STRATEGIC THINKER L obbying represents a dilemma for most organisations. On the one hand, organisations should seek to influence government departments or regulators whose actions affect them. On the other, any lobbying-like communications appear suspicious to the media and ultimately the general public. This suspicion makes government nervous over business involvement with government decision-making which then makes organisations nervous about engaging with government. Gradually, a vicious circle develops where a legitimate corporate activity looks illegitimate. How can organisations negotiate a path through what is either a dangerous threat to organisational reputation if they do lobby, or organisational performance if they do not? Also, what is the role of the communications director in this discussion? RESPONSIBLE LOBBYING 24 Lobbying maybe the archetypical dirty word, but introducing transparency and promoting its market-making benefits should change perceptions. By Howard Viney and Paul Baines 04/2013 COMMUNICATION DIRECTOR LOCATION MATTERS Perhaps one of the biggest challenges is that attitudes to lobbying appear to vary depending upon location. Washington politics appears to depend upon lobbying, a guilty secret that everyone is aware of, whereas Brussels politics appears to embrace and encourage lobbying, an open engagement between government and business which might provide a template for other political centres such as London, where lobbying is neither truly encouraged, tolerated nor forbidden but rather appears increasingly to be an accident waiting to happen. It is this uncertainty as to what role lobbying can or should play in a representative democracy which prompts us to seek to make a case for lobbying. In addition, we Photo:s: Financial Times (2) STRATEGIC THINKER aim to explain why transparency and openness can provide a winwin-win scenario for government, business and society. We start with a problem we believe is at the heart of the question: the public’s mistrust of the concept of lobbying. Mistrust derives from the image that has been built up around the lobbyist as a furtive influence peddler engaged in undesirable, improper and even inappropriate activities, seeking to buy influence with government to protect the interests of a shadowy client. The implication is that public well-being is being undermined by lobbying, wherein well-resourced organisations use their resources to protect market failure, or imperfections in the market. This means that organisations acquire greater value for the delivery of their products or services than they would in a wellfunctioning competitive market, which would favour the consumer. From an economic perspective, lobbying is evidence of ‘rent-seeking’ behaviour (manipulating the social or political environment to generate profit) which is seen less favourably than ‘market-making’ activity (creating new markets and demand to generate profits). Market-making increases the sum of wellbeing in an economy by increasing employment and encouraging growth. Rent-seeking behaviour has the opposite effect and represents exploitation of existing strength to no-one’s benefit except the corporation. Using this line of thought, the lobbying company is clearly a corporate villain. THE BENEFITS OF REFORM The nail has been further hammered into the coffin of lobbying’s reputation due to its frequent association with the bribery of public officials – an illegal act – or the making of excessive campaign contributions – which is not always illegal. High profile examples have compounded the problem. Many organisations make contributions across the political divide at elections, favouring no one party but seeking to influence all. However this represents one side of the argument, albeit the side most often debated. The other side proposes that organisations play a significant role in a representative democracy, supporting government in the creation of effective laws and regulation and assuming much of the cost. At the very highest level, organisations can co-create new laws and regulations. This may be looked upon disapprovingly in some quarters, but if a new technology is emerging Organisations play a significant role in a representative democracy. or new ethical dilemmas are created by a medical development, would tax-payers be willing to pay for government to develop the necessary skills and knowledge to deliver a wholly objective opinion? We suspect not. Co-creation with organisations leading the technological change is frequently a necessity on many levels. Similarly, organisations already play a very important role in the provision of information in developing more standard laws or regulation, offering opinions at the request of government during the policy development phase of the legislative process. From this perspective lobbying activity plays an active and positive role in a representative democracy. MAKING A CONTRIBUTION However, the key question is the self-interest involved in lobbying. The inevitable suspicion is that organisations are only motivated to act when their interests are challenged. But is this necessarily a negative act? Individuals faced with a planned new building project, for example, have a legitimate right to make their voices heard and would feel justifiably aggrieved to have that opportunity denied. Why does this not apply to organisations? We believe it should apply to all organisations, but the challenge is in how that message is communicated and what organisations must do to ensure that the message is credible and legitimate. The European Commission has championed transparency in interest representation since its lobbying green paper in 2006. One interesting observation is that its code 04/2013 COMMUNICATION DIRECTOR 25 STRATEGIC THINKER of conduct is enabling rather than constraining; therefore it is concerned with offering external scrutiny of relationships to ensure transparency (and hence public confidence) is built into information or other exchanges. It also publishes rules on integrity, highlighting what is perceived to be good behaviour rather than focusing upon what is identified as bad or unacceptable behaviour. The difference between rules on integrity and more limiting language (such as found in the new UK lobbying bill which “places limits”, “sets caps”, and widely discusses “taking enforcement action”) is perhaps only semantic but it certainly implies a different value being placed upon the contribution being made by organisations which lobby to the economics they operate in. THE ROUTE FORWARD We would like to address one more important issue regarding organisational capability. We believe that organisations often face difficulty in managing ethical dilemmas because they are designed as profit-maximising machines and their managers are incentivised to seek profit maximisation; anything less would be to fail to deliver against their financial responsibilities to their owners. If this is no longer acceptable, politically or socially, organisations need to review their organisational capabilities to live in their new operating environments. However, this does not imply a fundamental review of how organisations conduct their business. Rather, there are number of small actions for business and for government which offer the potential to create a win-win-win outcome. For business we suggest a change in attitude regarding how organisations talk about how they engage with government and there is a strong communication as- The role of the non-executive ethicist would be to act as the conscience of the organisation. 26 pect to this. We argue for a commitment on the part of organisations towards openness about how and why they interact with government, recognising the inherent selfinterest of any such action but also emphasising the positive contribution such dialogue can make to an effectively operating democracy. Organisations would commit to list all interactions with government or regulator publicly on their corporate website, using this opportunity to make an argument as to why this action is legitimate and justifiable. To us, the argument that an organisation is seeking 04/2013 COMMUNICATION DIRECTOR EXECUTIVE SUMMARY Towards transparency Organisations should admit the self-interest inherent in lobbying, but also advertise the beneficial effect of such dialogue The advancement of commercial interest as a motivation should not be disguised but linked to market-making benefits Large organisations should appoint an ‘ethicist on board’, a non-executive director to spearhead ethical concerns and act as devil’s advocate to advance its commercial interest is not one that ought to be disguised, especially if the motivation is market-making and will have a wider positive outcome. The vast majority of lobbying activity is legitimate and makes an active contribution to a well-functioning representative democracy. Organisations should reflect this reality in their communication strategy. Government also need not be squeamish about favouring organisations engaged in lobbying when this has a positive impact upon the economy or society. As a sign of good faith, large organisations could take an extra step to build confidence by appointing a non-executive director whose sole responsibility is to offer advice on the ethical aspects of any decisions taken by an organisation. The role of the non-executive ethicist would be to act as the conscience of the organisation, tasked with the responsibility to act as devil’s advocate, challenging major decisions to ensure that they can be defended on ethical grounds and anticipating public responses to actions so that they may be communicated to stake- STRATEGIC THINKER holders without fear of reputational damage. This may not appear to advocate any new role for the non-executive directorate, but we suggest that the role of being the board’s ethicist might represent a significant change in the background of appointees. Communication directors with a background in responsible lobbying or lawyers with experience or specialised training are but two possible examples. Such a role would require a different range of working experience or training to be able to address complex ethical questions in order to improve rather than simply hinder executive decision-making. The key benefit of appointing a non-executive ethicist would be that organisations could defend corporate decisions because they Photo: Alex Griffiths For government, we suggest a much more explicit code of conduct to govern relationships. have been approved by an executive decision-maker specifically tasked with determining the legitimacy of any decision. For government we suggest a much more explicit code of conduct to govern relationships but, as with the European Commission’s code, this code should emphasise the positive rather than the negative and alongside this positive positioning of lobbying, governments’ should take the opportunity to acknowledge the contribution of enterprise to an effective democracy alongside the rights of organisations to be heard when important decisions are being taken. We argue that making dealings transparent will break the cycle of cynicism and mistrust. If organisa- tions believe that their interactions with government are legitimate and potentially beneficial to the economy, why hide this? The initial response may be negative, but additional confidence-building activity such as the appointment of a non-executive ethicist may go some way to reducing cynical responses. This does not absolve government of responsibility for establishing clearer and more comprehensive guidelines for relationship engagement. Appropriate regulation will also help address concerns regarding whether organisations are equipped to judge what is, or is not, ethically appropriate behaviour – an issue our suggestion of getting an ethicist on board goes some ways to addressing from a different direction. WIN-WIN-WIN We believe that the outcome of embracing these ideas would be: win – better decisions are taken: government gains access to the information and expertise it would otherwise be unable to obtain or would take too long to develop; win – business can focus upon business: with a greater acceptance of the legitimate Dr Howard Viney strategic option of lobbying Open University Business organisations can focus upon School, UK operating effectively with the Dr Howard Viney is senior reduced risk of reputational lecturer in strategic managedamage currently associment at the Open University Business School, UK. ated with lobbying; and win – society benefits from a more effective democratic process and policies which are transparent and hopefully more efficient. We suggest that there are benefits from recognising that members of the public are able to appreciate the realities of Dr Paul Baines public policy decision makCranfield School of ing as well as the motivations Management, UK of organisational action – an Dr Paul Baines is professor of improvement in the political political marketing at Crandiscourse and a reduction in field School of Management, UK and has worked on varithe extent of suspicion surous communication research rounding the motives of all projects for UK government departments. involved. 04/2013 COMMUNICATION DIRECTOR 27