Semi—subsistence farming: a remnant from the past or a provider of public goods and a cultural asset? Sophia Davidova, School of Economics, University of Kent Context • • • The last two enlargements brought millions of small farms into the EU, most of which semi-subsistence (SSFs): – The persistence of SSFs has been explained by market failure and particularly high transaction costs – SSFs market integration and competitiveness are low – The lack of engagement in markets is seen as an impediment to economic growth and contributor to rural poverty (World Bank, 2007); BUT – SSFs populate rural areas often the most fragile ones; maintain local rural communities; provide cultural and environmental services (public goods) Similar issues affect all small farms (they may or may not be SSFs but are equally important for rural areas) Therefore, the current situation and the effects of structural change on the survival (or disappearance) of SSFs and small farms in general are of great significance for rural development A visual context: where can we see the importance of SFs and SSFs? Landscape HNV pastures Farmers markets, local food Traditional lifestyle, cultural heritage Outline • • • • • Definitional and measurement issues Main barriers to market participation SSFs role in rural development Typologies Policy implications This presentation benefits from the collaborative work on EU FP6 SCARLED project together with L. Fredriksson (University of Kent) and M Gorton (University of Newcastle) Concepts • What are SSFs? How to define these farms? • Lack of consensus on definition (Barnett et al. 1996; Kostov and Lingard, 2004) • Production versus consumption approach • Wharton (1970) use 50% of output sold as threshold for classifying farms as mainly subsistence /semi-subsistence or mainly commercial – Farms placed on a continuum from 0 to 100% depending on proportion of output sold – Extremes are purely subsistence and purely commercial operations • Lack of adequate data. Some evidence from EU Farm Structural Survey, however not comprehensive Measurement issues • Three main criteria: – Physical measure - e.g. UAA: McConnell and Dillon (1997) suggest 0.5-2.0 ha of cultivated land as a good indicator of semisubsistence farms – In the EU for policy purposes small farms are defined as <5ha – BUT land fertility and farm specialisation vary – Economic size (ESU) – less than 1 ESU (SFs); 2-8 ESU – small (SSFs?) (Eurostat) – Market participation – the share of output sold -Council Regulation EC No. 1698/2005: SSFs are “agricultural holdings which produce primarily for their own consumption and also market a proportion of their output” • Other e.g. standard labour requirement (SLR) used in the UK which allows to differentiate between hobby farms with SLR less than 0.5 person-years; part-time farmers 0.5-<1 person-years; small fulltime - 1<2 person-years The importance of SFs, SSFs and small farms within farm structure Some aggregate facts, EU-27 in 2007 Number of holdings (million) Share in the total number of holdings(%) UAA (million ha) Share in total UAA (%) ESU <1 ESU 1<8 0<5 ha 6.4 4.7 9.6 46.6 34.4 70.4 11.7 27.2 14.4 6.8 15.8 8.4 Total 13.7 100.0 172.5 100.0 Calculations based on Eurostat Agriculture database, FSS data Measurement (cont) Market participation criterion: Share of holdings producing primarily for their own consumption and the share of UAA they manage, 2005 and 2007 (excluding holdings <1 ESU) What are the barriers to market participation specific for SSF? • Transaction costs (Goetz, 1992; Swinnen, 2005; Gorton et al. 2006) • Costs of gaining certification and meeting standards – public and private (Dries et al. 2004; Reardon, 2006) • Non-pecuniary benefits (hobby farming) (Holloway, 2002) – Subsistence mindedness (Mellor, 1970) Role of small and SSFs in agriculture and rural development • At least three important functions: – Buffer against poverty - safety net – Basis for diversification and pluriactivity in rural areas – Provision of environmental public goods; maintaining rural traditions and cultural heritage Contribution of the value of non-marketed output (subsistence production) to household income (%) Households Households below above poverty line poverty line Bulgaria Hungary Poland Romania Slovenia 41.7 19.2 39.0 58.5 23.1 24.5 5.7 22.7 31.5 9.0 Country average Households shifted from below to above poverty line 29.0 7.6 24.2 32.9 12.5 17.1 3.5 7.4 2.8 8.4 Source: SCARLED Diversification • The West European experience shows that if small farms are to survive, they need to decrease their reliance on farm incomes and combine their farming with diversification of their activity or with off-farm employment • Normally it is thought that diversified enterprises require capital or rich farm assets which are beyond the reach of SSFs, particularly in NMS • However there are several success stories of small farms’ diversification Diversification examples Environmental and cultural benefits stemming from SFs and SSFs •SSFs support HNV farmland (Birdlife International, 2008) •Lower stocking densities and lower use of chemical inputs support higher biodiversity Environmental and cultural benefits stemming from SFs and SSFs (cont) • Case study Romania (Page, 2010): – SFs and SSFs are associated with the management of large areas of semi-natural grassland – This forms the basis for low intensity HNV livestock farming – Due to their small size and mixture of grazing and field crops, SFs and SSFs contribute to a landscape rich in biodiversity HOWEVER – It is difficult for policies to reach this group despite their importance for environmental benefits as most of SFs are not registered – In the Romanian System of National Accounts these farms are located in the sector ‘non-observed/non-registered economy’ How to maintain and enhance the delivery of public goods by SSFs in EU? • What incentives should be in place for SSF to continue the provision of environmental public goods? • How can policies compensate the smallest farms (often not registered) for the provision of public goods? Is it necessary? • How can policy CAP/national help decrease the barriers to diversification faced by SSFs and small farmers? • Two major issues: – Despite the CAP, evidence from various Member States indicates that after the accession to the EU those exiting the sector were disproportionally weighted to small farms – SSFs are not homogenous Structural Change: Spain Economic size (ESU) <2 2-8 8-6 16-40 40-100 >100 1989 % farms % SGM 63.4 9.5 24.3 23.1 7.4 18.9 3.7 20.4 0.9 12.9 0.3 15.1 1999 % farms 47.1 28.6 11.0 9.1 3.2 1.1 % SGM 3.8 12.9 13.4 23.9 20.1 25.9 Source: Iraizoz (2008) Structural Change: Poland Farm size (ha) 0-1 1.01-2 2.01-5 5.01-10 10.01-15 15.01-20 20.01-50 > 50 ha Total >1 ha Source: Wołek (2009) Index 1996 = 100 2005=100 2002 2005 2007 2007 111,8 94,3 81,9 70,2 93,7 127,7 192,1 94,2 96,7 87,6 74,5 77,2 86,2 131,3 210,8 87,3 91,4 92,0 76,8 76,7 86,8 136,7 270,8 88,6 81,5 94,6 105,0 103,1 99,4 100,6 104,1 128,5 101,4 Typologies of farmers: EU-15 (Hawkins et al., 1993) 24 areas in 12 EU countries Typologies of farmers: NMS, Davidova et al (2009) 15 regions in 5 NMS Policy implications – can one-size-fit all? • SSFs are heterogeneous • Most are small, run by older farmers who are either unwilling to change or intend to disengage from farming altogether • However, there is also a significant minority of SFFs who are seeking to develop the business, either agriculturally or through some form of diversification • There is also a group tending to become more reliant on off-farm income • And there are hobby farmers who will hardly respond to any policy measures or market signals • Are the policy needs of different types of SSF different? Policy Implications (2): how to decrease the barriers to market participation specific for SSFs and small farmers • The benefits of SFs and SSFs can hardly be seen in measures of agricultural productivity and efficiency • However they are important providers of environmental, cultural and community benefits valued by European citizens • Current CAP is not effective for SSFs and small farms • Problems: – i) difficulty to identify them as a large fraction are not registered – ii) prohibitive transaction costs to reach millions of tiny SFs and SSFs – iii) difficulty to reach them by policies requiring formal co-operation due to farmers’ reluctance to co-operate – iv) eligibility thresholds for some CAP measures – v) need to fill forms and/or develop business plans Examples of difficulties to reach SSFs/small farms by CAP measures: Pillar I Minimum thresholds Minimum thresholds Value Value € Ha 400 2 200 0,5 Belgium Bulgaria Czech Republic Denmark Germany Estonia Ireland Greece Spain France Italy Finland Sweden UK 200 300 300 100 200 400 300 300 400 200 200 200 € Cyprus Latvia Lithuania Luxemburg Hungary Malta Netherlands Austria Poland Portugal Romania Slovenia Slovakia 5 5 4 3 3 0,4 2 4 0,5 3 4 5 Ha 300 100 100 300 200 500 500 200 200 200 200 300 200 0,3 1 1 4 0,3 0,1 2 2 0,5 0,3 0,3 0,3 2 Source: DG Agri e.g. in Romania around 3 million SSFs are not eligible for SAPS as they do not fulfil the eligibility criteria (Guirca, 2008) ha Average size of SAPS beneficiaries (ha) 200 180 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 186 186 165 159 146 148 127 120 10 11 24 42 8 8 2004 2005 2006 2007 2004 2005 2006 2007 2005 2005 2005 2007 2007 2008 Czech Slovakia PL LI HU BG Source: Davidova, 2008 e.g. in Bulgaria SAPS beneficiaries only 20% of the total No of holdings reported by Eurostat Farm Structure Survey RO Examples of difficulties to reach SSFs/small farms by CAP measures: Pillar 2 Target for the number of farms to benefit from the measure ‘Support to SSFs undergoing restructuring’ Target number as % of all farms between 1 and 8 ESUs (2007) Bulgaria Hungary Latvia Lithuania Romania 19.7 2.7 6.9 4.7 9.0 Key policy questions for discussion • • • • • • There are several issues concerning the design and delivery of CAP Pillar 1 and Pillar 2 measures relevant to SSF and small farms Is there a case to define specific policy measures/policy packages to facilitate SSF market participation/commercialisation? Is there a justification not to pursue commercialisation but to pay (compensate) SSFs for the delivery of public goods? If the answer is yes, HOW? – New CAP Pillar? New RD Axis? Some social/cohesion RD package for SSFs and small farms? Co-operation between small farmers is central to improve their access to markets but SSFs, particularly in the NMS, are reluctant to cooperate: – Reported in case studies on Hungary, Romania, Poland In view of this, should networking be given a high priority for SSF, and if so, what forms would be the most effective? (so far very low interest in the support to producer groups in NMS)