a clear-cut structure and, if so, what that structure is. Two chief statistics are of interest here. The information statistic shows how much of the information in the initial data is restituted by a given blockmodel. This statistic is 0 if the relations between pairs of vertices are entirely predicted by the respective structural equivalence positions they belong to. The higher it is, in contrast, the less these positions tell us about the actual relations between vertices. A better blockmodel therefore has a lower information statistic. The clarity statistic, on the other hand, measures for a given number of positions our certainty that any two individuals belong to the same position – or to different positions. In other words, it indicates the propensity of a n-position partition to unequivocally summarize the positions of vertices in the underlying network. The clarity statistic is 0 if, for any pair of vertices, we know for sure that they are approximately structurally equivalent – or not. It is 1 if any pair of vertices has a .5 probability of being formed of individuals belonging to the same position. Likewise, then, the smaller this statistic, the better the blockmodel. Table 7 reports values of the information and clarity statistics for various blockmodels and for two specifications of ties in the network of crossrepresentations of artists across the 120 galleries. In the upper panel, a tie between galleries is defined by their sharing of at least one artist. Five galleries, which did not share any artist with other galleries, are here excluded 44 from the analysis. In the lower panel a tie is defined as the sharing of two artists or above, which excludes eighteen galleries. Lines in bold signal the blockmodel that the combination of both statistics indicates as most relevant. Information and clarity are here interpreted both in terms of levels and trends – that is, taking into account the marginal gain obtained by adding one position to the blockmodel. The very low values of the clarity statistic show that the market exhibited a remarkably clear relational structure. Examining the most relevant partitions for various specifications of ties also reveals many regularities: the number and composition of positions are relatively similar regardless of the dichotomization threshold, suggesting robust results. Table 7: Statistics used in determining the optimal blockmodel, for two specifications of ties between galleries Tie definition Tie = 1 or more shared artists Tie = 2 or more shared artists Number of positions Information Clarity 2 positions 3 positions 4 positions 5 positions 6 positions 7 positions 8 positions 2 positions 3 positions 4 positions 5 positions 6 positions 7 positions 8 positions .465 .420 .390 .367 .347 .334 .320 .431 .393 .369 .348 .321 .312 .306 .316 .188 .150 .178 .078 .154 .128 .090 .145 .125 .078 .058 .060 .073 The remainder of this article focuses on the six-position blockmodel obtained when a tie between galleries was defined as two or more shared artists. Several reasons account for this choice. Theoretically, first, this specification of ties between dealers seems reasonable to capture meaningful affiliations 45 between galleries. The sharing of one painter could more easily be interpreted by observers as the result of chance. This definition of ties also yields the least equivocal blockmodel according to the clarity statistic. Finally, on the more empirical side, a closer examination of the number and composition of positions in the best blockmodels for the two specifications of ties shows that they yield largely consistent results. 46 Appendix B. Auction prices as an indicator of the economic value of artists For the bulk of artists auction prices fall well below prices asked for their work on the primary market.18 Figure 4 for example plots the highest and lowest prices asked by gallery Percier for works by three of its young artists – Francisco Borès, Irène Lagut, and Léon Zack – on the occasion of their solo exhibitions, against the highest and lowest prices commanded by their works at auctions over the same period. Size of the works was not reported in the exhibition catalogs, so that the comparison is somewhat rough. Yet it shows that for all three artists, the range of auction prices falls short of reaching even the lower range of gallery prices – despite the fact that the works sold at auctions, especially by Lagut and Borès, were indeed relatively large. 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 Francisco Borès 1926‐27 Irène Lagut 1927‐28 Léon Zack 1927‐28 Figure 4: Gallery and auction prices over one season for three artists of the Percier gallery. Full dots indicate the range of prices as posted in the gallery’s exhibition catalogs, empty dots the range of selling prices at auctions. Source: Fonds Galerie Percier, Bibliothèque Kandinsky, Paris, and Lang (1918-1929). Various mechanisms can explain why gallery prices range systematically higher than auction prices for comparable works by the same artist. Most obviously, as DiMaggio and Louch (1998) have shown in other instances, transactions mediated by personal relations, as is the case when a dealer 18 On this issue, see in particular Hutter et al. (2007). 47 is involved, are likely to entail an element of trust that auction sales do not provide, and for which customers may be willing to pay a monetary premium. Gallery prices can be in better accordance with auction prices when artists are more established. This seems to be the case of Henri Matisse’s paintings throughout the late 1910s and early 1920s (Figure 5). When an artist is in high demand, the difference between his auction and gallery prices can even be reversed, with the latter falling behind. Rather than sticking to the auction rate, a dealer can indeed prefer to sell for a lesser price to carefully targeted amateurs, such as those he deems strategic to an artist’s career. In a 1917 letter to Henri Matisse, Felix Fénéon, the manager of the Bernheim-Jeune galleries, for example writes: Our Lausanne branch has sold two of your paintings, for 11,500 French francs, to Mr. [Josef] Mueller, a Solothurn manufacturer of screws for watches and eyeglasses. [. . . ] This is a very cheap deal. Yet for the first time, to my knowledge, your work enters a Swiss collection, and it was important to make this first step. [. . . ] Switzerland has a handful of amateurs of good painting. We hope they will follow Mr. Mueller’s example: if so, we shall no more resort to the concessions we had to make for this debut (Archives Matisse, Issy-les-Moulineaux, Bernheim-Jeune Correspondence, item 170821a). Overall however, there is certainly a correlation between prices on the primary market and at auctions – hence the findings by Beckert and Rössel (2004) showing relatively similar patterns in the determinants of the ones and the others. This correlation can be observed both between artists and over time for the same artist, as evidenced by Figure 5 in the case of Matisse. Practically, it arises from the shared understanding that public prices breed the expectations of collectors regarding over-the-counter prices on the primary market. As Turpin (1929) puts it, The first valuation of an artist takes place when a painting appears at Hôtel Drouot, and generally rests on the gallery price. The dealer will sustain this price using all possible means. From this day on artist and dealer are tied to one another. If he wishes to, the dealer can even have a few paintings by the artist he wants to establish a value for auctioned off. All he needs to do is add them to the listing of an existing sale. Obviously this strategy 48 5 4 3 2 1 0 Figure 5: Selling prices per square centimeter for paintings by Henri Matisse. Full dots indicate prices in galleries, empty dots prices at auctions. Prices have been adjusted for inflation and are expressed in constant 1917 francs. Source: Archives Matisse, Issy-les-Moulineaux, and Lang (1918-1929). involves numerous sacrifices for the dealer, since he must be prepared to absorb all the artist’s production that amateurs willing to cash in on their collection could throw onto the market. An artist also has an interest in supporting his prices by himself, in case his dealer fails to do so, since the latter could as well walk away if prices happened to plummet brutally. [. . . ] The artistic strategy thus suggests having one’s works valued through auction sales as early as possible, provided that the initial price is not too high, and that one does not already have too many works in private collections. Upsides of such valuation: amateurs, realizing that they own more than a mere painting, but instead a real asset – that they can realize either at auctions or directly with a gallery – will be less reluctant to buy further pieces by the artist. Gradually, then, artist and dealer should be in a position to increase the market value of the artist’s work, which will be recognized by critics and amateurs, and supported by auctioneers (Turpin, 1929, 102-103, emphasis in the original). The second reason for choosing auction prices as a barometer of the value of artists – and therefore as a means to explore its determinants – has to do 49 with the evolution of art market institutions themselves in the wake of World War I. Up until 1914, only a handful of sales organized at Drouot would revolve around the work of living artists.19 The situation evolved around 1920. Although infamous for having unfairly hit the personal businesses of Wilhelm Uhde and Daniel-Henry Kahnweiler, the sales of these German dealers’ collections and stocks, which had been seized at the outbreak of war, also paradoxically spread the notion that modern art could encounter demand at the auction house. Indeed, however flooded the market was with their work as a consequence of the sales, which took place between May 1921 and May 1923, some artists (in particular Derain, Vlaminck, Van Dongen, and to a lesser extent Picasso) pulled off relatively high and steady prices.20 The growing legitimacy of modern art as a marketable product prompted Drouot auctioneers to organize more sales featuring modern works alone. Figure 6 thus shows the evolution of the number of modern art specific sales at Drouot over the late 1910s and 1920s. Mixed sales only are taken into account (as opposed to those featuring the estate of single collectors). There were ten such sales in season 1918-19, and 27 in season 1927-28. As can be seen, despite a drop around 1922, probably attributable to the still depressing effect of the Kahnweiler sales, the growth of modern art specific sales largely exceeded that of other types of sales. As a market category, in other words, modern art underwent a breakthrough in the 1920s. The new category furthermore had its recognized officiant, auctioneer Alphonse Bellier, who at the end of the 1920s presided over about half of auction sales specifically devoted to modern art.21 Whether the rise of modern art as an auction category contributed to the general increase in its prices throughout the 1920s is a question beyond the scope of this article.22 More important here is the fact that by the end of the decade, Drouot had become a global exchange for modern painting, where works by living artists would be traded on a regular basis. “Hôtel 19 The sale of La Peau de l’Ours, held on March 2, 1914, was no doubt the most famous of such sales, probably because it was unexpectedly successful, and helped propagate the idea that cutting-edge painting could be a profitable investment. On the Peau de l’Ours society, and on the sale itself, see in particular the account provided by the society’s manager in Level (1959). 20 For a detailed analysis of the sales, see Gee (1981, Appendix F, 19-32). On the positive impact of the sales for modern art, also see Level (1959, 71-72). 21 On Bellier, see Turpin (1929, 108-110), Moulin (1987, 18). 22 For an investigation of this very question in the case of contemporary Indian art, see Khaire and Wadhwani (2009), who build on the recent scholarship addressing sociocognitive categories and valuation in markets (e.g. Espeland and Stevens, 1998; Rosa et al., 1999; Zuckerman, 1999, 2004). 50 300 250 200 Modern paintings sales All auction sales 150 100 50 Figure 6: Auction sales and auction sales specifically devoted to modern painting at Hôtel Drouot, 1918-19 to 1928-29. Season 1918-19 = 100. Source: Lang (1918-1929). Drouot is the stock exchange of modern art”, Turpin thus observes in 1929 (Turpin, 1929, 107; also see Basler, 1926). And as early as 1925, Picasso’s dealer Paul Rosenberg writes to his artist: I have never had so much to do, every collector in the world is in Paris [. . . ] The Gangnat sale [held at Drouot on June 24 and 25, 1925] was a triumph, and people are getting crazy. [. . . ] Painting has become an exchange, it is incredible how an universal atmosphere has emerged around French painting (Paul Rosenberg – Pablo Picasso correspondence, July 7, 1925, Musée National Picasso, Paris). The auction market for modern painting, as a consequence, became large, deep and reactive enough in the late 1920s – and it attracted bidders from enough horizons – that it can be deemed a good place to look for an indicator of the value of artists. 51 Appendix C. Outcome of the survey by art journal L’Art vivant, 1925 Artist Matisse Henri Derain André Dunoyer de Segonzac André Bonnard Pierre Maillol Aristide Picasso Pablo Utrillo Maurice Braque Georges Vlaminck Maurice Rouault Georges Vuillard Edouard Dufresne Charles* Denis Maurice Friesz Othon Marquet Albert Dufy Raoul Moreau Luc-Albert Favory André Laurencin Marie Léger Fernand Van Dongen Kees Signac Paul De Waroquier Henri Guérin Charles Laprade Pierre Lhote André Besnard Albert Boussingault Jean-Louis Flandrin Jules Forain Jean-Louis Le Fauconnier Henri Léopold-Lévy Lurçat Jean Marval Jacqueline Modigliani Amedeo Puy Jean Roussel Ker-Xavier Simon Lucien Valadon Suzanne Vallotton Félix Alix Yves Charlot Louis Charmy Emilie Cottet Charles Daragnès Jean-Gabriel De la Fresnaye Roger Desvallières Georges Dufrénoy Georges Girieud Pierre Gromaire Marcel Hervieu Louise Laboureur Jean-Emile Laurens Henri Sex M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M F M M M M M M M M M M M M M M F M M M M F M M M F M M M M M M M F M M Born 1869 1880 1884 1867 1861 1881 1883 1882 1876 1871 1868 1876 1870 1879 1875 1877 1882 1888 1883 1881 1877 1863 1881 1875 1875 1885 1849 1883 1871 1852 1881 1882 1892 1866 1884 1876 1867 1861 1865 1865 1890 1878 1877 1863 1886 1885 1861 1870 1876 1892 1878 1877 1885 Dead 1954 1954 1974 1947 1944 1973 1955 1963 1958 1958 1940 1938 1943 1949 1947 1953 1948 1937 1956 1955 1968 1935 1970 1939 1931 1962 1934 1943 1947 1931 1946 1966 1966 1932 1920 1960 1944 1945 1938 1925 1969 1951 1974 1925 1950 1925 1950 1942 1940 1971 1954 1943 1954 Votes 26 20 19 18 18 18 15 14 13 12 11 9 8 8 8 7 7 6 6 6 6 5 4 4 4 4 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 Artist Lebasque Henri Luce Maximilien Mainssieux Lucien Marchand Jean Metzinger Jean Naudin Bernard Piot René Aman-Jean Edmond Asselin Maurice Bissière Roger Blanchard Maria* Blanche Jacques-Emile Bouche Georges Boutet de Monvel Bernard Caro-Delvaille Henri* Chavenon Roland Chéret Jules* Clairin Pierre-Eugène Dauchez André De Dardel Nils* Déziré Henri Fautrier Jean Fix-Masseau Pierre Félix Foujita Léonard Fournier Gabriel Galanis Démétrius Gleizes Albert Goerg Edouard Gris Juan Guénot Auguste Herbin Auguste Heuzé Edmond Huyot Albert Kisling Moïse Kvapil Charles Lipchitz Jacques Lotiron Robert Manguin Henri Mare André Martin Henri Ménard René Miró Joan Muter Mela Ottmann Henri Pascin Jules Péquin Charles Quizet Alphonse Sabbagh Georges-Hanna Schuffenecker Emile* Simon-Lévy* Valmier Georges* Valtat Louis Willette Adolphe* Sex M M M M M M M M M M F M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M M F M M M M M M M M M M * indicates that the artist was not represented permanently in any of the galleries surveyed in 1928-29. 52 Born 1865 1858 1885 1882 1883 1876 1869 1858 1882 1886 1881 1861 1874 1884 1876 1895 1836 1897 1870 1888 1878 1898 1869 1886 1893 1882 1881 1893 1887 1882 1882 1884 1872 1891 1884 1891 1886 1874 1885 1860 1862 1893 1876 1877 1885 1879 1885 1887 1851 1886 1885 1869 1857 Dead 1937 1941 1958 1941 1956 1946 1934 1936 1947 1964 1932 1942 1941 1949 1928 NA 1932 1980 1948 1953 1965 1964 1937 1968 1963 1966 1953 1969 1927 1966 1960 1967 1968 1953 1957 1973 1966 1949 1932 1943 1930 1983 1967 1927 1930 1963 1955 1951 1934 1973 1937 1952 1926 Votes 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1