Classical Model: Practice Problems Key Intermediate Macroeconomics John T. Dalton Question 1 a) ∂U (Y D ,LS ) ∂Y D = b) ∂U (Y D ,LS ) ∂LS 1 = − 1−L S c) ∂Y S ∂LD 1 YD =4 d) A competitive equilibrium in the classical model is prices (p∗ , w ∗) and allocations (LD∗ , LS∗ , Y D∗ , Y S∗ ) such that the following conditions hold: 1) Given prices (p∗ , w ∗ ), the representative household solves max U(Y D , LS ) Y D ,LS s.t. p∗ Y D = w ∗ LS 2) Given prices (p∗ , w ∗ ), the representative firm solves max p∗ Y S − w ∗ LD s.t. Y S ,LD Y S = f (LD ) 3) Markets clear Y S∗ = Y D∗ LS∗ = LD∗ e) Labor demand is derived from the firm’s problem. max pY S − wLD s.t. Y S ,LD 1 Y S = 4LD ⇒ max 4pLD − wLD LD L = 4pLD − wLD ∂L = 4p − w = 0 ∂LD w =4 p This is an elastic labor demand curve, so w∗ p∗ = 4. Labor supply is derived from the household’s problem. max ln(Y D ) + ln(1 − LS ) Y D ,LS s.t. pY D = wLS wLS ⇒ max ln + ln(1 − LS ) p LS wLS + ln(1 − LS ) L = ln p p w ∂L 1 = − =0 S S ∂L wL p 1 − LS Solving for LS , 1 2 This is an inelastic labor supply curve, so LS∗ = 12 . Using the market LS = clearing condition for the labor market, LD∗ = LS∗ = 21 . Using the firm’s production function, Y S∗ = 4(LD∗ ) = 4( 12 ) = 2. Finally, using the market clearing condition for the goods market, Y D∗ = Y S∗ = 2. 2 The competitive equilibrium for this example is the price allocations LS∗ = 1 , LD∗ 2 = 1 , Y S∗ 2 w∗ p∗ = 4 and = 2, and Y D∗ = 2. f) π ∗ = p∗ Y S∗ − w ∗ LD∗ = (1)(2) − (4)( 12 ) = 0 g) See Figure 1 below. h) p = MS kY D = 2 YD i) Using the aggregate supply curve, Y S∗ = Y D∗ = 2, which means p∗ = 1. Question 2 a) ∂U (Y D ,LS ) ∂Y D =1 b) ∂U (Y D ,LS ) ∂LS = −LS c) ∂Y S ∂LD = 5 − LD d) pY D = wLS (1 − τ ) e) 1 max Y D − (LS )2 D S 2 Y ,L ⇒ max LS L= s.t. pY D = wLS (1 − τ ) w S 1 L (1 − τ ) − (LS )2 p 2 1 w S L (1 − τ ) − (LS )2 p 2 ∂L w = (1 − τ ) − LS = 0 S ∂L p 3 2 2 = LS = w (1 − τ ) p f) max pY S − wLD Y S ,LD s.t. 1 Y S = 5LD − (LD )2 2 1 ⇒ max p 5LD − (LD )2 − wLD 2 LD 1 L = p 5LD − (LD )2 − wLD 2 ∂L = p5 − pLD − w = 0 ∂LD LD = 5 − w p g) Using the market clearing condition in the labor market, LS∗ = LD∗ w∗ w∗ (1 − τ ) = 5 − p∗ p∗ w∗ 5 = p∗ 2−τ h) Using the labor supply curve, L∗ = LS∗ = w∗ (1 p∗ 1−τ − τ ) = 5 2−τ OR Using the labor demand curve, L∗ = LD∗ = 5 − i) Real Tax Revenue = w∗ ∗ Lτ p∗ 4 w∗ p∗ 2−τ = 5 2−τ − 5 2−τ 1−τ = 5 2−τ j) Plugging in the equilibrium values for L∗ and Revenue = 5 5 1−τ τ 2−τ 2−τ = w∗ p∗ derived above, Real Tax (1−τ ) 25 (2−τ τ. )2 k) “Supply-siders” argued the government should cut taxes to increase revenue. They believed U.S. tax rates were such that we were on the “wrong side” of the Laffer Curve, that is, to the right of the tax rate which generates the maximum amount of revenue. Question 3 a) The balanced government budget shows total tax revenue equals total expenditure: τ pY S = T . b) 1 max Y D − (LS )2 2 Y D ,LS ⇒ max LS L= s.t. pY D = wLS + T 1 w S T L + − (LS )2 p p 2 w S T 1 L + − (LS )2 p p 2 ∂L w = − LS = 0 ∂LS p LS = w p c) max (1 − τ )pY S − wLD Y S ,LD s.t. Y S = 3LD ⇒ max(1 − τ )p3LD − wLD LD 5 L = (1 − τ )p3LD − wLD ∂L = (1 − τ )p3 − w = 0 ∂LD w = 3(1 − τ ) p d) Using the labor demand curve, w∗ p∗ = 3(1 − τ ). Plugging the equilibrium real wage into the labor supply curve gives LS∗ = 3(1 − τ ). Market clearing in the labor market implies LD∗ = LS∗ = 3(1 − τ ). Plugging the equilibrium quantity of labor demanded into the firm’s production function gives Y S∗ = 9(1 − τ ). Market clearing in the goods market then implies Y D∗ = Y S∗ = 9(1 − τ ). Notice, the goods market equilibrium can also be solved through the household’s budget constraint: pY D = wLS + T, which we know also holds with equality in equilibrium, so we have the rewritten budget constraint Y D∗ = w ∗ S∗ T L + ∗. p∗ p Using the government budget constraint and plugging in the equilibrium values for the real wage and labor supplied gives the following: Y D∗ = 3(1 − τ )3(1 − τ ) + τ Y S∗ , which simplifies to Y D∗ = 9(1 − τ ). 6 e) See Figure 2 below. Household consumption in equilibrium, Y D∗ , increases after the government eliminates the tax on total revenue. Eliminating the tax shifts the labor demand curve of the firm outward, which increases the equilibrium quantity of labor demanded, LD∗ . Using the firm’s production function, output supplied in equilibrium, Y S∗ , also increases. Through the market clearing condition in the goods market, Y D∗ must also increase. 7 Figure 1: Aggregate Supply Curve P AS S* Y =2 8 Y Figure 2: Eliminating the Tax on Firm Revenue ZS /6 /' /IJ' <6 /IJ' /' / <6 <IJ6 /IJ' /' /' 9