Competing Retailers and Inventory: An Empirical Investigation of U.S. Automobile Dealerships Gérard P. Cachon Marcelo Olivares The Wharton School, University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia PA, 19104 cachon@wharton.upenn.edu maolivar@wharton.upenn.edu opim.wharton.upenn.edu/~cachon opim.wharton.upenn.edu/~maolivar January 12, 2007 Abstract In this study we empirically estimate the e¤ect of local market conditions on inventory performance of U.S. automobile dealerships. We show that the in‡uence of competition on a retailer’s inventory holdings can be separated into two mechanisms. First, the entry or exit of a competitor can change a retailer’s demand (a sales e¤ect). Second, the entry or exit of a competitor can change the amount of bu¤er stock a retailer chooses to hold, which in‡uences the probability a consumer …nds a desired product in stock (a service level e¤ect). The sales e¤ect can in‡uence inventory through the presence of economies of scale. Theoretical arguments of inventory competition are ambiguous on the expected sign of the service level e¤ect: there are models suggesting that service level increases, decreases or remains constant with entry. We obtained data (via a web crawler) on inventory and sales of auto dealerships of a large manufacturer. Using cross-sectional variation of dealers in isolated markets, we estimated the e¤ect of market structure (number and type of competitors), local demographics and sales on inventory levels. We used market population as an instrumental variable to control for the endogeneity of market structure. Our results suggest a strong positive nonlinear e¤ect of the number of rivals on service levels. Furthermore, we …nd that the impact of competition on inventory via the service level e¤ect is comparable to the impact via the sales e¤ect. Counterfactual experiments indicate that reducing the dealership network of this manufacturer (thereby reducing competition) could reduce the remaining dealers’ days-of-supply (inventory divided by average sale rate) from 13% to 24%. Keywords: Inventory competition, empirical, entry, supply chain management, automobile industry. 1. Introduction There exists a substantial literature on how …rms should manage inventory (e.g. Zipkin (2000)), but less is known about how …rms actually manage inventory. In particular, why does there exist considerable heterogeneity in inventory holdings, even across …rms within a single industry? For example, Table 1 displays data on inventory holdings in the U.S. automobile industry supply chain. During the years 1999-2004, Chevrolet held on-average a 73 day supply of inventory in its supply chain whereas Toyota held only about a 42 day supply. Cachon and Olivares (2006) demonstrate that di¤erences in manufacturing ‡exibility and product assortments across auto makes (i.e., brands) explains nearly half of this gap, but, due to the nature of their data, they are unable to assess whether di¤erences in dealership structure is also a factor. Table 1 indicates that there are indeed dramatic di¤erences across makes. For examples, Toyota has fewer than a third of the number of dealerships as Chevrolet (1200 vs. 4227), but each of their dealership sells on average twice as many vehicles per year (1251 vs. 627). Inventory theory suggests that there generally are economies of scale in managing inventory. Hence, Toyota may carry less inventory in part because their dealerships operate at a higher sales rate. Some Chevrolet dealers sell considerably more vehicles per year than other Chevrolet dealerships, so economies of scale (with respect to sales) could even explain heterogeneity in inventory holdings within a make. However, the U.S. auto makes exhibit other signi…cant di¤erences across their dealership structures. For example, we would expect that Chevrolet dealerships would be geographically located closer to each other than Toyota dealerships because there are simply more of them in the U.S. Furthermore, dealerships are not uniformally distributed across the country. Figure 1 plots the relationship between the ratio of the number of General Motors (GM) dealerships to Japanese brand dealerships (Toyota, Honda and Nissan) by state relative to each state’s population growth. In states with large population growth from 1950 - 2004, such as California and Arizona, there is approximately the same number of GM and Japanese brand dealerships, whereas in slow growth states, such as Iowa and South Dakota, GM dealerships are much more numerous in a relative sense. As a result there exists signi…cant variation in both the number and type of dealerships in local markets. This variation regulates the degree to which dealerships compete and theoretical models predict that inventory is in‡uenced by the intensity of competition. (Interestingly, as we elaborate on in section 2, there is disagreement in the theoretical literature as to how competition in‡uences inventory, i.e., does competition lead …rms to hold more or less inventory.) Finally, in addition to scale and competition e¤ects, we expect that inventory holdings could vary due to di¤erences in consumer characteristics across markets. For example, all else being equal, a …rm’s optimal inventory decreases as its customers become more patient, i.e., more willing to wait for their prefered product rather than choose a competitor’s product. Indeed, European consumers expect to wait 1 to receive their vehicles, so dealerships in Europe carry a very limited supply of on-hand vehicles. Although the U.S. market operates in a very di¤erent fashion (most vehicles in the U.S. are purchased from dealer inventory), there is signi…cant heterogeneity in consumer demographics across the country, which could lead to di¤erences in buying behavior.1 The objective of this paper is to identify how inventory holdings of U.S. automobile dealerships are in‡uenced by economies of scale with respect to sales, market structure (the term we use to describe local competition) and consumer characteristics. We developed a web-crawler to collect data on GM dealerships located in more than 200 isolated markets. Because there is little heterogeneity in dealership structures across time, our empirical strategy is to exploit the cross-sectional variation in these markets to identify the e¤ects of interest. We use instrumental variables to control for the endogeneity of market structure with respect to unobserved market characteristics. We focus on the auto industry because it is economically signi…cant and detailed data on local inventory holdings are available (via our web-crawler). Although our results are speci…c to this industry, our econometric methods could be applied to study inventory in other retail industries. Furthermore, some of our …ndings may apply broadly to other forms of retailing. Our study is related to the growing empirical literature on inventory. Wu et al. (2005) study the relationship between …rm inventory holdings and …nancial performance, while Hendricks and Singhal (2005) study the impact of supply chain disruptions (including problems with inventory) on short term …nancial and accounting measures. Gaur et al. (2005) …nd that retailers’ with higher margins and lower (or higher) assets tend to carry less inventory. Roumiantsev and Netessine (2006) use aggregate inventory data to measure the relationship between demand uncertainty, lead times, gross margins and …rm size on inventory levels. These studies use data on publicly traded …rms and they do not measure the e¤ect of market structure on inventory. Amihud and Mendelson (1989) use public data on manufacturing …rms to estimate the e¤ect of market power (proxied by the …rms’margins and market shares) on inventory levels and variability. They …nd that …rms lower their inventory as market power decreases, i.e., as competition intensi…es. Our study is di¤erent in the sense that we track individual units of inventory and we are able to measure di¤erences in local market structures. Other empirical studies analyze the e¤ect of market structure on product variety. For example, Berry and Waldfogel (2001) …nd that higher market concentration leads to higher product variety in the radio broadcasting industry, showing evidence that …rms use product line expansion to preempt entry. Alexander (1997) …nds a non-monotonic e¤ect of market concentration on product variety in the music recording industry, where the highest level of variety is achieved at a moderately concentrated structure. Inventory is not a primary 1 Holweg and Pil (2004) report that 89% of the sales in the U.S. are …lled from dealership stock, versus 38% in Europe. 2 concern with either of those industries. Watson (2004) also …nds a non-monotonic e¤ect of competition on product variety among eyeglass retailers.2 In the next section, we provide a general econometric framework to measure the e¤ect of sales and competition on inventory. Section 3 describes the data and the speci…cation of the model. Section 4 shows our main results and section 5 provides a sensitivity analysis and further empirical evidence. Section 6 analyzes a conterfactual experiment of changing the dealership network. We conclude and discuss our …ndings in section 7. 2. An empirical model of retail inventory We use a basic single-item periodic review base-stock model to motivate our empirical framework. Orders are received at the beginning of each period with zero lead-time. Let D be i.i.d. normal demand in each period with mean and standard deviation : Some fraction of the demand that is not ful…lled from in-stock inventory is backordered; the remaining demand is lost. Let Q be the order-upto level and z = (Q )= . In this model the service level is the probability that all demand within a period is satis…ed from inventory. The service level is increasing in z; so for convenience we refer to z as the service level with the understanding that it is really a proxy for the service level. The expected inventory at the end of each period, I, is then I = (z + L (z)) (1) where L (z) is the standard normal loss function. It is empirically inconvenient to work with (1) directly because demand is not directly observable. However, it can be shown (see the Appendix for details) that (1) can be written as I = s K (z) (2) where s is the standard deviation of sales (minfQ; Dg) and K (z) is an increasing function. Estimation of s requires an assumption of the relevant period length. Instead, as in van Ryzin and Mahajan (1999), we use (3) s = As to approximate the standard deviation of sales, where s is observed sales over a sample period and A and are coe¢ cients. The coe¢ cient re‡ects the degree to which there are economies of scale in inventory management with respect to sales. If = 1; then days-ofsupply (inventory divided by daily demand rate) is independent of expected sales whereas 2 He …nds that stores with two or three nearby rivals o¤er the highest level of variety, but product variety falls as competition increases beyond that threshold. In auto dealerships, inventory levels can be viewed as a measure of variety because it is rare to have two identical vehicles in stock. Watson (2004) does not observe sales, so unlike in our model, he is unable to distinguish whether competition in‡uences his variable of interest (variety/inventory) via a sales e¤ect or a service level e¤ect. 3 if < 1; then higher sales retailers carry a lower days-of-supply for the same service level. Combining (2) and (3) and taking logarithms yields. log I = constant+ log s + log K (z) (4) The above equation suggests that a …rm’s inventory level can be decomposed into two separate components: a sales component, log s; and a service level component, log K(z): According to (4), market structure can in‡uence a …rm’s inventory either through its sales or through its service level. Suppose the number of …rms competing in a market is taken as the proxy for market structure. If a market’s potential sales is reasonably …xed, then it is intuitive that entry could reduce each …rm’s sales (the …xed market potential is allocated among more …rms). However, entry could increase a retailer’s sales either because price competition is su¢ ciently severe to increase total sales (i.e., total potential demand increases) or via a retail agglomeration e¤ect - consumers may be more likely to search a retailer located near other retailers rather than an isolated retailer because the consumer wishes to economize on search costs. In other words, all else being equal, the potential sales of several …rms located near each other may be greater than their potential sales when they are far apart.3 We are not directly concerned with the speci…c mechanism by which market structure in‡uences sales because we conjecture that these mechanisms in‡uence inventory only through their e¤ect on sales. The other part of (4), the service level, is in‡uenced by several factors. Taking demand to be exogenous, a retailer may choose a service level z to balance the cost of holding too much inventory (overage cost) with the cost of holding too little inventory (underage cost). The overage cost is mainly composed of the opportunity cost of capital, storage costs and depreciation. We assume these are independent of market structure. The underage cost depends on the behavior of consumers when they do not …nd their preferred product either because it is not carried by the retailer or because it is temporarilly out of stock. In such a situation a consumer could purchase some other product at the retailer (substitute), defer purchase of the most preferred product to a later time (backorder) or leave the retailer without making a purchase (the no-purchase option). A retailer’s underage cost is increasing in the retailer’s margin - the larger the margin on each sale, the more costly it is to lose a sale. Furthermore, the underage cost is decreasing in consumers’propensity to substitute or backorder but increasing in the consumers’propensity to choose the no-purchase option. These behaviors probably depend on numerous consumer characteristics, such as the intensity of their preference for the products in the retailer’s assortment, their perception of the cost to search/shop, and their ability and willingness to defer their purchase. Although most inventory models assume demand is exogenous, the retailer’s service level may also in‡uence 3 See Dudey (1990), Eaton and Lipsey (1982), Stahl (1982) and Wollinsky (1983) for models of consumer search in which …rm location decisions are endogenous. 4 its demand, i.e., a retailer’s demand may be endogenously determined by its service level. As a result, in addition to balancing overage and underage costs, a retailer may use its target service level to attract and/or retain customers. (Dana and Petruzzi (2001) and Gerchak and Wang (1994) develop single-…rm models where a higher service level attracts more demand). Therefore, market structure can in‡uence service levels through two mechanisms: overage/underage costs or endogenous demand. Deneckre and Peck (1995) consider n retailers that compete on price and quantity where consumers can observe both prices and quantities before making their …rm choice. As a result, competition can in‡uence each …rms’underage cost (via price competition that may reduce margins) and each …rm can increase its demand via o¤ering higher service (i.e., demand is endogenous because consumers are attracted to …rms that they believe to have higher service levels). If an equilibrium exists, they …nd that equilibrium prices are decreasing in n; but service levels are nevertheless independent of n:4 This surprising result implies that the two e¤ect of market structure on service levels are o¤setting each other in their model. Dana (2001) modi…es the Deneckre and Peck (1995) model and indeed …nds that entry can reduce service levels - the e¤ect of price competition on the …rms’underage costs can dominate the endogenous demand e¤ect.5 The analogous conclusion can be inferred from Bernstein and Federgruen (2005).6 Other models obtain the same result, but the causality is reversed: competition induces …rms to reduce their service level, even if a 100% service level is costless, because lower service levels dampen price competition (see Balachander and 4 There are other models that …nd the same result for a di¤erent reason. Suppose retailers face stochastic demand, …xed retail prices and each retailer’s strategic decision is its initial stocking quantity (e.g., Lippman and McCardle (1997), Mahajan and van Ryzin (2001), Netessine and Rudi (2003)) Furthermore, the a priori allocation of demand is exogenous, so …rms only in‡uence each other through spillover demand, i.e., if a retailer’s initial demand exceeds its stocking quantity then some portion of this excess demand visits another …rm in an attempt to …nd stock. In Deneckre and Peck (1995) there is no spillover demand …rms compete in the initial allocation of demand. Because competition does not impact price and each …rm cannot in‡uence its initial demand via its stocking decision, each …rm’s optimal service level is independent of market structure, where service level in this case is (as in our base-stock model) the probability all demand is satis…ed immediately from stock. Hence, monopolists and duopolists choose the same service level. Note, they do not choose the same stocking level because market structure also in‡uences inventory via sales - a duopolist does not sell the same amount as a monopolist. 5 Dana (2001) shows that prices and service levels decrease in n with the following sequence: …rms choose stocking quantities, …rms observe the quantity choices, …rms choose prices and …nally consumers make their …rm choices based on observed prices and their expectations of the …rms’ stocking quantities given their prices. Dana (2001) also studies a model in which prices are chosen …rst and observed by all …rms and consumers and then …rms choose quantities. With that sequence service levels are independent of n; as in Deneckere and Peck (1995). Note, in Dana (2001) …rms that deviate from equilibrium by o¤ering higher availability do not attract more customers because availability is unobservable. Hence, incentives to increase availability are softened relative to Deneckre and Peck (1995). 6 If prices decrease, Bernstein and Federgruen (2005) …nd that service levels decrease, but they do not explicitly study the impact of market structure, and their model is ill suited to do so. To explain, their model of retailer i’s demand is Di (p) = di (p)"i ; where p is the vector of retail prices, di (p) is a deterministic demand function and "i is a stochastic shock. It is not clear how to modify "i to account for …rm entry. It is possible to make assumptions regarding the impact of entry on "i but they do not do so. 5 Farquhar (1994) and Daugherty and Reinganum (1991)). Consistent with the hypothesis that competition leads to lower service levels, Gaur et al. (2005) …nd that retailers with lower margins carry lower inventory and Amihud and Mendelson (1989) provide evidence of a direct link between market power and inventory levels.7 In Cachon (2003) …rms compete on their service levels but prices are …xed: demand is allocated to n retailers proportional to their stocking quantities. (This is a special case of the Deneckre and Peck (1995) model with …xed prices) There is only the demand attraction e¤ect in this model (competition has no impact on the …rms’underage costs because prices are …xed), so he …nds that service levels are increasing in n: each retailer ignores the marginal impact its inventory decision has on the demand allocation of the other retailers, so increased competition results in more aggressive stocking levels. The Cachon (2003) model lacks product variety and consumer search. Now suppose …rms compete both in terms of the breadth and depth of their assortment and consumers must shop around to …nd a product that matches their preferences at a reasonable price. Recall, if a consumer does not …nd their most preferred item at a retailer the consumer can substitute, backorder or no-purchase. The no-purchase option can mean either shopping another retailer, if one is available, or literally never buying an item. Hence, the no-purchase option is less desirable to a consumer in a monopoly market than in a duopoly market - in a monopoly market no-purchase means never-purchase whereas in a duopoly market the nopurchase option includes shopping and possibly buying something from the other retailer. Because, all else being equal, a monopolist could expect its customers to be more likely to substitute or backorder, the monopolist’s optimal service level is lower than the duopolist’s - increased competition could lead to higher service levels due to consumer preferences for variety, i.e., a demand retention e¤ect.8 To summarize, theoretical models of inventory competition predict service levels are either decreasing, independent or increasing with respect to entry. Additional competition reduces service levels if the impact of price competition on margins is severe, whereas additional competition increases service levels if the endogenous demand e¤ect is strong (i.e., if higher service levels either attract additional demand or help to retain demand). Given this discussion, we now further elaborate on (4). For each retailer i and product category b; based on the periodic review model, inventory, Iib; is determined by a combination of sales, sib ; and the service level, zib . (We now distinguish products by category because it is plausible that inventory levels across categories at the same retailer have di¤erent motivations to hold inventory.) Market structure can in‡uence sales and possibly service level, but there 7 Gaur et al. (2005) do not directly link retail competition to inventory level - they only observe a correlation between margins and inventory turnover. Amihud and Mendelson (1989) also explore the variability of inventory holdings. 8 See Cachon et al. (2006) and Watson (2006) for formal models in which …rms compete on prices and product assortment. However, demand in their models is (e¤ectively) deterministic, so it is di¢ cult to interpret their results with respect to the impact of entry on service levels. 6 are other factors that could potentially in‡uence service level (e.g., consumer characteristics). We assume the following reduced form for the e¤ect of service level: log K (zib ) = k + Cib + mib + Xib + ib (5) The term mib captures the e¤ect of the margin (mib ) on service level. Based on Dana (2001) and the empirical …ndings of Gaur et al. (2005), we would expect to be positive. Covariates in Cib include di¤erent measures of competition and market structure, such as the number of rival stores in the same market as …rm i o¤ering products that are substitutes for b. Cib measures the impact of competition on service level, net of price competition. According to either an inventory competition e¤ect (Cachon (2003)) or a consumer preference for variety e¤ect, we expect to be positive. Xib and ib denote other observable and unobservable factors, respectively, that a¤ect service level. Covariates in Xib include demographic characteristics of the markets that capture di¤erences in consumer characteristics which in‡uence a retailer’s optimal service level. For example, if a certain demographic of consumers (e.g., college educated) has a particular a¢ nity for a retailer’s product (so that they are unwilling to choose the no-purchase option) then retailers in markets with a high concentration of these types of consumers may have a lower optimal service level. In some applications, including the one studied in this paper, margins are unobserved.9 The linear projection of margin on market structure is de…ned as mib = Cib + ib , where ib denotes other factors determining margins. We expect that competition reduces margins, i.e., < 0: Replacing (5) in (4) and mib for its linear projection gives the following model, which we seek to estimate using data from a cross section of retailers: log Iib = + log sib + Cib + Xib + ib : (6) The coe¢ cient + measures the overall e¤ect of market structure on the service level, including price competition. Note, with this formulation we estimate the net e¤ect of various mechanisms by which competition can in‡uence service level, ; but we do not estimate each of them separately. The term ib = ib + ib captures factors unobserved by the econometrician that a¤ect the service level, either directly or through margin. Other control variables may be needed, depending on the application. For example, it may be necessary to include controls for di¤erences in the retailers’supply processes (e.g., retailers may vary in how frequently they are replenished and in the average size of each replenishment). The parameters to be estimated are = ( ; ; ; ) : We are interested in the magnitude of ( = 1 means there are no economies of scale with respect to sales) and the sign and magnitude of ( < 0 suggests that the margin e¤ect of competition dominates whereas > 0 suggests that the demand attraction/retention e¤ects dominate). 9 An alternative is to use price as a proxy for margin. We do not have data on transaction prices of automobiles. 7 There are several challenges associated with the the identi…cation of : It is important to de…ne each retailer’s market appropriately, otherwise Cib may be a poor measure for competition and Xib may be a poor measure of consumer characteristics. We attempt to alleviate this concern by identifying geographically isolated markets. To estimate precisely, it is important that the selected markets have su¢ cient variation in market structure. The endogeneity of market structure is of particular concern with respect to the identi…cation of : Retailers choose which markets to enter and they may do so based on market characteristics that they observe but are unobserved by the econometrician. Inventory costs a¤ect dealership pro…ts, therefore entry decisions are a¤ected by factors that in‡uence inventory, including ib . If such is the case, Cib and ib may be correlated and estimating (6) using Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) would lead to biased estimates. We use Instrumental Variables (IV) to obtain consistent estimates of and assess the magnitude of the endogeneity bias. We seek an observable instrument that is correlated with market structure, Cib ; but uncorrelated with unobservable consumer characteristics in ib : We use market population as our main instrument on the assumption that population is correlated with entry (more …rms enter as a market’s population increases) and population is uncorrelated with unobserved consumer characteristics that in‡uence service level conditional on the observed controls in Xib :10 Sales can also be endogenous in (6). A product is likely to have higher sales in markets where consumers have high idiosyncratic valuation for the product. These consumers’ characteristics may also a¤ect their purchasing behavior, leading to a di¤erent service level. To assess the magnitude and sign of this potential bias, we estimate including market …xed e¤ects in (6). In this model, is identi…ed through di¤erences in sales volume across stores located in the same market. This approach is feasible only in markets where two or more retailers are observed. Furthermore, if Cib is common to all products and retailers in a market, then is not identi…ed because the e¤ect of competition is absorbed into the market …xed e¤ect. 3. Data This section provides a brief description of the U.S. auto industry and details the data in our study. Six companies account for about 90% of sales in the U.S. auto market: Daimler-Chrysler (DC), Ford, GM, Honda, Nissan and Toyota. We refer to DC, Ford and GM as domestic manufacturers. Each company o¤ers vehicles under several brands or auto makes. For example, GM makes include Chevrolet, GMC, Pontiac, Buick, Saturn, Cadillac and Hummer11 . 10 The assumption that larger markets lead to more entry can be veri…ed empirically when markets are well de…ned. 11 GM closed its Oldsmobile brand in 2000. 8 Each auto make produces several models. Examples include the Chevrolet Malibu, the Toyota Camry and the Ford Explorer. Models can be classi…ed into vehicle classes, including cars, sports cars, Sport Utility Vehicles (SUV) and pickups, among others. Each model is o¤ered with multiple options, which include di¤erent body styles, engines, transmission types and breaking systems, among other features. In the U.S., more than 90% of new passenger vehicles are purchased from dealership inventory. Auto distribution is regulated by franchise laws, which require that all new vehicles must be sold through a network of dedicated franchised dealers.12 As of 2006, there are approximately 22,000 dealerships in the U.S. The number of dealerships has been declining in the U.S. since it peak in 1930 when there were about 50,000 dealerships (Marx (1985)). 3.1 De…nition of Markets Based on (6), we seek to de…ne isolated markets so that we can accurately proxy for the level of competition within the market. Markets are de…ned by isolated Urban Areas (UA) of population below 150,00013 . The criteria used to determine whether a UA is isolated depends on the population of the UA. These criteria are summarized in Table 2. For example, a UA with population between 50 and 100 thousand will qualify as an isolated market if it is at least 50 miles away from the closest UA with population above 100 thousand and 30 miles away from the closest UA with population above 50 thousand. Note, these criteria impose minimum distance requirements to markets of equal or larger size. Our rationale behind these criteria is that consumers not …nding their desired product inside the market will consider travelling to the closest market which o¤ers the product. This tends to be a more populous market. Similar rationale was utilized by Dranove et al. (1992) and Bresnahan and Reiss (1991) to de…ne markets. From these markets, we selected those which had at least one GM dealership. (As we describe later, our data are from GM dealerships.) Based on these criteria, we obtained 235 isolated markets. We obtained demographic data and geo-coded information (latitude and longitude) for these markets from the 2000 decennial census. 37%, 5%, 26% and 31% of the markets are located in the Mid-West, North-East, South and West census regions, respectively. Data on new vehicle dealerships located in each market were obtained from edmunds.com.14 Table 3 describes the selected markets. We grouped markets according to the total number of Ford, DC, GM, Honda, Toyota and Nissan dealerships. The second column of 12 Smith (1982) provides a detailed analysis of dealership franchise laws. We used UAs de…ned in the 2000 Census. These include: (i) urban areas consisting of territory with a general population density of at least 1,000 people per square mile of land area that together have a minimum residential population of at least 50,000 people; and (ii) urban cluster of densely settled territory with at least 2,500 people but fewer than 50,000. 14 We matched dealers to UA based on 5 digit zipcodes. Matching tables were obtained from the Missouri Census Data Center (http://mcdc2.missouri.edu). 13 9 the table shows the number of markets with the observed number of dealers. For example, there are 17 monopoly markets with one GM dealership. In more than 90% of the markets, the number of dealerships is in the range 1 to 10. The number of dealerships increases with market size, measured by population (third column). The last three columns show the percent of markets with at least one dealership of non-GM domestic manufacturers (Ford or DC), Japanese manufacturers (Toyota, Honda or Nissan) and a second GM dealership, respectively. The …rst competitor faced by a GM dealer is usually a non-GM domestic dealership. Japanese dealerships usually enter markets with three or more dealerships. All of the observed markets with six or more dealerships have at least one GM, one non-GM domestic and one Japanese dealership. Several markets have more than one GM dealership. In all but 5 markets, the GM dealers carry franchises of di¤erent brands. The table shows that the selected markets have su¢ ciently rich variation in market structure, both in the number and type of dealerships. We obtained the following demographic data for each market: percent of population above 60 years old (OLD), African-American (BLACK ), with college (COLLEGE ), active in the army (ARMY ), with farming occupation (FARMING) and using public transportation to commute to work (PUBTRANS ). We also obtained median household income for each UA (INCOME ) and the voting turnout and percent of republican votes for the county of each market (TURNOUT and REPUBLICAN, respectively, obtained from uselectionatlas.org). Summary statistics of these variable are shown in Table 4. We included BLACK, INCOME, COLLEGE, REPUBLICAN, TURNOUT, OLD, and FARMING in Xib because these variables have substantial partial correlation with the number of dealerships in a market (see Appendix Table 11). In addition, we included PUBTRANS and ARMY to capture potential di¤erences in consumer characteristics and their a¢ nity to GM brands. 3.2 Model speci…cation We obtained inventory and sales data from a website o¤ered by GM that enables customers to search new vehicle inventory at local dealerships15 . We developed a web-crawler that monitors daily inventory in all the GM dealerships located in the selected markets. We obtained data only for GM dealerships16 . For our empirical study, we collected data from July 20 to November 15 of 2006. The web-crawler keeps record of the number and type of vehicles available at each dealership. For example, it records the number of GMC Yukon 2007 15 http://www.gmbuypower.com Developing web-crawlers for each manufacturer would require substantial additional e¤ort. Some websites o¤er inventory search for dealerships of several brands (e.g. nada.org) but many of these are not suitable for the large-scale data collection that we require. We monitored our web-crawler frequently in case changes were made to the website. In fact, during our study period GM did change its website. Substantial e¤ort was required to repair the crawler. 16 10 4WD available at each dealer. The web-crawler also keeps track of speci…c information of each vehicle, such as color, options, list price and, more importantly, the vehicle identi…cation number (VIN) which uniquely identi…es all new vehicles in the U.S. By keeping track of the speci…c VINs available at each dealership, we can identify replenishments and sales. We also observe some vehicles that are transferred from one dealership to another. As we show below, data on transfers are used in our estimation. Because in our markets there is only one GM dealership o¤ering each brand, transfers are always received from a dealership outside the market. To identify all vehicles transferred between dealers it is necessary to monitor all dealerships in the U.S., which is infeasible. Instead, we monitored all dealerships in seven states.17 To validate the data, we visited three dealerships in the Philadelphia area18 . Most of the vehicles found at the three dealers lot during June 2, 2006 were posted in the website during that day19 . The dealerships visited declined to provide data on the speci…c vehicles sold. To estimate model (6), we de…ned the dependent variable as the average vehicle inventory of each brand b at a GM dealership i.20 We imputed total sales (SALES ) of each make during the study period to measure sib .21 We include the demographic variables in Xib . We estimated several speci…cations for the competition e¤ect, Cib : The simplest measure is a linear e¤ect of the number of dealerships in the market (NC ). We restricted the dealership counts to the following manufacturers: GM, DC, Ford, Toyota, Honda and Nissan. The square of this variable (NCSQ) is included in some speci…cations to test for non-linearities. We also estimated the e¤ect of the number of rivals using a ‡exible non-parametric speci…cation, with indicator variables of the form x = 1 fN C xg ; with x 2 f1::Nmax g : x measures the e¤ect of the xth entrant on service level. We restricted our sample to markets with 10 or fewer dealerships to measure this e¤ect more precisely (Nmax = 10). We also used an alternative measure of competition de…ned as the presence of dealerships of di¤erent manufacturers. We de…ned three measures: HASDOM, HASJAP and HASGM2, which capture the presence of non-GM domestic dealerships (Ford and DC), Japanese dealerships (Toyota, Honda and Nissan) and a second GM dealership in the markets (recall that in all our markets there is at least one GM dealership). To measure potential competition from outside the market, we included the driving time to the closest GM dealership outside the UA (GMDRIVET ).22 Driving time was used to 17 The selected states are Colorado, Nebraska, Florida, Wisconsin, Maine, California and Texas. These states are geographically relatively isolated (they border Mexico or Canada, they have a substantial coastline and/or their border areas are sparsely populated) and exhibit variation in population growth (see Figure 1). 18 We selected this dealerships by convenience. None of the selected markets are in the Philadelphia area. 19 The dealership lots include many vehicles (sometime more than 100) and the authors could not verify all of them. 20 We excluded the HUMMER brand from our analysis because it is present in only one of the markets in our study. 21 Sales included vehicles transferred to other dealerships. 22 We used Rand McNally’s website to obtain driving distances and time. 11 capture the e¤ect of nearby highways on transportation costs. We also estimated models with “bird-‡y”distance (using latitude and longitude data) and to GM dealerships carrying the same brand. Our results were similar with these alternative measures. GM dealerships can own multiple franchises of GM brands. If customers substitute between di¤erent GM brands, a stock-out in one brand is less likely to become a lost sale for a multi-brand dealership, because customers may buy a vehicle from another brand in the lot. If inter-brand substitution within GM is substantial, we expect the number of franchises carried by a dealership (NFRANCH ) to have a negative e¤ect on the service level. Dealership inventories are a¤ected by other factors in addition to sales and service levels. We include two measures that control for di¤erences in the dealerships’ supply processes. Due to …xed transportation costs, dealerships receive vehicles in batches. Larger batch sizes increase average inventory levels. Let Qibt be the total incoming orders (without transfers from other dealerships) of product category b in week t to retailer i. To proxy batch size, we calculated the coe¢ cient of variation of the volume of weekly incoming orders: p V (Qibt ) CV Qib = E (Qibt ) where V ( ) and E ( ) are the variance and expectation operators, respectively. CVQ is positively correlated with batch size, therefore we expect to see a positive e¤ect of this variable on inventory levels23 . It is common to observe vehicle transfers between dealerships that carry the same make. Let Tib be the total amount of transfers received of product category b by dealership i. We measure the percent of transfers received as: TRANSF ib = Tib + Tib P15 i=1 Qibt (the denominator is the total number of vehicles received during the 15 weeks of the study period, including transfers). Transfers enable dealerships to share inventory and bene…t from risk pooling. Hence, we expected TRANSF to have a negative e¤ect on average inventory levels.24 Recall, we are unlikely to observe all the transfers for all dealerships. We include a dummy, ALLSTATE, indicating whether the dealership is located in one of the states where 23 Consider two dealership with the same sales volume S per week. Dealership A is replenished every week, with a batch size of p S. Dealership B is replenished every two weeks, with a batch size of 2S. Clearly, CV QA = 0 < CV QB = 2: We used weekly replenishments to reduce measurement error. 24 Anupindi and Bassok (1992) show that centralization of inventory stocks of multiple retailers usually decreases total inventory relative to the descentralized case where each retailer chooses their inventory level independently. Rudi et al. (2001) analyze a model of two newsvendors with transshipments of left-over inventory. It can be shown that their model implies a negative association between the average number of transfers received by a retailer and its service level. Narus and Anderson (1996) report inventory reductions from inventory sharing initiatives in several industries operating with descentralized distribution networks. 12 we monitored all dealerships.25 Table 5 shows summary statistics and correlation matrix of the main variables in the econometric model. The structural model underlying equation (6) suggest that coe¢ cient captures statistical economies of scale associated with sales volume. In auto dealerships, there are additional economies of scale in sales volume. CVQ controls for economies of scale arising from …xed ordering costs (such as order processing and transportation).26 We believe that statistical economies of scale (i.e., the coe¢ cient of variation in sales decreases in the level of sales) and …xed ordering costs are the main sources of economies of scale in auto distribution. If CVQ is a good proxy for batch size, then the estimated can be interpreted as a measure of statistical economies of scale. 3.3 Instrumental variables We use two measures of market population to instrument for market structure (all based in data from the 2000 decennial census). The …rst one is total population in the UA (UAPOP). The second one is fringe population (FRINGEPOP). The fringe of a UA is de…ned as the population of all zipcodes outside the UA within a 100 miles radius for which the UA is the closest UA with dealerships27 . In some speci…cations, we use additional instruments to increase e¢ ciency in the estimation. Franchising laws impose costs on the manufacturer to close existing dealerships. Markets with current low population which had higher population in the past are likely to have more dealerships than those which never had a large population. Due to this “stickiness” in dealership exit, past population has positive partial correlation (conditional on current population) with the number of dealerships. We use county population in 1950 and 1970 (POP50, POP70 )28 . We also use county population in 2000 (POP2K ) as an additional measure of current market size. All population measures were included with natural log transformation because it provided better …t in the …rst step estimates of the IV regressions. 25 If the coe¢ cient on TRANSF is negative, we expect ALLSTATE to be positive because for the observations with ALLSTATE=0 a fraction of the transfers are unobserved. In all the speci…cations analyzed, the coe¢ cient on ALLSTATE was positive and signi…cant. The average percent of transfers for dealerships with ALLSTATE=0 and ALLSTATE=1 is 4.5% and 10%, respectively. 26 Indeed, there is substantial negative correlation between logSALES and CVQ. 27 A similar measure was used by Dranove et al. (1992). We calculated distances using latitude and longitude. The census proxy of zipcodes (ZCTAs) were used. 28 Historical county population was obtained from the Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Sciences (ICPSR). 13 4. Results Table 6 shows the estimation results. In all the speci…cations the dependent variable is logINV. Columns 1 through 6 include demographic control variables and the dummies for make, region and ALLSTATE. The estimated coe¢ cients on these controls are ommited for ease of visualization (a full description of the estimates of column 1 and 3 are shown in the Appendix Table 10). Column 1 shows the OLS estimates of the regression including the number of dealerships in the market (NC ) as a measure of competition. The coe¢ cient on NC measures the average e¤ect of an additional dealership in the market, within the range 1 to 10. The coe¢ cient is positive and measured with precision. Increasing the number of dealerships by one standard deviation (2.6 dealers, approximately) increases inventory by approximately 6.8%. Batch sizes, proxied by CVQ, have a positive (and statistically signi…cant) e¤ect on inventory, as expected. The use of transfers from other dealerships, measured by TRANSF, has a large economic (and statistically signi…cant) e¤ect in reducing inventory levels. Increasing TRANSF by 0.1 (a 10% increase in the fraction of supply received from transfers) reduces inventory by 8.9%. Similar estimates were obtained for the e¤ect of transfers and batch sizes across all the speci…cations analyzed. The coe¢ cients on GMDRIVET and NFRANCH are small and not statistically signi…cant, suggesting that competition from outside the market and substitution from other brands in multi-franchise dealerships is relatively small. Our market de…nition seems to capture well the local competition faced by a dealership. Sales volume has the highest explanatory power in describing inventory variations across dealerships. The magnitude of the coe¢ cient suggest substantial economies of scale: a 10% increase in sales translates into a 2.6% decrease in days-of-supply ( (1 ) 10% ). In all the speci…cations, the estimated coe¢ cient is between .68 and .74. Column 2 instruments for NC using population in the UA and fringe population as instrumental variables. The point estimate of the NC coe¢ cient is positive and statistically signi…cant. A Hausman test cannot reject that the estimates of columns 1 and 2 are equal at any reasonable con…dence level (p-value 0.87). We also tested for the equality of the single NC coe¢ cient and rejected the null (p-value less than 0.01)29 . There is some evidence suggesting that OLS underestimates the e¤ect of competition. Nevertheless, the number of dealerships has a positive e¤ect in the OLS and IV estimates. The …rst step regression has an R-square of 0.76. The excluded variable UAPOP has the largest explanatory power in describing variation in the number of dealerships. A full description of the …rst step estimates are shown in Appendix Table 11. In column 3, we estimate a non-linear e¤ect of competition, including a linear and a quadratic term on the number of dealerships (NC and NCSQ). We …nd strong evidence 29 See Wooldridge (2002) pg. 120 for details on the test. 14 of decreasing marginal e¤ects of the number of dealerships on service level. The impact of the …rst rivals is substantially larger than the average e¤ect estimated in column 1 and 2. The top part of Figure 2 illustrates the estimated impact of the number of dealerships on inventory, measured by the percent change relative to a monopolist. Upper and lower bounds of the 95% con…dence interval are illustrated with + and - symbols, respectively (the standard errors are calculated using the delta method, see Hayashi (2000)). Column 4 instruments NC and NCSQ using the instruments of column 2 (UAPOP and FRINGEPOP) plus measures of past and current county population (POP50, POP70 and POP2K ). The coe¢ cients on NC and NCSQ have the same sign as in column 3 and both have high statistical signi…cance. While the magnitude of the estimates are di¤erent, the marginal e¤ect at the mean is similar (aproximately 0.04). The IV estimates also suggest a positive and marginally decreasing e¤ect of competition on service level. In column 5 we estimate the e¤ect of competition using a ‡exible non-parametric speci…cation. We include seven indicator variables of the form 1 fN C xg with x 2 f2; 3; 4; 5; 6; 7; 9g : The results provide strong evidence of a non-linear e¤ect of competition in service level. The …rst rivals have the highest impact, and the e¤ect diminishes as the number of dealerships in the market increases. The bottom part of Figure 2 illustrates the coe¢ cient estimates, where the e¤ect is measured as the percent change in inventory relative to a monopolist30 . Interestingly, the quadratic polynomial model estimated in column 3 approximates very well the ‡exible non-parametric model. The large number of endogenous variables in the non-parametric speci…cation makes IV estimation infeasible. Column 6 uses indicators for the presence of di¤erent type of rivals in the market (HASDOMESTIC, HASJAPAN and HASGM2 ). The three measures are positive and highly signi…cant. Non-GM domestic rivals have the largest e¤ect in increasing the service level: GM dealerships in markets with Ford and DC dealerships have approximately 26% more inventory (controlling for sales) compared to markets where these rivals are not present. 5. Sensitivity analysis and further empirical evidence In this section, we do a sensitivity analysis and provide additional empirical evidence to test the robustness of our results. Model (6) suggests a linear relationship between the logarithms of inventory and sales. Furthermore, the model forces the slope to be constant across markets and una¤ected by market structure. We analyzed a scatter plot of logINV versus logSALES for three types of markets: GM monopoly markets, markets with GM and non-GM domestic dealers, and markets with all kinds of dealerships (GM, non-GM domestic and Japanese).31 We …nd a 30 To make the …gure, we estimated the model with NC measured in levels. Standard errors, which are used to plot the 95% con…dence intervals, were calculated using the delta method. 31 The scatter plot is shown in the Appendix. 15 strong linear relationship between the two variables. We regressed logINV on logSALES allowing for di¤erent slopes and intercepts across the three groups. We cannot reject that the slopes of the three series are equal (p-value= .4)32 . The R-square of the regression is 0.93. This analysis suggests that there are no interaction e¤ects between logSALES and market structure, i.e., the e¤ect of competition on service level is separable from the e¤ect of sales. The regressions in Table 6 treat sales as exogenous. To test for potential biases in the estimated coe¢ cient, we add market dummy variables to control for unobserved market characteristics that could be correlated with sales. Note, market dummies control for all market speci…c characteristics (including market structure), so in this regression the coe¢ cients of NC and the demographic controls in X are not identi…ed. We limit the sample to markets with two or more GM dealerships and estimate using within-market variation in dealership sales (373 observations in total). The estimated is 0:608 with standard error SE ( ) = :037. A Hausman test rejects the estimated coe¢ cient from being equal to the one obtained in column 3. The estimated reported in Table 6 seems to have a positive bias, meaning that they under-estimate the e¤ect of economies of scale. In regressions over the subsample of dealerships with ALLSTATE=1 the estimates of and the competition e¤ect are similar in magnitude, sign and statistical signi…cance to those reported in Table 6. In section 4 we use market population as an IV to identify a causal e¤ect of competition on service level. The main concern of using OLS is that the positive correlation between competition and service level is driven by unobserved factors that a¤ect both variables rather than a causal e¤ect of competition. For example, GM rivals may have higher incentives to enter markets where consumer’s a¢ nity for GM brands is lower. These are markets where GM is also likely to set a higher service level. Given all the demographic controls included in Xib , we believe that it is unlikely that unobserved consumer characteristics that a¤ect service level are correlated with market population. Hence, the IV estimates should be consistent. Nevertheless, we provide additional results following a di¤erent identi…cation strategy which corroborate our …ndings. We conjecture that dealerships raise their service level when facing more intense competition to prevent losing customers to rival stores.33 If so, it is then reasonable to expect that the e¤ect of entry on service level depends not only in the number of dealerships in a market but also on the number and type of products that they o¤er. An entrant that o¤ers more models which are close substitutes to the products o¤ered by the incumbents should trigger a larger increase in the service level. Cachon and Olivares (2006) show that aggregate 32 We also conducted pairwise tests of the coe¢ cients. The smallest p-value among the three tests was .24 33 This e¤ect is suggested by Cachon (2003) and the consumer retention e¤ect that we propose in Section . 2. 16 days of supply of a model tends to increase with the number of models o¤ered in the same segment, providing some support for our conjecture. To validate our conjecture, we estimate equation (6) using the number of models o¤ered by rival dealerships as a measure of competition. We include several measures of competition based on product characteristics. Following the literature of spatial competition (e.g. Seim (2006)), we de…ne di¤erent bands where the products o¤ered by rival dealerships can be located. These bands de…ne a measure of “distance”between product b and products o¤ered by rivals. The de…nition of the bands is based on a market segmentation commonly used in the auto industry. While these de…nitions can be subjective, they work reasonably well with some product categories to capture the degree of similarity across products. We conjecture that the number of products in closer bands should have a higher impact on the service level than products located in the outer bands. On the contrary, if the positive correlation between competition and service level is driven by unobserved characteristics related to a¢ nity for GM brands, then products in all bands should have the same positive e¤ect on service level. Let be the set of all models o¤ered in model-year 2007. For a given product b, we 1 K de…ne a partition of the set of products . We refer to kb as the k th band of b ::: b product b. Bands are de…ned so that their distance to product b is increasing in k: Let Cibk be the number of models in band kb o¤ered by the rivals of dealership i: The number of models o¤ered is calculated based on the brands carried by each rival dealership and the list of models o¤ered by each brand34 . We included dealerships of all manufacturers (not just t the six included in the previous estimation). De…ne the column vector Cib = Cib1 :::CibK and the row vector of parameters = 1 ::: K : The parameter k measures the average e¤ect of adding a model in the k th band to the assortment of a rival dealership in the market. This model is di¤erent to the speci…cation de…ned in Section 3.2 because the e¤ect of competition depends not only in the number of dealerships in the market but also the number and type of models that they o¤er. We de…ne product bands based on Ward’s model segmentation, which classi…es models into several groups based on three dimensions. Models are partitioned into vehicle classes, which include standard car, luxury car, sport utility vehicle, cross utility vehicle, van and pickup. Within each class, models are classi…ed according to sizes (small, medium and large) and prices (lower, middle, upper, etc.). This gives a total of 26 segments, which are shown in the Appendix Table 13. For our empirical analysis, we focused in groups of products for which at least three product bands can be reasonably de…ned. We chose small and medium sized standard cars (hereon SM cars, which exclude luxury and large cars) and light-trucks (hereon Trucks, which include SUV, CUV and mini-van)35 . We de…ned bands for the segments on each of these 34 We do not know the actual number of models o¤ered since we do not observe inventory of dealerships other than GM. 35 Full-sized vans and pickups are excluded because we could not obtain inventory data on them. We 17 two groups and ran two separate regressions. The dependent variable is the logarithm of the average inventory level of models in a speci…c model segment o¤ered by each dealership. For example, for the SM car regression, inventory of "Lower Small Car" and "Upper Middle Car" of a speci…c dealership is counted as two di¤erent observations. For SM cars, four bands were de…ned. The …rst band includes standard cars which have similar size or price (B(PRICE,SIZE)). The second band includes all other standard cars (B(STDCAR)). The third and fourth band includes luxury cars and light-trucks, respectively (B(ANYCAR) and B(OTHER))36 . For trucks, we de…ned three bands. The …rst band includes vehicles within the same class with similar size or price (B(PRICE,SIZE)). For example, if b ="Middle SUV", band 1 includes vehicles in the segments "Middle Luxury SUV" and "Large SUV" but not "Large Luxury SUV" nor "Middle CUV". Band 2 includes all other trucks (B(TRUCK)), and band 3 all cars (B(OTHER)). Table 7 summarizes the estimation results of the regressions for SM cars and Trucks. All the speci…cations include dummies for region, price (based on the model segmentation) and ALLSTATE and demographic characteristics37 . Columns 1 and 3 include the number of vehicles on each band as the measure of competition. While none of the measures are statistically signi…cant, the …rst band B(PRICE,SIZE) has the largest positive point estimate of all the bands. In columns 2 and 4 we add a quadratic term on the number of vehicles on the …rst band (SQ B(PRICE,SIZE)) to capture non-linearities. The results show that the number of vehicles in the …rst band has a positive e¤ect on the service level, and the marginal e¤ect is decreasing in the number of vehicles. The number of vehicles in the outer bands have no signi…cant e¤ect on the service level (conditional on the number of models in the …rst band). The results are similar in sign, magnitude and statistical signi…cance across the two groups. To compare the magnitude of the competition e¤ect between the product competition and dealership competition models, we calculated the elasticities at the mean implied by each model. For the dealership competition model estimated in Table 6, column 3, the implied elasticity is 22%. For the SM car and Truck product competition models, the implied elasticities are 32% and 20%, respectively. The average elasticities across the models are similar in order of magnitude, suggesting that the estimated e¤ect of competition is robust to di¤erent speci…cations and identi…cation strategies. The empirical results can be interpreted as follows. First, the number of vehicles o¤ered by rivals has a positive e¤ect on the service level of the products o¤ered by a dealership. The e¤ect of competition in service level is increasing in the number of products o¤ered by an entrant. Second, most of the e¤ect is captured by products which are closer substitutes. excluded large and luxury cars because bands for this type of vehicles could not be reasonably de…ned. 36 We also ran regressions merging bands 3 and 4, and obtained similar results. 37 Given the detailed unit of analysis, there were few replenishments for each observation, making CVQ very noisy. We excluded this measure from the regression. 18 The e¤ect of competition in service level depends not only on the number but also on the type of products o¤ered by an entrant. Third, there is a saturation e¤ect: the …rst close substitutes have a large impact in the service level, but the e¤ect becomes smaller as more products enter the …rst band. Overall, these empirical results provide good support for our conjecture that the intensity of inventory competition depends on the number and type of products o¤ered in a market. This pattern is unlikely to be driven by unobserved market characteristics a¤ecting service level. 6. The e¤ect of reducing the dealership network Domestic manufacturers started expanding their dealership networks in the early 1900’s. At that time a large fraction of the U.S. population was living in rural areas and transportation was di¢ cult. As a result, many dealerships were established so that they could be close to population centers. The Japanese manufacturers started their dealership networks in the second half of the century. Due to improved transportation and a greater concentration of the population in urban areas, there are fewer Japanese brand dealerships and they are concentrated in di¤erent regions of the country than the domestic manufacturers. (See Figure 1.) Due to rigid franchise laws that impose high costs on manufacturers for forcing the closure of a dealership, the domestic manufacturers still have considerably more dealerships than the Japanese brands. (GM paid more than one billion dollars to dealers to close its Oldsmobile division (Welch (2006)).) Domestic manufacturers are concerned that the large number of dealerships in their network is causing ine¢ ciencies. As a result, there is discussion on the value of reducing the number of dealerships, despite the costs of doing so (Rechtin and Wilson (2006)). Closing a dealership in a market has two e¤ects on inventory of the remaining dealerships. First, some of the sales of the closed dealership will be captured by the remaining dealerships. Due to economies of scale, the remaining dealerships will reduce their days of supply. Second, as shown in Table 6, column 6, the presence of another GM dealership in a market increases a dealership’s service level. Hence, removing a dealership from a market is likely to decrease the remaining dealer’s service level, further decreasing that dealers’days of supply. We used the estimates of Table 6, column 6 to measure the e¤ect of closing some of GM’s dealerships. We selected markets with seven or fewer dealerships. The maximum number of GM dealerships in these markets is three. In the counterfactual, all but one of the dealerships, the one with highest sales volume, remains in the market. To obtain a lower bound, we assumed that all the sales of the dealerships closed are lost. This case considers inventory reductions only due to lower service level. To obtain an upper bound, we assumed that all the sales of the closed dealerships are captured by the remaining dealership. If the remaining dealership carries di¤erent brands, the sales are allocated proportionally to the actual sales of 19 each brand. The following table summarizes the results from the counterfactual experiment. No. dealers closed No. obs. Actual days of supply Reduction in days of supply lower bound upper bound 1 79 122.1 15.0 27.0 2 5 126.2 15.5 37.9 Total 84 122.3 15.7 29.1 Actual days-of-supply and the two bounds on its reduction are reported separately for markets in which one or two dealerships are closed. The improvement in inventory performance is substantial, between 15 and 29 days-of-supply on average. Interestingly, the service level e¤ect (measured by the lower bound) is similar in magnitude to the potential gains from economies of scale.38 7. Conclusion We develop an econometric model to estimate the e¤ect of market structure on inventory holdings. We identify two drivers of inventory holdings: a sales e¤ect and a service level e¤ect. We …nd that the sales e¤ect exhibits statistical economies of scale - increasing a dealer’s sales reduces the dealer’s inventory when measured in terms of days-of-supply (i.e., inventory increases with sales, but at a slower rate). Based on our estimates, Chevrolet could reduce its days-of-supply by 17% (a 12.3 decrease in days-of-supply) by matching Toyota in sales volume per dealership. Our analysis suggests that, due to unobserved market characteristics, this calculation may underestimate the inventory reduction due to economies of scale in sales. We are particularly interested in the impact of market structure (local competition) on service levels (bu¤er inventory held by dealerships conditional on sales). Some theoretical models predict that increased competition can lead to a decrease in service levels via a price competition e¤ect - entry reduces margins, thereby reducing underage costs and the incentives to hold inventory. Other models predict that entry can lead to higher service levels - …rms may increase their service level to attract demand (as in Cachon 2003) or they may increase their service level to better retain demand (i.e., to prevent customers from searching other retailers). Among dealerships in the automobile industry we …nd that competition increases service levels, i.e., any price competition e¤ect associated with entry is dominated by the demand attraction/retention e¤ects. This result di¤ers from the …ndings in Gaur et al. (2005) and Amihud and Mendelson (1989). Gaur et al. (2005) …nds that retailers with lower margins tend to carry less inventory. (Amihud and Mendelson (1989) has a similar 38 An increase in a dealership’s sales volume is also likely to reduce its batch sizes, generating additional improvements in inventory performance. Accounting for this reduction requires modeling the e¤ect of sales on batching. Given that our measure of batch size, CVQ, is noisy and its e¤ect is measured imprecisely, we ommited this e¤ect from the counterfactual analysis. 20 …nding but they study manufacturing …rms.) If low margins are taken as a proxy for higher competition, then they …nd that inventory decreases with competition. They do not study auto retailing, so it is possible that in other retail markets the price competition e¤ect of entry dominates the demand attraction/retention e¤ects. Further research is needed to reconcile these results. Competition increases inventory in the auto industry, but we …nd that the marginal e¤ect of competition is decreasing: the …rst entrant into a monopoly market causes a 17% increase in inventory whereas entry beyond the seventh dealership has no positive e¤ect on inventory (conditional on sales). We provide additional empirical evidence showing that the service level of products depends on the number of close substitutes o¤ered by rivals, but is insensitive to the number of disimilar products. Our results are robust to di¤erent econometric speci…cations. Our …ndings suggest that inventory may vary across automobile makes in part because auto makes vary in their dealership structures. As the dealership network becomes more dense there are two reinforcing e¤ects on inventory. One, if sales per dealership declines as the number of dealerships increases (which is plausible), then the presence of statistical economies of sales with respect to sales suggests that inventories will increase (measured in days-of-supply). Second, an increases in the density of dealerships increases competition among them (i.e., there will be more dealerships per market), which also increases inventory via higher service levels. Thus, when comparing two automobile makes, we expect (all else being equal) the one with the greater number of dealerships to carry more inventory. This conjecture is consistent with aggregrate data for U.S. inventory holdings of the major automobile manufacturers. For example, Toyota has approximately half as many dealerships as Chevrolet, and carries 42% less inventory (42 days of supply vs. 73 days of supply). (See Cachon and Olivares (2006) for other factors that explain di¤erences in aggregate inventory holdings.) Furthermore, in the markets that we study, reducing the number of GM dealerships reduces days-of-supply by at least 13% and by as much as 25%. In the automobile industry, due primarily to restrictive franchise laws, it is di¢ cult for an auto make to close dealerships. These restrictions therefore may force an auto make to operate with more dealerships than it desires. As a consequence, the auto make would carry more inventory than it would with a distribution network with fewer dealerships. However, it is not possible with our analysis to conclude whether these franchise laws are bad for consumer welfare - although they may lead to high inventory holding costs, they also provide consumers with potentially lower prices (due to price competition) and a greater selection of available products. Similarly, we are unable to conclude whether or not GM would bene…t from reducing its dealership network - we do predict that GM would carry less inventory, but this is only bene…cial if the impact on sales is su¢ ciently small.39 Thus, 39 Recently Ford attempted to consolidate dealerships in particular markets, such as Tulsa Oklahoma. They 21 an estimate of the impact of the dealership structure on sales is needed to obtain estimates of the impact of a dealership network on consumer and …rm welfare. These estimates are beyond the scope of this research, but worthwhile to pursue for future research. In addition to the number and location of dealerships, we found that inter-dealership transfers cause dealerships to lower their average inventory levels. Dealers may use transfers to help retain customers that are not entirely satis…ed with the dealer’s assortment, i.e., transfers help to retain a customer by allowing the dealer to …nd a vehicle that better matches the consumers’preferences. Alternatively, because dealers do not have full control over which vehicles they receive from the manufacturer, dealers may use transfers to adjust the mix of vehicles in their assortments. Additional research is needed to identify the particular motivations for vehicle transfers between dealers. Data Sources http://www.gmbuypower.com http://www.edmunds.com http://www.randmcnally.com U.S. Census Bureau (http://fact…nder.census.gov) Inter-University Consortium for Political and Social Sciences (ICPSR) Missouri Census Data Center (http://mcdc2.missouri.edu) Ward’s Auto Datacenter References Alexander, P. 1997. Product variety and market structure: A new measure and a simple test. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 32 207–214. Amihud, Y., H. Mendelson. 1989. Inventory behavior and market power. International Journal of Industrial Organization 7 269–280. Anupindi, R., Y. Bassok. 1992. Centralization of stocks: Retailers vs. manufacturer. Management Science 45(2) 178–188. Balachander, S., P.H. Farquhar. 1994. Gaining more by stocking less: A competitive analysis of product availablility. Marketing Science 13(1) 3–22. Bernstein, F., A. Federgruen. 2005. Descentralized supply chains with competing retailers under demand uncertainty. Management Science 51(1) 18–29. speculated that such a consolidation could lead to higher sales because customers a broader assortment of inventory would be available to customers at the consolidated dealership than at any of the previous smaller dealerships. This is plausible if consumer transportation/search costs are su¢ ciently low because the average consumer must travel farther to a single dealership than to one of several dealerships in a market. 22 Berry, S., J. Waldfogel. 2001. Do mergers increase product variety? Evidence from radio broadcasting. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 116(3) 1009–25. Bresnahan, T., P. Reiss. 1991. Entry and competition in concentrated markets. The Journal of Political Economy 99(5) 977–1099. Cachon, G. 2003. Supply chain coordination with contracts. Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science: Supply Chain Management, S. Graves and T. de Kok. 11:229-339. Cachon, G., M. Olivares. 2006. Drivers of …nished goods inventory performance in the U.S. automobile industry. Working paper, Wharton, University of Pennsylvania. Cachon, G., C. Terwiesch, Y. Xu. 2006. The impact of consumer search, …rm entry and competition on assortment and pricing. Working paper, University of Pennsylvania and University of Miami. Dana, J. 2001. Competition in price and availability when availability is unobservable. RAND Journal of Economics 32(3) 497–513. Dana, J., N. Petruzzi. 2001. Note: The newsvendor model with endogenous demand. Management Science 47(11) 1488–97. Daugherty, A., J. Reinganum. 1991. Endogenous availability in search equilibrium. Rand Journal of Economics 22(2) 287–306. Deneckre, R., J. Peck. 1995. Competition over price and service rate when demand is stochastic: A strategic analysis. RAND Journal of Economics 26(1) 148–162. Dranove, D., M. Shanley, C. Simon. 1992. Is hospital competition wasteful? RAND Journal of Economics 23(2) 247–262. Dudey, M. 1990. Competition by choice: The e¤ect of consumer search on …rm location decisions. American Economic Review 80(5) 1092–104. Eaton, C., R.G. Lipsey. 1982. An economic theory of central places. The Economic Journal 56–72. Gaur, V., M.L. Fisher, A. Raman. 2005. An econometric analysis of inventory turnover performance in retail services. Management Science 51(2) 181–194. Gerchak, Y., Y. Wang. 1994. Periodic-review inventory models with inventory-level dependent demand. Naval Research Logistics 41 99–116. Hayashi, F. 2000. Econometrics. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey. 23 Hendricks, K.B., V.R. Singhal. 2005. Association between supply chain glitches and operating performance. Management Science 51(5) 695–711. Holweg, M., F. Pil. 2004. The second century. MIT Press, 5 Cambridge Center, Cambridge, MA 02142. Lippman, S.A., K.F. McCardle. 1997. The competitive newsboy. Operations Research 45 54–65. Mahajan, S., G. van Ryzin. 2001. Inventory competition under dynamic consumer choice. Operations Research 49(5) 646–657. Marx, Thomas G. 1985. The development of the franchise distribution system in the U.S. automobile industry. The Business History Review 59 465–474. Narus, J.A., J.C. Anderson. 1996. Rethinking distribution. Harvard Business Review 112– 120. Netessine, S., N. Rudi. 2003. Centralized and competitive inventory models with demand substitution. Operations Research 51(2). Rechtin, M., M. Wilson. 2006. Thinning the herd. Automotive News 81 82–84. Roumiantsev, S., S. Netessine. 2006. What can be learned from classical inventory models: A cross-industry empirical investigation. Working paper, http://www.netessine.com. Rudi, N., S. Kapur, D.F. Pyke. 2001. A two-location inventory model with transshipment and local decision making. Management Science 47(12) 1668–80. Seim, K. 2006. An empirical model of …rm entry with endogenous product-type choices. (forthcoming) RAND Journal of Economics. Smith, R.L. 1982. Franchise regulation: An economic analysis of state restrictions on automobile distribution. Journal of Law and Economics 25(1) 125–157. Stahl, K. 1982. Di¤erentiated products, consumer search, and locational oligopoly. Journal of Industrial Economics 31 97–113. van Ryzin, G., Siddarth Mahajan. 1999. On the relationship between inventory costs and variety bene…ts in retail assortments. Management Science 45(11) 1496–1509. Watson, R. 2004. Product variety and competition in the retail market for eyeglasses. Working paper, University of Texas at Austin. 24 Watson, R. 2006. Search, availability, and competition in product ranges. Working paper, Department of Economics, University of Texas at Austin. Welch, D. 2006. The other club battering GM. Businessweek 3974(38). Wollinsky, A. 1983. Retail trade concentration due to consumers’ imperfect information. Bell Journal of Economics 14(14) 275–82. Wooldridge, Je¤rey. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts. Wu, O.Q., H. Chen, M.Z. Frank. 2005. What actually happened to the inventories of American companies between 1981 and 2000. Management Science 51(7) 1015–1031. Zipkin, P. 2000. Foundations of Inventory Management. McGraw-Hill. 25 Make Days of No. of supply dealers Chevrolet 73 4227 Ford 74 3939 Honda 48 1001 Toyota 42 1200 Averages during years 1999-2004 Sales per dealership 627 795 1077 1251 Table 1 – Comparison of inventory performance, number of dealerships and sales per dealership across four auto makes. Days-of-supply is calculated based on all finished vehicle inventory in the supply chain, including factory lots, ports of entry, in transit to dealerships and in the dealerships. Population (thousands) [100,150] [50,100] [25,50] <25 Distance to closest UA (miles) Pop>100 Pop>50 Pop>25 Pop>10 50 ---50 30 --50 50 30 -50 50 30 30 Table 2 – Market selection criteria. Criteria vary depending on the population of the UA, indicated in the first column. Columns two through five indicate the minimum distance (in miles) required to the closest UA with population above the threshold shown in the header. # of dealers 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 % of markets with dealers # of Median non-GM markets population domestic Japanese 2nd GM 17 24 43 29 21 22 14 21 9 13 9 3 6 1 1 3.91 6.20 9.76 13.05 26.16 36.48 38.37 62.63 68.22 61.47 78.50 100.32 122.00 105.36 122.98 0% 83% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 0% 8% 5% 55% 86% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 0% 8% 2% 41% 57% 41% 71% 95% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% 100% Table 3 – Summary statistics of the isolated markets. The last three columns show the percent of markets with at least one dealership of non-GM domestic manufacturers, Japanese manufacturers and a second GM dealership, respectively. Variable INCOME OLD BLACK PUBTRANS COLLEGE REPUBLICAN TURNOUT FARMING ARMY Mean 32.6 15.5 5.4 0.8 18.5 0.6 0.4 1.3 0.7 Std. Dev. 5.9 4.8 11.9 1.3 9.9 0.1 0.1 1.5 2.4 Min 19.7 4.7 0.0 0.0 1.5 0.3 0.1 0.0 0.0 Max 63.0 38.3 70.1 11.9 57.3 0.9 0.6 12.7 22.6 ANC H -0.21 -0.47 0.19 -0.28 0.07 0.21 -0.08 -0.06 0.04 0.04 Table 5 – Summary statistics and correlation matrix. CVQ 0.49 -0.19 -0.43 -0.57 0.06 N FR Std. Min Max Dev. 0.90 -0.24 5.14 0.98 0.00 5.74 2.63 1.00 10.00 0.55 0.05 6.50 1.29 1.00 5.00 0.47 0.42 3.04 0.08 0.00 0.50 RIVE T NDE Mean 2.84 2.92 5.55 0.88 3.19 1.26 0.06 GMD logS ALES 0.89 0.51 -0.12 -0.43 -0.51 -0.02 V logIN Variable logINV logSALES NDEALERS GMDRIVET NFRANCH CVQ TRANSF ALER S Table 4 – Summary statistics for the demographic variables in the selected markets. LOGSALES NC 1 OLS Linear 0.740*** (0.026) 0.026*** (0.009) 2 IV Linear 0.689*** (0.029) 0.077*** (0.015) -0.02 (0.032) -0.021 (0.014) 0.085** (0.043) -0.886*** (0.201) 0.001 (0.033) 0.011 (0.016) 0.085* (0.044) -0.914*** (0.206) NCSQ GMDRIVET NFRANCH CVQ TRANSF 3 OLS Square 0.728*** (0.025) 0.181*** (0.028) -0.013*** (0.002) -0.023 (0.031) -0.024* (0.014) 0.075* (0.042) -0.879*** (0.196) NC>=2 NC>=3 NC>=4 NC>=5 NC>=6 NC>=7 NC>=9 4 5 Comp IV Square Level 0.709*** 0.726*** (0.028) (0.025) 0.351*** (0.1) -0.028*** (0.01) -0.023 -0.019 (0.033) (0.032) -0.024 -0.024* (0.018) (0.014) 0.065 0.074* (0.044) (0.042) -0.875*** -0.889*** (0.202) (0.198) 0.170* (0.091) 0.109* (0.063) 0.099* (0.053) 0.017 (0.061) 0.073 (0.064) -0.014 (0.056) -0.104** (0.05) HASDOMESTIC HASJAPAN HASGM2 Observations R-squared 680 0.84 680 0.83 680 0.85 680 0.84 680 0.85 6 Comp Type 0.715*** (0.025) -0.025 (0.031) -0.002 (0.015) 0.072* (0.042) -0.863*** (0.197) 0.259*** (0.067) 0.113*** (0.04) 0.132*** (0.042) 680 0.85 Table 6 – Main estimation results. Demographic variables and dummies for make, region and ALLSTATE not shown (see Appendix for full estimation results). Column 2 uses TOTPOP and FRINGEPOP (in logs) to instrument for NC. Column (3) uses the same IVs plus POP50, POP70 and POP2K to instrument for NC and NCSQ. Standard errors shown in parenthesis. ***,** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. 1 SM car 0.5973*** (0.0275) 0.0070 (0.0057) LOGSALES N B(PRICE,SIZE) 2 SM car Sq. 0.5972*** (0.0274) 0.0360*** (0.0112) -0.0005*** (0.0002) -0.0080 (0.0076) -0.0119 (0.0079) NSQ B(PRICE,SIZE) N B(STD_CAR) -0.0005 (0.0072) -0.0112 (0.008) N B(ANY_CAR) N B(TRUCK) N B(OTHER) 0.0007 (0.0035) -0.4529* (0.2312) 818 0.62 PERTRANSF Observations R-squared -0.0015 (0.0036) -0.4654** (0.23) 818 0.62 3 Truck 0.8051*** (0.025) 0.0068 (0.0062) 4 Truck Sq. 0.8026*** (0.0249) 0.0399** (0.0157) -0.0009** (0.0004) -0.0029 (0.0044) -0.0017 (0.0051) -0.5975** (0.2578) 779 0.67 -0.0053 (0.0045) -0.0013 (0.0051) -0.6477** (0.258) 779 0.67 Table 7 – Estimation results with number of models as a measure of competition. Separate regressions were estimated for Small and Medium size cars (SM cars) and Light-trucks (Truck). N B(.) measures the number of models in each product band. Other controls include region and price dummies and demographics (not shown). Standard errors shown in parenthesis. ***,** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10%, respectively. Number of dealerships vs. population growth (1950-2004) 2.50 SD IA MI WI NE MT log GM/Japan Dealers 1.50 OH NY 0.50 -50% 0% 50% AK CO NJ 100% CA FL 150% NV AZ 200% 250% 300% -0.50 HI -1.50 log(1+Growth) Figure 1 – Scatter plot of the ratio of GM to Japanese dealerships versus population growth between 1950-2004. Each observation is a state and both axes are with logarithm transformation. Selected labels indicate US postal service state codes. Service level effect of competition on inventory (quadratic polinomial model) 100% Inventory increase (% above monopoly) 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 -20% # of dealerships Service level effect of competition on inventory (non-parametric model) Inventory increase (% above monopoly) 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 1 2 3 4 5 6 7-8 9-10 -20% # of dealerships Table 2 – Effect of competition on the targeted service level, measured as the percent change in inventory relative to a monopolist GM dealership. Top (bottom) figure shows the effect measured by the quadratic (non-parametric) model. + and – indicate upper and lower bounds on 95% confidence interval, respectively. Appendix The following Lemma and Proposition provides a formal proof of equation (2) and the properties of K (z) : Lemma 1 Let D is a normally distributed random variable with mean and standard deviation :De…ne Q = + z and S = min fQ; Dg : Then, the variance of S, V (S), is given by: V (S) = 2 f (z) (z) [z + (z)]g where (z) and respectively, and z. (z) are the density and distribution functions of the standard normal, (z) = (z) = (z) is the hazard rate. Furthermore, V (S) is increasing in Proof. We write the variance of sales V (S) as: V (S) = V (SjD Q) Pr (D = 0 + V (DjD < Q) Q) + V (SjD < Q) Pr (D < Q) (1) (z) De…ne W Q D; which is a normal r.v. with mean w = Q and variance V (W ) = 2 :Note that w = = z. By construction, the events fD < Qg and fW > 0g are equivalent. Using a result for the truncated normal distribution (see Olsen (1980)): V (DjD < Q) = V (W jW > 0) = 2 f1 + H (z) [ z H (z)]g where H ( ) = ( ) = ( ). Replacing this expression in 1 gives the formula for V (S). Taking derivatives of the term in brackets and doing some algebra gives: d dz (z) (z) z + (z) (z) = (z) (z + (z))2 which is positive. Proposition 2 In the periodic review base-stock inventory model with normally distributed demand D with mean , standard deviation ; and order-upto level Q, the expected inventory can be expressed as: I = s K (z) where s = V (S)1=2 and K (z) = (z (z) + (z)) f (z) Furthermore, K (z) is increasing in z: 1 (z) [z + (z)]g 1=2 : Proof. The loss function for the standard normal is given by L (z) = Combining this expression with the Lemma implies that K (z) = V (S)1=2 (z) z (1 (z)). (z + L (z)) Equation (1) implies I = s K (z) : Denote f1 = (z (z) + (z)) and f2 (z) = (z) (z) [z + (z)] : Note that f10 = (z) and that f2 (z) 0 (otherwise, V (S) could be negative). Taking derivatives of K (z) = 1=2 f1 (z) = [f2 (z)] we obtain: sign fK 0 (z)g = sign (z) f2 (z) = sign f2 (z) = sign which is positive given that f2 (z) (z) 1 0 f (z) f1 (z) 2 2 1 (z) (z + (z))3 2 (z) [z + (z)] 1 1 (z + (z))2 2 0: References Olsen, R. 1980. Approximating a truncated normal regression with the method of moments. Econometrica 48(5) 1099–1106. 2 APPENDIX 0 10 logINV 20 30 40 Scatter plot of aggregate inventory versus sales (by UA) 0 10 20 30 40 50 logSALES GM monopoly GM + other domestic + Japanese GM + other domestic Figure 3 – Scatter plot of log inventory (logINV) and log sales (logSALES) for three types of market: monopoly markets (circles), markets with GM and non-GM domestic dealers (squares) and markets with all types of dealers (GM, non-GM domestic and Japanese). Each observation is a market, and both measures are aggregated across dealerships in each market. LOGSALES NDEALERS OLS 0.740*** (0.026) 0.026*** (0.009) Beta 0.805 0.078 NDEALERSSQ GMDRIVET NFRANCH CVQ TRANSF ALLSTATE OLD BLACK PUBLICTRANS LOGINCOME COLLEGE REPUBLICAN TURNOUT ARMY FARMING MAKENAME==BUICK MAKENAME==CADILLAC MAKENAME==CHEVROLET MAKENAME==GMC MAKENAME==PONTIAC REGION==MW REGION==NE REGION==SO CONSTANT Observations R-squared -0.02 (0.032) -0.021 (0.014) 0.085** (0.043) -0.886*** (0.201) 0.131*** (0.038) -0.013*** (0.004) 0.001 (0.002) -0.007 (0.012) 0.155 (0.116) -0.001 (0.001) 0.074 (0.14) -0.26 (0.159) -0.004 (0.006) -0.009 (0.015) 0.226* (0.116) 0.227* (0.119) 0.483*** (0.11) 0.326*** (0.118) 0.234** (0.117) -0.221*** (0.041) -0.211** (0.085) -0.176*** (0.055) -0.961 (1.21) 680 0.84 -0.012 -0.03 0.045 -0.076 0.064 -0.063 0.015 -0.01 0.028 -0.014 0.009 -0.032 -0.013 -0.012 0.096 0.09 0.243 0.133 0.108 -0.121 -0.048 -0.09 -1.074 680 0.84 OLS Sq 0.728*** (0.025) 0.181*** (0.028) -0.013*** (0.002) -0.023 (0.031) -0.024* (0.014) 0.075* (0.042) -0.879*** (0.196) 0.132*** (0.037) -0.012*** (0.004) 0.002 (0.002) -0.006 (0.012) 0.220* (0.113) -0.001 (0.001) 0.123 (0.137) -0.261* (0.155) -0.008 (0.005) -0.009 (0.014) 0.177 (0.113) 0.156 (0.116) 0.445*** (0.108) 0.278** (0.115) 0.186 (0.114) -0.196*** (0.04) -0.183** (0.083) -0.127** (0.054) -1.943 (1.192) 680 0.85 Beta Sq 0.792 0.531 -0.465 -0.013 -0.035 0.04 -0.076 0.064 -0.06 0.029 -0.009 0.04 -0.013 0.016 -0.032 -0.025 -0.011 0.075 0.062 0.224 0.113 0.086 -0.107 -0.042 -0.065 -2.17 680 0.85 Table 10 – OLS estimates including all controls (intercept not shown). “Beta” column shows standardized coefficients. LOGUAPOP LOGFRINGEPOP LOGSALES GMDRIVET NFRANCH CVQ TRANSF ALLSTATE OLD BLACK PUBLICTRANS LOGINCOME COLLEGE REPUBLICAN TURNOUT ARMY FARMING MAKENAME==BUICK MAKENAME==CADILLAC MAKENAME==CHEVROLET MAKENAME==GMC MAKENAME==PONTIAC MAKENAME==SATURN REGION==MW REGION==NE REGION==SO REGION==WE CONSTANT Observations R-squared NDEALERS 1.616*** (0.089) 0.337*** (0.067) 0.206** (0.097) -0.071 (0.119) -0.467*** (0.048) -0.116 (0.155) 2.336*** (0.734) 0.084 (0.137) 0.033** (0.015) 0.033*** (0.006) -0.006 (0.045) 1.649*** (0.415) 0.017*** (0.005) -0.805 (0.508) -0.889 (0.591) -0.005 (0.02) -0.149*** (0.053) 0.044 (0.196) 0 (0) -0.758*** (0.204) 0.087 (0.185) 0.067 (0.172) -0.504 (0.43) -0.233 (0.15) -0.707** (0.311) -0.398** (0.201) 0 (0) -16.216*** (4.335) 679 0.76 Beta 0.607 0.103 0.076 -0.014 -0.228 -0.021 0.068 0.014 0.056 0.16 -0.003 0.103 0.063 -0.035 -0.037 -0.005 -0.063 0.006 0 -0.13 0.012 0.011 -0.026 -0.043 -0.055 -0.069 0 -6.167 679 0.76 Table 11 – Estimates from first step of IV regression. The dependent (endogenous) variable is NC. Excluded exogenous variables are TOTPOP, FRINGEPOP and COMMIN. (intercept not shown). “Beta” column shows standardized coefficients. Manufacturer GM Ford DC Toyota Nissan Honda Total Standard car Luxury car Sport/Cross Utility Veh. Van Pickup 56 38 25 26 16 14 15 9 6 9 5 3 8 10 2 5 2 4 20 14 12 9 6 5 6 2 3 1 1 1 7 3 2 2 2 1 Table 12 – Number of models offered by each manufacturer in model-year 2007. The total number of vehicles is decomposed into multiple model segments, based on the model segmentation of Ward’s Auto. Segment class size price Lower Luxury Luxury Specialty Luxury Sport Middle Luxury Upper Luxury Large Regular Lower Middle Lower Small Middle Specialty Small Specialty Upper Middle Upper Small Large Cross/Utility Vehicle Large Luxury Cross/Utility Vehicle Middle Cross/Utility Vehicle Middle Luxury Cross/Utility Vehicle Small Cross/Utility Vehicle Large Pickup Small Pickup Large Luxury Sport/Utility Vehicle Large Sport/Utility Vehicle Middle Luxury Sport/Utility Vehicle Middle Sport/Utility Vehicle Small Sport/Utility Vehicle Large Van Small Van luxury car luxury car luxury car luxury car luxury car standard car standard car standard car standard car standard car standard car standard car CUV CUV CUV CUV CUV pickup pickup SUV SUV SUV SUV SUV van van large middle small large large large middle small middle small middle small large large middle middle small large small large large middle middle small large small lower specialty specialty middle upper upper lower lower specialty specialty upper upper std luxury std luxury std std std luxury std luxury std std std std Table 13 – Model segmentation (Source: Ward’s Auto). no. of models 17 5 14 11 6 10 6 7 9 6 16 20 7 6 20 12 7 9 11 8 9 5 16 1 4 12