CHINHUI JUHN Universityof Houston KEVIN M. MURPHY Universityof Chicago ROBERT H. TOPEL Universityof Chicago CurrentUnemployment, Historically Contemplated our BrookingsPaper"WhyHas the NaturalRate of UnemploymentIncreasedover Time?" analyzed long-termchanges in joblessness among Americanmen.' We documentedthe dramaticrise between 1967 and 1989 in both unemploymentand nonparticipationin the laborforce amongprime-agedmales. Ourmainconclusionwas thata steep and sustaineddecline in the demandfor low-skilled workershad reducedthe returnsto workfor this group,leadingto high ratesof unemployment,laborforce withdrawal,andlong spells of joblessnessfor lessskilled men. We found that time spent out of the labor force and time spentunemployedaccountedin roughlyequalmeasurefor the long-term growthin joblessness.We concludedthatstructuralfactors,primarilythe declinein the demandfor low-skilledlabor,haddramaticallychangedthe prospectsfor a returnto low ratesof joblessnessany time soon. After thatpaperwas published,things appearedto change.The 1990s openedwith a brief recessionthatwas followed by the longest sustained decline in unemploymentin modernU.S. history. By the end of that expansion,the unemploymentratehad reachedits lowest level since the late 1960s, falling below 4 percentfor the first time since 1969. Some macroeconomistsarguedthatthe so-callednaturalrateof unemployment ELEVEN YEARS AGO, We thank the Brookings Panel participants for helpful comments. Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the National Bureau of Economic Research Labor Studies meeting and at the University of Missouri. We acknowledge financial support from the Center for the Study of the Economy and the State and the Milken Foundation. 1. Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991). 79 80 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 had permanentlyshiftedto 5 percentor below.2Because we had emphasized changesin the structureof labordemandthathad made a returnto low ratesof joblessnessunlikely,these facts presenteda challengeto our 1991 framework.Maybe we were just wrong-maybe the demandand supplyframeworkof ourpreviousworkis inconsistentwith ratesof joblessness in the post-1990 period. If so, we would join a distinguished groupof social scientistswho have drawnattentionto a significantempirical phenomenononly to watchthatphenomenondisappearimmediately As it turnsout, however,the frameworkthatwe developedfor thereafter.3 thinkingaboutpre-1990 patternsof joblessness also does fairly well in jobless time in the post-1990period. helpingto understand In this paper we look in some detail at employmentdata from the 1990s, revisitingissues raisedin ourearlierwork.Specifically,we ask: -Have the trendswe identifiedin ourearlierpaper-the concentration of nonemploymentamongthe less skilled,the growthof nonparticipation in the labor force, and the increased durationof joblessness-been reversedwith the fall in aggregateunemployment? -Did the expansionof the 1990s reallyreturnthe U.S. labormarketto conditionsof the late 1960s, as unemploymentstatisticsseem to indicate? -Does the economicframeworkof supplyand demandwe utilizeda decadeago still help in understandinglong-termdevelopmentsin unemployment,nonemployment,andlaborforce participation? Ouranswersare surprising.First,the basic trendstowardlongerspells of joblessness and rising nonemploymenthave continuedin spite of the prolongedexpansionof nationaloutputandthe concomitantfall in unemployment rates. Long jobless spells and labor force withdrawalwere more importantin the 1990s thanever before. Second, the fall in unemploymentto levels close to historicallows is very misleading.Broader 2. See, for example, Stiglitz (1997), Gordon (1998), and Staiger, Stock, and Watson (2001). 3. Malthus founded the club. His theory that the forces of endogenous population growth doomed the common people to perpetual poverty "explained" why incomes had failed to increase over the period his data covered. Publication of Malthus's theory was followed by two centuries of almost continuous progress. More recently, when the returns to a college education were at a record low in 1979, Richard Freeman (1976) offered a supplybased theory in The Overeducated American, only to see returns to a college education increase steadily over the next fifteen years, reaching a record high. To Freeman's credit, his model did predict a rebound, although not so large and sustained as the one that actually occurred. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 81 measuresof joblessness show thatthe labormarketof the late 1990s was morelike the relativelyslack labormarketof the late 1980s thanlike the boominglabormarketof the late 1960s. Finally,the basic forces of supply and demand identified in our previous paper continue to have explanatorypower.The theorydoes a reasonablygood job of explaining those trendsthathave continued,as well as those thathave changed. Recentdataalso provideconsiderableinsightinto what has happened in the labormarketover the past decade.Overthe 1990s, even as unemploymentwas falling,time spentout of the laborforce was rising.In fact, the increasein time spent out of the labor force was so large that total joblessness-which combinesthe unemployedwith those who have withdrawnfrom the labor force-was as high at the business-cyclepeak in 2000 as it hadbeen at the previouscyclical peakof 1989, even thoughthe unemploymentrate was roughly2 percentagepoints lower. In terms of totaljoblessness, the often-praisedboom of the 1990s really represented little in the way of employmentprogressfor Americanmales. Althoughthe growthin the amountof time Americanmales spendout of the labor force continuesa trendfound in our earlierresearch,other featuresof the datachangedin the 1990s. The real wages of less-skilled men, which had been falling steadilysince the early 1970s, stabilizedin the 1990s andeven reboundedslightlyin the secondhalf of the decade.It appearsthatthe thirty-yeartrendtowardgreaterwage inequalityhas run its course,at least at the bottomof the wage distribution.The dataon joblessness reflect the impact of the changingwage trends.The long-term divergencein employmentrates between low-wage workersand those with higherwages, so pronouncedin our earlierwork, has stopped,and unemploymentand wage gaps across skill groups have narrowed.The congruencebetween patternsof change in wages and in employment comportswith our previous work, which stresseddemand-drivenwage changes as the dominantfactor driving secularchanges in employment rates. We are not the first to study the decline in unemploymentin the 1990s. Othershave emphasizedchangesin the compositionof the labor force as a source of this decline. RobertShimerfound that aging of the laborforce is importantin explainingthe decline in unemployment,particularly compared with the late 1970s.4 Lawrence Katz and Alan 4. Shimer (1998). 82 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 Kruegerinvestigatedto what extent the withdrawalof the incarcerated populationfromthe laborforce, amongotherfactors,has led to a dropin the aggregateunemploymentrate.'Otherpapershave exploredthe role of improvementsin job searchtechnology.Forexample,DavidAutorargues that temporaryhelp agencies may have helped improve the efficiency with whichjob seekersarematchedwithemployers,thusbringingabouta The arrivalof the Internetmay have declinein frictionalunemployment.6 also reducedsearchcosts, althoughits impactis less certain.7 We show in this paperthata sharpdecline in the incidenceof jobless spells accountsfor the lowerunemploymentratesof the 1990s,butthatat the same time durationsof spells have remainedhigh. This fact is inconsistentwith a theorybuilt on decliningsearchcosts, which would imply shorterunemploymentspells. A relatedline of researchcomparesthe divergencein employmentoutcomes betweenthe UnitedStatesandEurope.Althoughboththe U.S. and the EU economies may have experienced similar patterns of labor demandduringthe 1970s and the 1980s, it is widely believed thatmoreflexiblelabormarketsandwages keptAmericanunemploymentratesrelatively low, while Europeanratesrose. Along these lines, severalpapers emphasizethe importanceof interactionsbetweenmacroeconomicshocks and labor marketinstitutions.8These papers find that althoughneither macroeconomicvariables(oil prices, real interestrates,total factorproductivity,the laborshareof income)norlabormarketinstitutionvariables (unemploymentbenefitsandduration,unioncoverage,collectivebargaining, employmentprotectionpolicies) alone can explain the differences betweenthe UnitedStatesandEurope,a modelthatallows for interaction effects fits the data well. But this shocks-plus-institutions frameworkis less successful in understandingrecentchanges in U.S. unemployment. For example, Giuseppe Bertola, FrancineBlau, and Lawrence Kahn 5. Katz and Krueger (1999). They conclude that up to 0.4 percentage point of the rise in the male employment-to-population ratio from 1985 to 1998 could be due to the bias from ignoring the institutionalized population. For the sample of prime-aged males we study here, the bias could be larger, further underscoring our finding that labor market conditions did not improve much for prime-aged males in the 1990s. 6. Autor (2000a). 7. Autor (2000b); Kuhn and Skuterud (2000). 8. Bertola and Inchino (1995); Blanchard and Wolfers (2000); Ljungqvist and Sargent (1998); Bertola, Blau, and Kahn (2001). ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 83 reportedthat the model significantlyunderpredictsthe decline in U.S. unemploymentin the late 1990s.9 We revisit the evolution of joblessness in the United States, using thirty-fouryears (1967-2000) of microdatafrom the CurrentPopulation Surveys(CPS) conductedby the Bureauof the Censusandthe Bureauof LaborStatistics.Ourmainconclusionsarethe following: -Falling unemploymentrates over the 1990s greatlyexaggeratethe improvementin labormarketconditionsfor prime-agedmales. Rates of overalljoblessness-which includetime out of the laborforce-remained roughlythe samein the late 1990s as they hadbeen in the late 1980s,even as unemploymentrates fell. Rising labor force nonparticipationamong prime-aged men largely offset declining unemployment,so that the employment-to-population ratioheld constant. -Trends towardlongerdurationsof both unemploymentand nonemployment continuedin the 1990s, in spite of declining unemployment rates.The probabilityof enteringunemployment(or nonemployment)fell dramaticallyduringthe 1990s. The decline in the incidence of jobless spells was so large that the likelihood of experiencingone reachedits lowest level in the thirty-fouryearscoveredby ourdata.But therewas no decline in the duration of unemploymentspells-these were about 2.8 weeks longerin 1999-2000 thanthey hadbeen a decadeearlier-and the durationof nonemploymentspells increasedby over fourmonthsduring the 1990s. Broadlyspeaking,all of the long-termgrowthin joblessness is the productof longerdurationsof jobless spells. -Although nonemploymentcontinuesto be concentratedamonglessskilled men, the trendtowardrisingjoblessness among the least skilled reversedcourse somewhatin the 1990s. The largest declines in unemploymentoccurredamongmen in the lowest skill categories.Unemploymentamongmen in the bottom10 percentof the wage distributionfell by 4.6 percentage points between the cyclical peaks of 1989-90 and 1999-2000, while the declinein unemploymentat the medianof the wage distributionwas about 1 percentagepoint. In contrast,over the longer term the growth in nonemploymentis heavily weighted toward lessskilled men. Among men at the bottomof the wage distribution,the nonemploymentrate increasedby 13.5 percentagepoints between the late 9. Bertola, Blau, and Kahn (2001). 84 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 1960s and 2000, but by less than 1 percentagepoint for men with wages abovethe medianof the distribution. -The long-termdeclinein the real wages of less-skilledmen stopped in the early 1990s and actuallyreverseditself slightlyin the latterpartof the decade.Althoughthe wages of highly skilled men grew most rapidly of all duringthe 1990s-continuing past patternsof relative growthinequalitybetweenmen at the bottomof the wage distributionandmen at the mediancontractedslightlyover the decade.Overall,the trendtoward greaterwage inequalityappearsto have stoppedfor males in the bottom half of the wage distribution. -Joblessness among less-skilled men has shown up increasinglyas time spent out of the laborforce ratherthan as time spent unemployed. Consistentwith our earlier work, we believe that this continuedtrend towardlaborforce withdrawalreflectstwo factors:relativelylow returns to work(realwages for the least skilledremainsubstantiallylowerthanin the past) and increasinglyattractivenonworkopportunities,such as collecting disabilitypayments,which have shifted labor supply among the least skilled.We findthatmorethan40 percentof the growthin nonparticipationis associated with an increase in men claiming to be ill or disabled. -Despite rising wages and rates of labor force participationfor women,the highrateof joblessnessamongless-skilledmenis not the outcome of improvedlabor marketopportunitiesfor their workingwives. Nonemploymentratesandratesof laborforce withdrawalincreasedmost amongmen who did not have a workingwife. Looking acrossthe male wage distribution,the proportionof men with a workingwife actuallyfell amonglow-skilledmen, whose wages andemploymentrateswerefalling, androse amongmen in the top 40 percentof the wage distribution,where wages rose and employmentrates were stable. We conclude that longtermchangesin joblessnesshave been the resultof adverseshifts in labor demand, perhaps coupled with policy-driven shifts in labor supply, amonglow-skilledmen. Data Our data are drawnfrom the 1968-2001 AnnualDemographicFiles that supplementthe MarchCPS. The CPS collects informationmonthly ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 85 from a rotating,randomsample of approximately50,000 U.S. households. It forms the basis for publishedgovernmentstatisticson earnings, employment,unemployment,and laborforce participation,amongother measures.Whereaspublishedlabor marketstatistics rely on questions abouteach surveyrespondent'semploymentstatusin the referenceweek of the survey(usuallythe thirdweek of the month),we studyretrospective information,collected each March,on labormarketoutcomesin the previous calendaryear. Hence our data cover the thirty-fourcalendar yearsfrom 1967 through2000. In additionto personaland householdcharacteristicsfor each respondent, the retrospectivedata in the March survey recordthe numberof weeks duringthe previousyear that the respondentworked,was unemployed, andwas out of the laborforce, as well as the respondent'snumber of unemploymentspells. We measuretime spentunemployed(U) as the percentageof the year spentin thatstate(for example,for the ith individual, Uiis the numberof weeks unemployeddividedby 52); time spentout of the laborforce (0) andtime spentnonemployed(N = U + 0) aremeasuredin analogousfashion.This differsfromthe usualmethodof measuring time in unemployment,whichdividesweeks unemployedby weeks in the labor force. Our method better summarizesthe allocation of time across the three states, and it naturallyaggregatesacross individuals.'0 Using methodsdescribedbelow, we use informationon weeks worked, unemployed,andout of the laborforce to calculateboththe incidenceand the durationof jobless spells. The survey also records a respondent'sannual earnings and usual weekly hours workedfrom all jobs as well as occupation,industry,and othercharacteristicsfor the longestjob held duringthe previousyear.We use the informationon earnings,weeks worked,andhoursworkedto calculate averagehourlywages and to assign individualsa percentileposition in the overallwage distribution,as describedbelow. This allows us to trackchangesin employmentoutcomes(U, 0, andN) for personsin differentpartsof the wage distribution. We focus ouranalysison malesbecausethey were the focus of ourearlier work and because labor force participationissues for women are significantlymore complex. To avoid issues associatedwith early retire10. Since the denominator for Ui, Ni, and Oi is always 52, the corresponding jobless rate is simply the sample average of weeks in the state divided by 52. 86 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 ment, Social Security,and pensions,we focus on men who have one to thirtyyears of potentiallabormarketexperience.For high school graduates this cutoffyields men who areroughlynineteento forty-nineyearsof age, with correspondinglyhigher age intervals for those with more schooling.We defineyears of labormarketexperienceas the smallerof two numbers:age minusyears of educationminus seven, and age minus seventeen."In addition,in orderto avoidmeasurementproblemsfor men who spentpartof the year in school or in the military,we exclude those who reportthat they did not work partof the year because of school or militaryservice. The employmentmeasureswe study are based on CPS respondents' weeks worked, weeks unemployed,weeks out of the labor force, and numberof unemploymentspells duringthe previousyear, as reportedin the surveyweek. Using these data,we are able to identifythe fractionof respondentswho experiencedsome unemploymentor time out of the laborforce duringthe year, as well as the numberwho workedno weeks duringthe year.We referto the latterevent as full-yearnonemployment. Imputing Wagesfor Nonparticipants and Other Adjustments We constructtwo samplesfor analysis. The "wage sample"contains non-self-employedmen for whom valid observationsare available on annualearnings,weeks worked,andusualweekly hours.'2Formen in the wage sample,we calculatean hourlywage as the ratioof annualearnings to the productof weeks workedand usual weekly hours.The "employment sample"includesthe entirewage sampleplus those men who lack valid wage databecausethey did not work.For men not includedin the wage sample,we imputea statisticaldistributionof wages basedon education,experience,andweeks worked.Foreach individualwith recorded earnings,weeks, and hourswe projectthe log hourlywage on a quartic function in potentialexperience,and we assign each individuala per11. We use age minus education minus seven rather the standard measure, age minus education minus six, because age is measured at the survey week and we wish to measure potential experience at the time of our wage and employment measures (which is the year before the survey). 12. For the early years (before the 1976 survey) we impute usual weekly hours from hours worked in the last week and individual characteristics, and we impute weeks worked and unemployed from the categorical data based on averages calculated for the 1976-80 period. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 87 centile rankbased on his positionin the distributionof the residuals.For personswith zero weeks workedin the previouscalendaryear,we impute a wage distributionbasedon the observeddistributionof wages for those who workedfrom one to thirteenweeks in that year.'3The imputation assigns ten probabilityweights-each correspondingto the probability that the individual'swage would come from a given decile of the wage distribution-along with a meanwage for each decile. Our 1991 papersoughtto explainchangesin jobless time by changes in wages across skill categories. As we showed then, the relationship betweencalculatedwages andtime workedduringa yearis contaminated by measurementerrorin the latter,andthe relativeimportanceof this type of measurementerrordeclines with the numberof weeks workedin the previouscalendaryear.'4This builds in a negative relationshipbetween labor supply (weeks worked)and calculatedwages, particularlyamong men with high calculatedwages. As in our 1991 paper,we use data on hourlywages for Marchrespondentswho were also in the outgoingrotation groupsto calculatethe wage adjustmentsthat would equatethe distributionsof calculatedretrospectivewages from the previous calendar year and reportedhourly wages from the survey week. We then apply these adjustmentsto each percentileof the wage distribution.The procedure effectively compresses the wage distributionin each year by an amountthatwe attributeto measurementerrorin calculatedwages. Armed with calculatedwages for those in the wage sample and an imputedwage distributionfor those withoutvalid wage data, we group individualsinto five "skill"categoriesbasedon theirpositionsin the wage distribution.The percentileintervalsare 1-10, 11-20, 21-40, 41-60, and 61-100. As describedabove, each individual'swage percentileis calculatedbasedon his wages relativeto those of men with the samelevel of experiencein a given year.Individualsin the wage sampleareassignedto one of the five categoriesbased on theiractualwage, whereasthose with 13. Men with zero weeks worked resemble those with one to thirteen weeks worked in terms of years of schooling completed and in terms of living arrangements (living alone, with a spouse, or with other family). We also matched the outgoing rotation groups to the March survey, yielding data on current (March) hourly wages for those who worked during the survey week. Among individuals with zero weeks worked in the previous year but who worked in the survey week, average log wages are nearly identical to those of men who worked one to thirteen weeks in the previous year. See Juhn, Murphy, and Topel (1991) for further details. 14. See Juhn (1992) for a more complete description. BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 88 imputed wages are assigned probabilities of being in each of the categories. Changes in Wages, 1967-2000 In light of the prominencewe assigned to wage changes in our 1991 paper,it is worthwhileto review what has happenedto both wage levels and the distributionof wages since then. Figure 1 and table 1 summarize the mainfeaturesof the data.Figure 1 shows trendsin real hourlywages by wage percentilegroup(skill category)since 1967;the dataareindexed to equal 100 in 1970. Forourpurposesthe most interestingaspectof these datais thatwage inequalitystoppedincreasingin the 1990s, especiallyat the lower end of the wage distribution,andthatthe real wages of all skill categories increased after 1993. For less-skilled workers, real wage growthin the 1990s representeda slight reversalof a twenty-yeardecline in the returnsto work,whichhadfallenby nearly30 log pointsafter1972. Figure 1. Real Wages, by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000a Index,1970= 100 115 110 to 1 1050 -61 100 - ' - ''''" 95 90 85 I to 40 80 75 II to20 to I 1970 I I 1975 1980 ~ ~ ~~~~~~~~I 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on annualMarchCurrentPopulationSurvey (CPS) data. a. Reportedhourly wage (in naturallogarithms)is projectedon a quarticfunction in potentialexperience. Men are assigned a percentile category based on their position in the residual distribution.Wages for nonworkersand self-employed workers are imputed. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 89 Table 1. Changes in Real Wages, by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000a Percent Wagepercentilegroup Period Ito10 11to20 21 to 40 41 to 60 61 to 100 1967-69 to 1988-89 1988-89 to 1994-95 1994-95 to 1999-2000 -24.8 -3.9 6.1 -19.9 -7.1 6.7 -12.7 -8.3 6.8 -4.0 -7.6 6.4 5.5 -3.6 10.7 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1967-69 to 1999-2000 2.2 -18.7 -0.4 -13.2 -1.5 -5.9 -1.2 2.4 7.1 16.2 Source: Authors' calculations using annualMarchCurrentPopulationSurvey (CPS) data. a. Reportedhourly wage (in naturallogarithms)is projectedon a quarticfunction in potentialexperience. Men are assigned a percentile category based on their position in the residual distribution.Wages for nonworkersand self-employed workers are imputed. Even so, average wages of the least-skilled men were roughly 20 percent lower in 2000 than in the late 1960s (table 1), whereas those of men in the top 40 percent of the distribution increased by a roughly equivalent amount. As we showed in our 1991 Brookings Paper, wage declines were most prominent among those whose employment outcomes are most sensitive to wage changes-the least skilled-whereas rising wages are concentrated among those with less elastic labor supply. With this evidence as background, we turn to evidence on changes in joblessness, both in the aggregate and across the wage percentile groups defined above. We return to the implications of wage changes in the concluding section. Unemployment, Nonparticipation, and Nonemployment We begin by describing trends in unemployment and comparing our March CPS-based data with unemployment statistics from the monthly CPS published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Figure 2 shows that by 2000 the unemployment rate had reached its lowest level in thirty years, and unemployment rates in 1999-2000 were close to the extremely low rates seen during the late 1960s.15This is the culmination of a long downward trend in unemployment: in both the 1991-92 and the 2001-02 recessions (not shown), the peak unemployment rate was lower than the peak in the preceding recession, reversing a trend of rising peaks across the 15. The publishedratehas been adjusteddownwardby 0.86 percentagepointto equate the meansof the monthlyandthe Marchseriesover the sample. BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 90 Figure 2. AlternativeMeasuresof the UnemploymentRate, 1967-2000 Percent 10 Monthlysurveyb Marc surve' 9 8 1111 7 6 5I- March ~ surveyvr h~smpe Mrc 4/ 3 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on Bureauof LaborStatisticsand MarchCPS data. a. Subsetincludingonly prime-agemales; calculatedas the numberof weeks unemployeddivided by 52. b. Each observationfrom the monthly survey is reducedby 0.86 percentagepoint to equate the means of the monthly and the Marchsurveys over the sample. It appearsfrom the figure 1970-71, 1974-75, and 1982-83 recessions.m16 thatthe U.S. economyhas come full circle:unemploymentrose for fifteen years (from 1968 to 1983) and then fell over the next seventeenyears (from 1983 to 2000), with interveningcyclical swings. One might conclude from these data that the labormarketconditionsof the late 1960s andlate 1990s were comparable. Figure 2 also shows annualunemploymentrates for our sample of prime-agedmales (calculatedfrom the MarchCPS dataas weeks unemployed divided by weeks in the labor force). Although the two series shouldnot be identicalbecauseof differencesin the underlyingpopulations (oursampleconsists only of prime-agedmales, whereasthe overall unemploymentdata are from the full populationof labor force participants aged sixteen and over), the two series are remarkablysimilarin terms of underlyingtrendsand rankingsof cyclical variationsin unem16. The recession of 1980 did not fit this pattern, but as the figure shows, it did not represent much of a peak in terms of unemployment rates. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 91 ployment.One would reachthe same basic conclusionsaboutunemployment trendsfrom the publishedmonthlyseries as from our calculations based on the MarchCPS data.Fromhere forwardwe analyzethe March CPS dataexclusively. A majorfinding of our 1991 paperwas that the long-termgrowthin unemploymentgreatlyunderstatedthe growthin joblessness.Recentdata suggest thatchangesin unemploymentshown in the aggregateand in the CPS statisticsare even more misleadingfor the 1990s. This is illustrated in figure 3, which plots two series: the fractionof annualweeks spent unemployedandthe fractionof annualweeks spentout of the laborforce. The nonemploymentrate is the sum of these fractions,so that the combined height of the two shadedregions representsthe proportionof the year spent out of work. Figure 3 confirmsthat measuredunemployment fell duringthe 1990s to levels comparableto those in the 1960s, but the conclusion in terms of overall jobless time is much different:the late 1990s were much like the 1980s, in that the decline in unemployment Figure 3. Unemployment,Nonparticipation,and Nonemployment,1967-2000 Percentof calendaryeara 16 - Nonemploymentb 1412 10 - 4 1970 1975 1980 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Numberof weeks a year in indicatedstate divided by 52. b. Unemploymentplus nonparticipation. 1985 1990 1995 92 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 over the 1990s is not reflectedin a lower overallrateof joblessness.This means that, on net, men who left unemploymentdid not find jobs but ratherleft the laborforce, so thatthe employment-to-population ratiowas unchangedfromits level in the 1980s. Table 2 summarizesthe data in figure 3 by aggregatingthe data into nine time intervalscorrespondingroughly to peaks and troughsin the business cycle, as measuredby aggregateunemploymentrates. Unemploymentshows a strongcyclical patternas well as a long-runupward trend(whethermeasuredpeakto peakor troughto trough)untilthe recession of 1982-83. After 1982-83 unemploymentratesfall or stay constant (again whethermeasuredpeak to peak or troughto trough).In contrast, the fractionof the year spent out of the laborforce rises betweenevery pairof intervals.In fact, whereasthe unemploymentratein 1999-2000 is very close to its level in 1967-69, the nonemploymentrateis 4.7 percentage pointshigher,andthe fractionof the year spentout of the laborforce is roughlydoublewhatit was in 1967-69. It is difficultto concludefrom these datathatemploymentconditionsof the late 1960s andthe late 1990s were "similar"in any meaningfulsense. Consider next the eleven-year interval between the business-cycle peaks of 1988-89 and 1999-2000. Over this peak-to-peaktime spanthe unemploymentratefell by 1.3 percentagepoints-from 4.3 percentto 3.0 percent-but the percentageof men who were out of the laborforce rose by exactly the same amount,from 6.7 percentto 8 percent.This left the nonemploymentrateat the same level (11.0 percent)in 1999-2000 as in 1988-89, even thoughthis period spans the longest sustainedeconomic expansion,andthe largestdeclinein unemployment,on record. We next divide the growthin nonemploymentalong a second dimension. The percentageof weeks spent out of work is equal to the sum of two components:the fractionof men who did not workat all overthe year (for whomthe fractionof weeks spentout of workis 100 percent)andthe fractionof weeks spentout of workfor those who workedsome positive amount(multipliedby the fractionof menwho workedat leastone week). In what follows we refer to these two componentsas "full-yearnonemployment"and "part-yearnonemployment," respectively.This decompositionallows us to examinehow muchof the growthin nonemploymentis accountedfor by men with very long stretchesof joblessness-that is, spells thatareso long thatmendo not workat all duringa calendaryearandhow muchis due to men with "transitory" jobless spells. b. a. Source: Period 1972-73 1988-89 1982-83 1991-92 1978-79 1975-76 1971-72 1967-69 Number 1999-2000 of Unemployed Authors' weeks plus in Units Table as 2. indicated calculations indicated Peak Peak Peak Peak Peakbusiness Phase based Trough Trough Trough Trough nonparticipating; of status on Unemployment, cycle detailsMarch divided may by CPS not52. data. sum 3.06.34.39.04.36.93.84.52.2 to Nonparticipation, Labor Unemployed totals and force because of status rounding. 8.07.56.76.35.95.65.04.94.1 (percent Nonemployment of Nonparticipating during calendar 13.811.0 15.2 11.0 10.212.4 8.89.46.3 yeara) Nonemployedb Business-Cycle Peaks and -3.32.0-4.74.6-2.53.0-0.72.3 (percentage Change in unemployment Troughs, points) 1967-2000 0.50.80.50.40.30.60.10.8 (percentage Change in nonparticipation points) 94 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 The results,shownin table 3 and figure4, are striking.The amountof joblessness accountedfor by those workingat least partof the year was only slightly higherin 1999-2000 than in 1967-69 (4.9 versus 4.5 percent). But the amountof joblessness accountedfor by those who did not workat all over the yearmorethantripled,from 1.8 percentin the 1960s to 6.1 percentin 1999-2000. Moreover,whereaspart-yearnonemployment declined by 4.5 percentagepoints from its recessionarypeak in 1982-83 to 1999-2000, full-yearnonemploymentincreasedslightly.This is particularlystrikinggiven that the interveningperiodis characterized by two of the longesteconomicexpansionson record. Whatexplainsthis trendtowardlong-termjoblessness?Onepossibility is that those men with the least favorablelabor marketprospectshave simplydroppedout of the labormarket:the so-calleddiscouragedworker effect. Figure5 addressesthis possibilityby disaggregatingnonemployment and nonparticipation, respectively,by reportedreason.We distinthree main guish among groups:those who reportedthat they could not findwork,those who reportedthatthey wereill or disabled,anda residual categorywe label "other."Overthe periodcoveredby ourdata,the figure shows only a small increasein the proportionof men who reportedthat theycouldnot findwork.Risingsharesof the "ill or disabled"and"other" categoriesaccountfor the largest changes of both nonemploymentand The largerimpactof the "ill or disabled"categoryis on nonparticipation. Table 3. Part-Yearand Full-Year Nonemployment,1967-2000a Percentof calendaryear Period 1967-69 1971-72 1972-73 1975-76 1978-79 1982-83 1988-89 1991-92 1999-2000 Phase of business cycle Part-yearb Full-yearc Total Peak Trough Peak Trough Peak Trough Peak Trough Peak 4.5 6.5 6.0 8.4 6.8 9.4 6.5 7.7 4.9 1.8 2.9 2.8 4.1 3.8 5.8 4.6 6.0 6.1 6.3 9.4 8.8 12.4 10.2 15.2 11.0 13.8 11.0 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Details may not sum to totals because of rounding. b. Fractionof males nonemployed for part of the year multiplied by the average percent of the calendaryear spent nonemployed for this group. c. Fraction of males nonemployed for the entire year multiplied by the percent of the calendar year spent nonemployed (100 percent). ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 95 Figure 4. Part-Yearand Full-YearNonemployment,1967-2000 Percentof calendaryear 16 j2i~~~~~~~~~Total 141412 10 8- 6 2 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Fractionof males nonemployedfor partof the year multipliedby the averagepercentof the calendaryear spent nonemployed for this group. b. Fractionof males nonemployedfor the entire year multiplied by the percent of the calendaryear spent nonemployed (100 percent). the nonparticipation rate (middle panel of figure 5): men in this category account for about 42 percent (0.8 out of 1.9 percentage points) of the increase in nonparticipation between 1982-83 and 1999-2000. The rest is "other."The bottom panel of figure 5 narrows the focus to men who were full-year nonworkers, for whom the effect of rising disability is more prominentstill. Virtuallynone of the long-termincreasein full-yearjoblessness is accounted for by discouraged workers: the "other" category and persons reportingjoblessness for health reasons account for the secu- lar increase. A largeliteratureexaminesthe impactof changesin the disabilitybenefits programon the labormarketparticipationof male workers.17These papersdocumenta substantialgrowthin the disabilityrolls in the early 17. Parsons(1980); Bound (1989); Bound and Waidmann(1992); Autorand Duggan (forthcoming). Figure 5. Nonemploymentand Nonparticipation,by ReportedReason, 1967-200a Percentof calendaryearNonemployment 16 14 12 - 10 8 Ill or disabled 6 Nonparticipatiaoknvaiabl 9 87 6 5 4 Ill or disabled 3 2 91 Full-year nonemployment 9 8 7 65 43 Ill or disabled 2 1970 1975 18 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPSdata. a. Excludes individualswho reportbeing studentsor retired. 195 1990 1995 ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 97 1970s, linked to the sharpdecline in participationamong older males. Becauserealwages were risingfor the most partover this period,the earlierepisodeis consistentwitha reductionin laborsupplyin responseto the improvingnonmarketalternativerepresentedby disabilitypayments.Durchangestighting the early 1980s,however,legislativeandadministrative led to in new these standards reductions tighter standards; ened eligibility awardsandterminatedbenefitsfor a substantialfractionof beneficiaries. After 1984, eligibility criteriawere substantiallyliberalized,and this led to increasedreceipt of disability payments.18 Examiningaggregate time series as well as cross-statevariation,John Bound and Timothy Waidmannconcludedthatvirtuallyall of the increasein nonemployment amongthose reportingthatthey were ill or disabledin the CPS could be explainedby increasedreceipt of disabilitybenefits.19Autor and Mark Dugganconcludedthatliberalizationof eligibilityfor disabilityinsurance interactswith adverse shifts in labor demand,as otherwiseemployable over unemploymentor low-wage men opt for subsidizednonparticipation work.Figure6 offers indirectsupportiveevidenceon this point,comparing the changes in unemploymentand nonparticipationbetween peaks and troughsof differentbusinesscycles. The figureshows thatincreased nonparticipationaccountedfor a much largerfractionof rising nonemploymentin 1989-92 thanin earlierrecessions.The smallestcontribution was in the recession of 1992, when eligibility rules of nonparticipation were tightened.The increasein nonemploymentamongthe ill or disabled accountedfor nearly 16 percentof the total change in nonemployment between 1989 and 1992 (not shown), a much higherproportionthan in previousrecessions.Nonemploymentof the ill or disabledactuallyfell during the 1982 recession, an observationthat also likely reflects the tighteningof eligibilityrulesduringthis period. Table 4 decomposes secular changes in nonemploymentbetween 1967-69 and 1999-2000, as well as over the 1990s. In the 1990s the data indicate that roughlyhalf (0.8 percentagepoint) of the 1.5-percentagereflectsa shiftin laborsupplycausedby pointincreasein nonparticipation improving nonmarketalternativesto working. There is no reason to believe thatthe healthof Americanmen deterioratedover the decade(and Yet nonparticipation caused much reasonto believe that it improved).20 18. AutorandDuggan(forthcoming);BoundandWaidmann(2000). 19. BoundandWaidmann(2000). 20. See MurphyandTopel (2001), for example. 98 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 Figure 6. Changesin Unemploymentand NonparticipationEntering Recessions Percentagepoints 5 - 0 Unemployment E Nonparticipation 43- 2- fAf?:$d9; 'S' i; 1969-71 1973-75 ..... ........ ;.~~~~~~~~~~~~........ 1979-82 1989-92 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. by self-reportedhealthreasonsincreasedby 0.8 percentagepointover the decade.Unlike in the early 1970s, when real wages were risingrapidlyas nonparticipationincreased,real wages remainedlow and were falling over the firsthalf of the 1990s. This fact makesit moredifficultto parcel out the componentdue to shiftinglabor supply.Yet with the increasein real wages in the latter half of the decade, continuinggrowth of nonparticipationindicatesa shift in labor supply. In a manneranalogousto interpretationsof the Europeanunemploymentexperience,the dataindicate thatthe interactionof disabilitybenefitsandlabormarketshocksmay be of key importance in understandingrising rates of labor force withdrawal.2' Figure7 summarizesour previousresults,showinglong-termchanges in three alternativemeasures of joblessness since the late 1960s. The unemploymentrate shows the most dramaticimprovementof the three measuresin the 1990s, nearlyreturningto 1960s levels. By this common 21. AutorandDuggan(forthcoming). ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 99 Table 4. Changes in Nonemployment,by Reported Reason for Nonemployment, 1967-2000a Percentagepoints Reasonfor nonemployment No work available Illness or disability Other Total Change1967-69 to 1999-2000 Nonemployment Outof laborforce Unemployment 1.2 0.6 0.6 1.7 1.7 0.0 1.8 1.7 0.0 4.7 4.0 0.6 Change1988-89 to 1999-2000 Nonemployment Outof laborforce Unemployment -1.9 -0.4 -1.5 0.8 0.8 0.0 1.1 1.0 0.0 0.0 1.5 -1.5 Measure Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data. a. Details may not sum to totals because of rounding. Figure 7. Changesin Unemployed,Discouraged,and NonemployedWorkers Since 1967, 1967-2000 Percent 10 Nonemployed Other nonparticipating 8 6 4 2 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Discouragedworkersare those who reportnot being employed because they were unable to find a job; they are not included in the labor force. 100 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 measureof labormarketperformance,events have come full circle, and one mightarguethatthe naturalrateof joblessnesshas returnedto previous low levels. Adding nonparticipantswho are discouragedworkers changes the conclusion slightly, althoughthe figure also demonstrates thattherehas been no reductionin discouragedworkerssince the 1980s. to give totalnonemploymentchangesthe Addingin othernonparticipants interpretation substantially.By this measuretherewas no improvementin overalljoblessnessfromthe late 1980s to 2000, despitefallingunemploymentrates.In this sense, changesin unemploymentprovidea misleading picture of changes in employmentopportunitiesand the likelihood of findingwork. The Incidence and Duration of Jobless Spells The dataon full-yearnonemploymentsuggestthatthe concentrationof unemploymentand nonemploymentincreased dramaticallyover the periodcoveredby our data.Table 5 providesfurtherevidence, showing, for variousperiods,the distributionsof spells of joblessnessduringa calendaryear. The trendtowardlong-termjoblessness is unmistakable.For rate was 6.3 percent, example, in the 1960s, when the nonparticipation men who were jobless for the entireyear accountedfor 28.8 percentof nonemployment.But by the end of the 1990s-when nonemployment reached11 percent-full-year nonemploymentaccountedfor over half of all joblessness. A similar patternholds for unemployment(table 6). Althoughunemploymentratesin 1999-2000 were roughlycomparableto those in the 1960s, the shareof unemploymentdue to shortspells (one to thirteenweeks) fell by one-third,from30 percentto 20 percent.Individuals with more than six monthsof unemploymentaccountedfor about a quarterof all unemploymentin the 1960s,but46 percentby the end of the 1990s. These shifts toward long-termjoblessness mean that particular have much differentmeanrates of unemploymentand nonparticipation ings todaythanin pastdecades. To examinethe increasedimportanceof long spells more closely, we use informationin the CPSto estimateboththe incidenceandthe duration of jobless spells. Focusingfirston unemployment,we note thatthe rateof unemploymentcan be decomposedinto the productof two components: the probabilityof an individualenteringunemployment(the entryrate), ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 101 Table 5. Distributionof Nonemployment,1967-2000a Percentof nonemployed Numberof weeksa year Period 1967-69 1971-72 1972-73 1975-76 1978-79 1982-83 1988-89 1991-92 1999-2000 2 orfewer 3 to 12 13 to 25 26 to 38 39 to 51 52 2.4 1.5 1.6 1.1 1.5 0.8 1.0 0.8 0.7 17.2 12.9 12.4 9.9 13.1 8.1 10.3 8.8 8.0 18.9 18.8 17.2 16.6 17.7 13.9 13.2 12.7 9.7 18.0 21.2 21.7 22.5 20.2 20.6 19.0 19.1 13.9 14.8 15.9 15.3 17.2 14.4 18.3 15.2 14.9 12.2 28.8 29.7 31.9 32.7 33.2 38.3 41.3 43.8 55.5 Source: Authors' calculations based on MarchCPS data. a. Details may not sum to 100 because of rounding. and the averagedurationof an unemploymentspell. Denote the instantaneous transitionratesfromemployment(e) andout of the laborforce (o) to unemployment(u) at date t by Xeu(t) and XOu(t),respectively,and the correspondingrates at which individualsleave unemploymentby Xue(t) andXkj(t).Thenthe rateof changein the unemploymentrateis (1) du(t) = dt e(t)Xeu(t) + o(t)0ou(t) - U(t)[Rue(t) + X0o(t)]. The steady-statefractionof weeks spentunemployed,[du(t)ldt= 0], correspondingto the entryandexit ratesat any given pointin time satisfies Table 6. Distributionof Unemployment,1967-20O0 Percentof unemployed Numberof weeksa year Period 1967-69 1971-72 1972-73 1975-76 1978-79 1982-83 1988-89 1991-92 1999-2000 13 orfewer 14 to 26 27 to 39 40 to 49 50 to 52 30.3 20.4 20.6 17.8 27.0 13.7 22.6 16.9 20.4 42.3 40.6 39.9 31.2 34.2 28.9 33.5 31.7 33.4 14.9 21.5 21.0 22.8 19.0 21.7 18.5 20.6 18.2 8.9 10.9 10.4 14.5 11.8 17.9 14.8 16.4 14.6 3.6 6.6 8.2 13.7 8.0 17.7 10.5 14.3 13.4 Source: Authors' calculations based on MarchCPS data. a. Details may not sum to 100 because of rounding. 102 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 () u(t) = [1-uWWI (2) ) where e (t) X-(t) = 'u(t) = Xue X-eu(t) + o* (t) X,u(t), and (t) + X-u(t). Here Xkis the rate at which individualsenter unemployment,being a share-weightedaverageof entryratesfor personswho are employedand those who are out of the laborforce. Similarly,X'(t) is the rateat which individualsleave unemploymentby becomingemployedor by leavingthe labor force. Since 1/X'(t) is the average durationcorrespondingto the contemporaneousrateof exit from unemployment,and [1 - u*(t)]X.(t) is the expectednumberof spells of unemploymentper year at the current entry rate, equation2 has a naturalinterpretationin terms of entry and duration.Growth in the steady-statefraction of the year spent unemployed can be decomposedinto growthin the probabilityof becoming unemployed(entry)andthe averagedurationof unemploymentspells. To implementthis frameworkempirically,we use two identitiesthat correspondto equation 1 integratedover the year. The change in the unemploymentratefromthe beginningto the end of yeart is (4) U,(t) - UO(t) = [1- U (t)]u () - U (0)u ('0, where U1(r)is the unemploymentrate(measuredas a fractionof the population)at the end of yearX, UjQr)is the correspondingrateat the startof the year, and U(t) is the averageunemploymentrateover the year.With these definitions,Xu(t) andX' (t) are weightedaveragesof the instantaThe expected neous transitionprobabilitiesto andfromunemployment.22 numberof spells of unemploymentover the yearis then (5) S(t) = Uo(t) + [1 - U ()r), since spells are generatedeitherby startingthe year unemployed,UO(t), or by becomingunemployedduringthe year, [1-U(r)]Xu(t). To estimate the entryandexit parameters,we use the datafromthe CPS togetherwith 22. The weights in these weighted averages are (1 - u)(0) and u(O), respectively, where e indexes weeks over the year. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 103 monthly data on aggregaterates to interpolatethe startingand ending numbersfor each year. Solving equations4 and 5 gives our estimating equationsfor unemploymenttransitionsas (6) () S(t)-U0(t) 1-U(t) and (7) (u S(t)- U,() The resultingestimatesareshownin the top panelof figure8 andin the first two data columns of table 7. For unemployment,the key findingis thatan increasein durationsaccountsfor the entiregrowthin unemployment over the 1967-2000 period.The entryrateinto unemploymentwas actuallylower in 1999-2000 (0.7 percenta month)thanit was in 1967-69 (1.1 percenta month),whereasdurationsof unemploymentspells doubled from2.1 to 4.2 months.Notice fromequation3 thata decliningincidence of unemploymentspells can be caused eitherby a decline in the rate at which individualslose their jobs, Xeu(t), or by a decline in the rate at which nonparticipantsstartto look for work, XOu(t). These contributions arenot separatelyidentified,althoughit is likely thatthe o -* u transition has declined substantiallyas nonparticipationhas become a permanent laborforce state for largernumbersof men. In any case, we cannotconclude fromtable6 andfigure8 thatthe e -* u transitionhas declined,that is, thatjobs have becomemore stable. Accordingto figure8, untilthe recessionof 1991-92, cyclical fluctuations in unemploymentwere drivenby changesin boththe incidenceand the durationof spells, with roughly equal weights on each component. But rising incidence played a minor role in the recession of 1991-92, while durationssoared. Indeed, unemploymentdurationsin 1993 were virtuallythe sameas in the recessionyear 1983, whichwerethe highestin all the yearsof our data,while the entryratewas about25 percentlower. The ensuingdeclinein unemploymentover the remainderof the decadeis drivenalmostentirelyby reducedprobabilitiesof becomingunemployed; durationsof unemploymentremainedhigh. From these data it appears that the main characteristicof the 1990s is that the historic correspondence between the incidence and the durationof unemploymentspells BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 104 Figure 8. EstimatedEntry Rates and Durationsfor Unemploymentand Nonemployment,1967-2000 Unemploymenta Monthsa year Percenta month 2.2 - Duration (rightscale) 2.0 - A" 5.0 / 1.8- ,*/13 {/ \~~~~~~~~~~~ 04 1 45 1.61.4 --3.5 - 3.0 0.8 2.5 Entry rate ,' (leftscale) _ 2.0 0.6 _ _ l l l l I l Nonemploymentb Duration (rightscale) 2.2 - 4 , 2.0 - 1 1.8 - ,1 1.6 11.4 -(left 10 scale) 1.2 8 6 0.8 0.6 _ l l l l l I 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Estimatedfrom the numberof spells using equations5, 6, and 7. b. Based on incidence of nonemployment;see text for details. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 105 Table 7. Estimated Entry Rates and Durations of Unemploymentand Nonemployment,1967-2000 Units as indicated Unemploymenta Nonemploymentb Phase of businesscycle Entryrate (percenta month) Duration (months) Entryrate (percenta month) Duration (months) 1967-69 1971-72 1972-73 Peak Trough Peak 1.1 1.5 1.4 2.1 3.2 2.9 1.0 1.2 1.1 6.7 8.6 8.5 1975-76 Trough 1.8 4.1 1.5 9.6 1978-79 1982-83 1988-89 1991-92 1999-2000 Peak Trough Peak Trough Peak 1.5 1.9 1.3 1.5 0.7 3.1 5.1 3.5 4.5 4.2 1.4 1.5 1.1 1.3 0.8 8.4 12.0 11.0 12.4 15.1 Period Source: Authors' calculations based on March CPS data. a. Estimatedfrom the numberof spells using equations 5, 6, and 7. b. Based on incidence of nonemployment;see text for details. came to an abruptend. Withfewerbutlongerspells, the populationdistributionof unemploymentis muchmoreconcentratedthanin earlieryears. The last two columnsof table 7 andthe bottompanelof figure8 show correspondingcalculationsfor the incidenceanddurationof nonemployment spells. In the case of nonemployment,the CPS does not provide informationon the numberof spells in a calendaryear-separate spells of arenot recorded-and so we use dataon the incidenceof nonparticipation nonemploymentover the year (thatis, the fractionof men with positive weeks of nonemployment)to infer the entry rate.23These calculations show thatthe contrastbetweenentryand durationis even more extreme than in the case of unemployment.As with unemployment,the rate of entryto nonemploymentis actuallylowerin 1999-2000 thanit was in the 1960s, but durationsshow a steady upwardtrend over the thirty-four 23. The fractionof individualswho experiencezero nonemployment(thatis, who are employedfor the full year)is given by F(r) = Eo(r)exp[-12X*(r)],whereX*(t)is the average monthlynonemploymenthazardover the yearfor individualswho havenot yet entered nonemployment,andEj(t) is the employmentrateat the startof the year.In general,X*(1t) for the populationof <X (t), whereX (t) is the averagerateof transitionto nonemployment employedpeople.This will cause our estimatesof entryandexit ratesto be biaseddownward.We attemptedto assess the magnitudeandvariabilityin this bias with similarcalculations for unemployment,where the numberof spells is recorded.In that case the bias variedlittle over time, lendingsome confidencethatthis methodshouldnot be too faroff. 106 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 yearscoveredby ourdata,withno sign of slowergrowthin the 1990s. By the end of the decadethe averagedurationof nonemploymentspells was over fifteenmonths,which is morethandoublethe lengthof spells in the late 1960s. The averagedurationof spells rose by over fourmonthsfrom the late 1980s to 1999-2000, reflectingthe increasingproportionof men who have simplyquitthe laborforce. Table 7 and figure8 painta clear picture.Althoughthe ratesof entry into unemploymentand nonemploymenthave returnedto or even fallen below levels experiencedduringthe late 1960s, the durationsof jobless spells aremorethantwice as long at the end of the period.Indeed,jobless spells were longer in 1999-2000 than at any previous cyclical low of unemployment,andthey exceededthe averagedurationof spells over the whole period of the data. It should be clear from these data that the employmentpatternsof the late 1990s resemble other periods of low unemployment-the late 1960s in particular-only in termsof the overall rate of unemploymentand the rates at which individualsenterjoblessness. The durationsof spells arevery differentandvery muchlonger.For the typicalworker,the occurrenceof a jobless spell is a fardifferentevent thanit was in the past. Unemployment,Nonemployment,and Wages Our previous analysis of wage and employmentdata through 1989 foundthatthe patternsof changein unemploymentand nonemployment variedsignificantlyacrossskill groups,as definedby percentileintervals of the overall wage distribution.Figure 9 and table 8 summarizeour results based on wage percentilegroupingsfor the period 1967-2000. Table 8 recordschanges in unemployment,nonparticipation,and total joblessness between 1967-69 and 1988-89 (the end of the data in our 1991 paper),between 1988-89 and 1999-2000, and over the full period of ourdata. All componentsof nonemploymentincreasedthe most for low-wage workers,especiallybefore 1989. Overthe 1990s, nonparticipation continued to rise while unemploymentratesdeclinedsharply.Reversingprevious trends,in the 1990s bothunemploymentandoverallnonemployment fell the most for workersin the bottom 10 percentof the wage distribution. Otherlow-wage groupsalso experiencedlower unemploymentover Figure 9. Unemployment,Nonparticipation,and Nonemployment,by Wage PercentileGroup, 1967-2000 Unemployment Percentof calendaryear 16 I tol /s0 -- l to 20 21 to 40 1_ -------41to 60 ''\ \ 12 8- Nonparticipation 20 15 10 S __-' 5,, . . .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ ..... ...,,,,,,.,, .....------.---- Nonemployment 35 3025 20 1970 1975 1980 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. 1985 1990 1995 108 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 Table 8. Changesin Unemployment,Nonparticipation,and Nonemployment,by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000 Percentagepoints Wagepercentilegroup Period I to 10 11 to 20 21 to 40 41 to 60 61 to 100 Unemployment 1967-69 to 1988-89 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1967-69 to 1999-2000 6.4 -4.6 1.8 4.9 -3.1 1.8 2.6 -1.6 1.1 1.5 -1.0 0.5 0.3 -0.5 -0.1 Nonparticipation 1967-69 to 1988-89 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1967-69to 1999-2000 10.9 0.8 11.7 7.2 2.4 9.5 2.9 2.6 5.5 1.3 1.3 2.6 0.0 0.9 0.9 Nonemployment 1967-69 to 1988-89 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1967-69 to 1999-2000 17.3 -3.8 13.5 12.1 -0.8 11.3 5.6 1.0 6.6 2.8 0.3 3.0 0.3 0.4 0.8 Full-yearnonemployment 1967-69 to 1988-89 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1967-69 to 1999-2000 10.2 1.7 12.0 6.3 2.7 8.9 2.9 2.4 5.4 1.6 1.3 2.9 0.5 0.9 1.4 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. the decade,althoughnonemploymentwas largelyunchangedfor workers above the bottom 10 percent,reflectingrising rates of laborforce withdrawal. Even with the sharp decline in unemploymentfor low-wage workersin recentyears,however,for the full periodbothunemployment andnonemploymentincreasedmost amongthe least skilled.Nonemployment rose by roughly 12 percentagepoints for the two lowest wage groups,but by less than 1 percentagepoint for men above the 60th percentile of the wage distribution.For workersnearthe median(percentiles 41-60), unemploymentwas essentiallyunchangedover the period as a whole, yet nonemploymentincreasedby 3 percentagepoints. Cyclicalincreasesin joblessnessareknownto fall most heavilyon the least skilled. Figure 10 comparesthe skill distributionsof cyclical and secularchangesin nonemployment.Foreach of the wage intervalsshown in table 8, the figure shows the averagecyclical change in jobless time going into and out of four recessions(1970-71, 1975-76, 1982-83, and ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 109 Figure 10. Cyclical and Secular Changesin Nonemployment,by Wage Percentile Group, 1967-2000 Percentage pointsa EJAverage over recessionsb 1967-69 to 1988-89 * 1988-89 to 1999-2000 * 15 - 10 - 5 0 I to 10 II to 20 21 to 40 41 to 60 61 to 100 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Change in the percentof weeks a year nonemployed. b. Average change entering(troughminus peak) and exiting (peak minus trough)four recessions (1970-71, 1975-76, 1982-83, and 1991-92). 1991-92),24the secular change between the cyclical peaks of 1967-69 and 1988-89 (the period covered in our 1991 paper), and the shorter secular change over the more recent 1988-89 to 1999-2000 period. Comparedwith business-cycleincreasesin nonemployment,the secular changein nonemploymentfromthe late 1960s to the late 1980s was much more skewed towardlow-skilled men, with virtuallyno impact on persons above the medianof the wage distribution.The secularmovement over the recentperiodis morenearlyskill neutral,with the exceptionthat nonemploymentfell significantlyfor men in the first decile of the wage distribution.In this sense the 1990srepresenta smallreversalof declining 24. We measurethis by the averageof the changegoing into andout of each recessionary period. The periods are defined using the same year groupingsused in the tables: 1967-69, 1970-71, 1972-73, 1975-76, 1978-79, 1982-83, 1988-89, 1991-92, and 1999-2000. 110 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 employment opportunitiesamong the least skilled. We relate these changes to concomitantchanges in the distributionof wages below, but firstwe takea briefdetourto explorean alternativeexplanationfor changingjobless ratesamongprime-agedmen, namely,the labormarketopportunitiesof theirwives. Did Working Wives Shift Male Labor Supply? It remainsour view that long-termchanges in male joblessness were drivenby changesin labordemandthatdisproportionately affectedlessskilled workers. These adverse demandconditions continued into the 1990s, althoughsomewhatmitigated,so thatnonemploymentcontinued to rise even as measuredunemploymentwas falling. An alternative explanation-with far differentwelfare implications-is that increased wages andgreaterlaborforce participationof womenhave shiftedmen's laborsupply:as the labormarketopportunitiesof wives improved,husbands chose to work less and household utility rose. On this view, at least partof the long-termincreasein nonemploymentamongmen represents a welfare-improvingchangein householdlaborsupplydecisions. Table9 andfigure11 explorethis issue. Table9 recordsmale earnings, the percentageof householdswith a workingwife, averageearningsof wives, and averagehouseholdincome for householdsin differentpercentilesof the malewage distribution.Amongless-skilledmen,wherethe largest increasesin nonemploymentoccurred,the percentageof households with a workingwife actuallyfell over time. For these men, declining marriageratesoffset increasedlaborforce participationof women, so that fewer low-wage men today reside with a working wife. For lessskilled men, averagehouseholdincome (which includes earningsof all household members)increasedonly slightly from 1972-73 (when the trendtowardrising inequalitybegan) to 1999-2000: averagehousehold income rose by 11 percentin each of the percentileintervals1-10 and 21-40; in these groups, increases in the average earningsof working wives by 40 percenthelpedto offset decliningmale earnings.In contrast, the presenceof a workingwife is both higher and rising in households above the 60th percentileof the male wage distribution,where men's wages were rising and employmentrateswere stable.The shareof these householdsin which a workingwife was presentincreasedby 9 percentage pointsafter1972-73 andby 12 percentagepointsfromthe 1960s, and ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 111 Table 9. HouseholdEarnings Characteristics,by Wage PercentileGroup, 1967-2000a 1996 dollarsa year,exceptwherenotedotherwise Item 1st to I Othpercentile Maleearnings Percentof households with workingwife Wife's earningsb Householdincome 21st to 40thpercentile Maleearnings Percentof households with workingwife Wife's earnings Householdincome 61st to I 00thpercentile Male earnings Percentof households with workingwife Wife's earnings Householdincome All households Maleearnings Percentof households with workingwife Wife's earnings Householdincome 1999-2000 1967-69 1972-73 1978-79 1988-89 11,134 11,354 11,479 8,625 9,584 38 3,050 22,965 36 3,392 26,366 36 3,766 28,140 31 3,975 25,952 29 4,770 29,194 23,746 25,213 23,579 21,522 21,507 49 5,132 35,394 48 5,773 39,137 48 6,133 40,770 46 7,410 40,773 40 8,091 43,431 44,213 49,375 47,147 51,449 59,843 41 4,786 54,456 45 5,918 61,722 50 7,219 61,861 55 11,537 71,937 54 14,993 88,507 31,230 34,121 32,686 33,193 36,789 44 4,713 42,263 45 5,548 47,538 48 6,388 48,560 49 8,895 52,821 45 10,854 61,541 Sources: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data and Economic Reportof the President, 2001. a. Earningsand household income are deflated by the price index for personal consumptionexpenditure.Male's and wife's earnings include income from wages, salary, and self-employment; household income includes all sources of earned and nonearned income of all household members. b. Average of wife's earningsfor all males in the sample; the observationis zero when there is no working wife. the averageearningsof these wives increasedby 153 percentbetween 1972-73 andthe end of the century. It is difficult to square these facts with the view that long-term increases in labor force withdrawalamong men have been driven by improvedlabormarketopportunitiesfor theirwives. To settle the issue, figure 11 shows changes in unemployment,nonparticipation,and fullyearnonemploymentfor men with andwithoutworkingwives. The clear patternis thatrisingunemploymentandlaborforce withdrawalhave been concentratedamongmen who do not have a workingwife. The contrastin trendsis particularlystrikingfor nonparticipationand full-yearnonemployment,where men without a workingwife have steadily withdrawn Figure 11. Male Nonemploymentand Nonparticipation,with and withouta Working Wife, 1967-2000a Nonemployment Percentof calendaryear 20 Withoutworkingwife 15 Withworkingwife Nonparticipation 12 F 10 86 42 - Full-yearnonemployment 10 86 4 2 - 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: Authors'calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. To qualify as a workingwife, the wife must both live with her husbandand have workedat least one week duringthe previous year. ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 113 fromregularemployment.Fromthese datawe concludethata theorybuilt on shifts in householdlaborsupplywill not go far in explainingchanges in malejoblessness. Wage Changes, Labor Supply, and Nonemployment So far our discussionhas focused on changes in unemploymentand nonemploymentover time. Figure 1 andtable 1 showedthatmanyof the same patternsobservedwith regardto employmentand unemployment hold for realwages. Inequalityin realwages grew significantlyfrom 1970 to 1990 across the full range of the wage distribution.Since 1990, inequalityhas continuedto increaseat the top of the wage distribution, but inequalityhas held steady or even narrowedslightly at the bottom: both low-wage and middle-wage workers experienced real wage increasesstartingaround1995. These increasesin real hourlywages representthe first significantgrowthin real wages for low- to middle-wage males since the early 1970s. According to our earlier analysis, rising wages for these groupsshouldlead to increasedemploymentrates,especially amongthe least skilled, for whom we concludedthatlaborsupply elasticitieswere largest. At a generallevel, trendsin nonemploymentby wage percentilegroup (bottompanelof figure9) andtrendsin real wages for these same groups (figure 1) reveal a similarpattern.In both cases low-wage workersfared far worse thantheirmiddle-andhigh-wagecounterpartsfor muchof the sampleperiod,and in both cases the divergencestops in the 1980s (after roughly 1983 in the case of employment,and afterroughly 1989 in the case of wages). Ourearlierpaperformalizedthis connection,arguingthat declining rewardsto work provokedlabor supply responsesfrom lessskilled workers, who chose to work less. To what extent does the demand-drivenexplanationwe stressedin our earlierpaper-that individuals respondto changingreal wage opportunities-help us to understand the changes since 1989 in employmentfor men in differentskill categories? Table 10 presentsestimatedpartiallabor supply elasticities obtained fromcross-sectionaldatafor the years 1972-73 and 1988-89.25Ourestimates correspondclosely to those reportedin our earlier paper. They 25. To obtain these elasticities,we fit a quadraticfunctionusing averagewage and employmentdataby percentilecategory.We reportthe slope at each percentile. 114 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 Table 10. EstimatedLabor Supply Elasticitiesand Changesin Nonemploymentand Wages, 1972-2000a Unitsas indicated Wagepercentilegroup Partial labor labor supply elasticityb Change inn nonem Changein real lognoepymt log real ~~(percentagepoints) hourlywage (percent) Predicted Actual 1972-73 to 1988-89 1 to 10 11 to 20 21 to40 41to60 61 to lOO Entiresample 0.287 0.217 0.170 0.126 0.048 n.a. -24.8 -22.3 -16.5 -9.2 -0.2 -9.9 7.0 4.7 2.7 1.1 0.1 2.0 10.2 5.7 2.6 0.8 -0.1 2.2 1988-89 to 1999-2000 1 to 10 llto20 21 to40 41 to 60 61 to 100 Entiresample 0.287 0.217 0.170 0.126 0.048 n.a. 2.3 -0.4 -1.5 -1.2 7.0 2.4 -0.7 0.1 0.3 0.2 0.1 0.1 -3.8 -0.8 1.0 0.3 0.4 0.0 Source: Authors' calculationsbased on MarchCPS data. a. Laborsupply elasticities and observed changes in real wages are used to predictthe change in nonemployment. b. Elasticities in both panels are estimated using cross-sectional data on average wage and employment, by percentile, for 1972-73 and 1988-89. show substantiallyhigherelasticitiesat low wages:the employmentrates of less-skilled workersare more responsiveto wage changes. The top panel of the table illustratesthe fact thatthe large wage declines (shown in the second data column),togetherwith the estimatedelasticities,can accountfor mostof the rise in nonemploymentfrom 1972-73 to 1988-89. The bottompanelof the tableuses the same laborsupplyelasticitiesestimatedfrompre-1990data,togetherwith post-1989wage changes,to predict changesin nonemploymentduringthe 1990s. Thereis a reasonable correspondencebetweenthe predictedandthe actualchanges:we predict an improvementin employmentfor the lowest wage groupandsomewhat worseningconditionsfor the othergroupsbelow the median.Yet we also the improvementin employmentfor the least-skilledgroup. underpredict Althoughwages and employmentare obviously linked in the long run, our interpretation of the resultsis thatthe laborsupplymodel is less successful in predictingthe dynamicsof employmentandwage changesover ChinhuiJuhn, KevinM. Murphy,and RobertH. Topel 115 a relativelyshortperiod.Notice also thatemploymentgains precededthe recoveryin wages among the least skilled, which is inconsistentwith a purelaborsupplyexplanationof changingemploymentrates. Conclusion We have examinedunemploymentandnonemploymentamongprimeaged males in the United States using thirty-fouryears of data on labor marketoutcomes. Although recent unemploymentrates have fallen to rates levels reminiscentof the 1960s, we findthatrisingnonparticipation have offset reductionsin unemployment,leaving nonemploymentrates unchanged.The rise in nonparticipationappearsto be due to both an expansionof the disabilitybenefits program-as previous researchhas argued-and continuedlow levels of real wages of less-skilledmen during the 1990s. in the Comparedwith earlierdecades,the increasein nonparticipation skill groups.Employmentratesof 1990s is moreevenly distributedacross the least skilled rose the most, even as their wages lagged behindother groupsfor muchof the decade.This suggeststhatrisinginequality,which characterizedlabor marketsin the 1970s and 1980s, may have run its course. Is the Americanlabormarkettoday fundamentallydifferentfromthat of the 1960s?Despite the comparabilityof unemploymentratesbetween the late 1960s and the late 1990s, the changingcompositionof nonemand from part-year ployment-from unemploymentto nonparticipation, to full-yearnonemployment-suggeststhatthe combinationof low wages and the availabilityof nonworkalternativeshas madeout-of-workmales increasinglyless likely to enter new jobs. From this perspective,our assessmentof the labormarketfor less-skilledmen is rathergrim. Ourearlierwork concludedthatthe naturalrate of unemployment,or of nonemployment,is not a constanttowardwhich the economy gravitates over time. Rather,it varieswith labormarketconditionsin a manner consistentwith the original formulationof EdmundPhelps.26Over the long term, the naturalrate of nonemploymenthas increased because 26. Phelps(1974). 116 BrookingsPapers on EconomicActivity,1:2002 changingpatternsof labordemandhave reducedthe returnsto work for less-skilledmen. In this setting,the low unemploymentratesof the latter half of the 1990s have a far differentinterpretation thancomparablerates of the past. By the end of the 1990s, an importantproportionof lessskilled men had withdrawnfrom the laborforce for demand-related reasons. Thatthey arenot countedamongthose seekingworkis not a sign of strengthin currentlabormarketconditions.