Proceedings of the 3rd Annual Beaufort Marine Socio-Economic Workshop Organised by SEMRU (Socio-Economic Marine Research Unit), National University of Ireland, Galway in association with the Marine Institute, Ireland Proceedings of the 3rd Annual Beaufort Marine Socio-Economic Workshop Friday 11th November, Aras Moyola, National University of Ireland, Galway, Co. Galway Organised by SEMRU (Socio-Economic Marine Research Unit), J.E. Cairnes School of Business and Economics, National University of Ireland, Galway. Compiled by: Stephen Hynes (SEMRU, National University of Ireland, Galway) Copies can be downloaded from: http://www.nuigalway.ie/semru/documents/beaufortworkshop2.pdf Table of Contents Introduction .............................................................................................................. 2 Stephen Hynes, SEMRU, NUI Galway Valuing Impacts to Recreation from the 2007 San Francisco Bay Oil Spill................... 3 Eric English, Stratus Consulting Inc. The Role of Marketing in Driving the Sustainable Consumption of Seafood ............... 5 Judith Kildow, Centre for the Blue Economy, Monterey Institute for International Studies The Potential for an Irish Maritime Transportation Cluster:An Input-Output Analysis7 Karyn Morrissey, School of Environmental Sciences, University of Liverpool Valuing the Dead Sea and Peaceful Cooperation in the Middle East .......................... 9 Alberto Longo, Anil Markandya and Ramon Ortiz, School of Biological Sciences, Gibson Institute for Land, Food and the Environment, Queen's University of Belfast The Role of Marketing in Driving the Sustainable Consumption of Seafood ............... 9 Ann Walsh, Department of Marketing and SEMRU, NUI Galway Site Choices in Recreational Demand: A Matter of Utility Maximization or Regret Minimization? ......................................................................................................... 10 Marco Boeri, Alberto Longo, Edel Doherty, Stephen Hynes Coral-Fisheries Interactions in Bioeconomic Modelling – Comparing Norway and Iceland’s Redfish Fisheries ....................................................................................... 12 Naomi S. Foley & Claire W. Armstrong, Norwegian Fishery College, University of Tromsø, Norway Valuing Marine Environmental Characteristics Associated with Changes to the EU Bathing Water Directive .......................................................................................... 14 Stephen Hynes, Caitriona Scully and Alphonsus Browne, SEMRU, NUI Galway Port and Shipping Data as Economic Indicators ....................................................... 16 Fergal Curtin, Shipping Market Analyst, Irish Maritime Development Office, Marine Institute Valuing the Non-Market Benefits of the WFD Implementation in Ireland ................ 18 Daniel Norton, Stephen Hynes, Edel Doherty SEMRU, NUI Galway; Cathal Buckley, Teagasc; Danny Campbell, Queens University The Impact of Cost Uncertainty on the Feasibility of Wave Energy Conversion Devices and the Implications for Policy ................................................................................ 20 Niall Farrell, SEMRU, NUI Galway Another Collective Tragedy? The Case of the Killary Mussel Farming Co-operative . 22 Peter Cush, School of Political Science and Sociology and SEMRU, NUI Galway Annex 1 ................................................................................................................... 24 Annex 2 ................................................................................................................... 25 1 Introduction Stephen Hynes, SEMRU, NUI Galway Introduction On Wednesday the 17th November, SEMRU (the Socio-Economic Marine Research Unit) in association with the Marine Institute held the third annual Beaufort Marine Socio-Economic Workshop. This annual workshop is an opportunity for researchers and policy makers in the area of marine socio-economics, working in Ireland, to get together to meet and discuss their on-going work. The J.E. Cairns School of Business and Economics, NUI Galway hosted this year’s event. The workshop was divided up into 3 sessions. The topic of the morning session was “The Irish Ocean Economy: National and Sectoral Perspectives”. The second session was dedicated to “Marine Ecosystem Service Valuation” and the evening session showcased the research being conducted by the SEMRU PhD students. Speakers on the day included Dr. Marco Boeri and Dr. Alberto Longo of Queens University, Belfast who presented the results of a random regret model for water based recreationalists and a CVM model related to ecosystem services in the Dead Sea, respectively. Dr. Eric English of Stratus Consulting, Colorado spoke on valuing oil spill impacts in marine environments while Dr. Judith Kildow of the National Ocean Economics Program in the US presented a paper on the US Ocean and Coastal Economies. There were 9 presenters on the day from both Irish and international academic institutions. SEMRU and the Beaufort Socio-Economic Award This annual workshop is held as part of the work program of the Beaufort Socio-Economic Research Award. SEMRU, based in NUI, Galway was set up though the commitment in funding from the Beaufort Award under the Marine Research SubProgramme of the National Development Plan 2007–2013. Personnel from a range of university departments are actively involved in the Beaufort Socio-Economic Research Award Work Program. These include members of the Department of Economics, the Department of Marketing, the Department of Management and the Department of Political Science & Sociology. Other research institutes across Ireland and the UK also collaborate on projects within SEMRU. These include the Rural Economy Research Centre, Teagasc, the Irish Marine Institute and the Department of Economics, Stirling University, Scotland. Three PhD students are currently funded under the Award with a further 3 PhD students within the Unit. There are currently 16 active research projects within the unit. The main research focus of the unit is on the economic importance of coastal and off-shore marine environments. This involves examining the economic utility of the marine environment (e.g. transportation, recreation) and ecological value (e.g. fisheries, aquaculture) derived from the productivity of associated ecosystems. The coastal and contiguous marine environment surrounding Ireland and the EU in general provides the geographical focus for the research of the unit. Consideration of the human dimension in the management of marine ecosystems is also a critical component of all research projects within the unit. Unit projects include the collection and monitoring of socio-economic marine data for Ireland, the estimation of participation rates and value of marine-related recreation activities and an analysis of market orientation, competitiveness and innovation of firms in the Irish seafood sector. The unit has once again been successful in the last 12 month in getting EU INTERREG IV, EU FP7 and EPA funding to carry out further research in the areas of marine economic valuation in the Atlantic area, assessing the preferences of fishermen for fisheries management options and estimating the economic value of a “water related features” (see www.nuigalway.ie/semru for further information on these projects and other activities of the unit). Given one of the main aims of the Beaufort Award is to build marine socio-economic research capacity in Ireland, this third workshop was once again a means of finding out what others in the marine economic research community are working on. The exchange of knowledge in the area of marine socio-economics is of benefit not only to the different research institutes but also marine policy makers. In what follows, the presentations given on the day of the workshop are reviewed in two page summaries. 2 Valuing Impacts to Recreation from the 2007 San Francisco Bay Oil Spill Eric English, Stratus Consulting Inc. Introduction On November 7th, 2007, in a thick fog, the Cosco Busan container ship struck a concrete piling of the Oakland Bay Bridge and released 56,000 gallons of oil into San Francisco Bay. Over the next few days, tidal waters flushed the oil in and out of the harbor and winds and currents carried the oil up and down the coast. Over 100 miles of coastal beaches and marshes were ultimately contaminated. In addition to establishing liability for cleanup costs and private financial losses, the United States Oil Pollution Act of 1990 requires compensation for nonmonetary public losses associated with oil-spill impacts to fish, wildlife, and habitats, and to human-use ecosystem services such as recreation. Experts working for local, state and federal agencies evaluated impacts to habitats and wildlife and determined the appropriate resource restoration actions to compensate for ecological impacts. Experts also estimated the lost value of recreational activity at beaches and other shoreline areas following the spill. With over 15 million recreation visits in the San Francisco Bay Area each year, and with a substantial decline in recreation following the spill, recreation impacts formed the largest component of damages in the Cosco Busan case. The final quantification of $18.8 million in damages for recreational losses was the largest such claim in United States history at the time. In this article we report on lessons learned about measuring recreational losses and defending a travel-cost valuation model in the context of potential litigation. The study of recreation losses for the Cosco Busan incident relied on counts of visitors at recreation sites as well as a telephone survey of Bay Area residents about their recreation behavior and response to the spill. The simultaneous use of onsite counts and a general population survey revealed some potential discrepancies between data collected using the two different modes, but also indicated that certain results, such as the estimated percentage decline in recreation due to the spill, were robust across data collection modes. The telephone survey data were also used to estimate a valuation model of Bay Area shoreline recreation. The model incorporated several features common in oil spill assessments over the last 20 years, such as the use of alternative-specific constants to represent site characteristics and the calculation of per-trip values that varied according to the extent and severity of spill impacts at various stages of the spill. The vulnerability of survey results to criticisms about low response rates and apparent inconsistencies in survey responses are also discussed. Estimating lost trips A telephone survey to assess losses from the Cosco Busan oil spill was administered beginning in June, 2008. The telephone survey was administered to Bay Area residents using a random sample of landline telephone numbers. The objective of the shoreline recreation survey was to estimate the number of recreation trips lost due to the Cosco Busan oil spill and to develop a travel-cost model for estimating the value of lost trips. In order to estimate the number of lost trips, respondents were asked whether they went less often to any shoreline sites because of the spill and if so, they were asked to name the sites. Respondents were then asked how many fewer trips, in total, they took to these sites because of the spill. Finally, respondents were asked whether they went to alternative sites instead, and if so, which sites and how many times. Information about the decline in a respondent’s trips to affected sites was obtained for each of the months following the spill, up to the point when a respondent reported their recreation was no longer affected. Information from the telephone survey was used to estimate the percentage decline in recreation trips. To estimate total lost trips, the percentage decline was multiplied by an estimate of total trips to San Francisco Bay Area beaches derived from onsite surveys. The onsite surveys were conducted during November 2008, and predictions of the number of visitors throughout the year were developed based on an estimated relationship between daily weather and beach visitation. The advantage of the telephone survey included the ability to account for spill effects throughout a lengthy period of impact without the high cost of onsite data collection sustained over many months. The advantage of onsite data collection was the 3 elimination of most potential error associated with nonresponse bias, since information is collected largely by visual observation. The value of a lost trip The valuation model for the Cosco Busan assessment was specified using alternative specific constants in a repeated-logit specification (Morey et al. 1993). Since recreation impacts from a spill often last less than a year or two, it is usually feasible to compare recreation activity during the spill to recreation activity at the same sites either before or after the spill. Since spill impacts are evaluated by comparing the same set of sites at different points in time, the only site characteristic that the researcher must value is the impact of the spill itself. Alternative specific constants can be used to capture the combined value of all other characteristics, which can be assumed to remain the same under spill and non-spill conditions. Logit models are the most widely used valuation model in the field of recreation demand (Smith and Phaneuf 2005) and have been widely used in applied work, including many oil spill assessments (Hausman et al. 1995; English 2008). The valuation model was estimated using information from the telephone survey on the origin and destination of recreation trips taken by Bay Area residents. The model estimate of the value per trips ranged from $22.65 in November 2007 to $8.90 in June 2008. The decline in value throughout the spillimpact period reflects the greater availability of substitute sites as the number of areas impacted by oil declined. Defensibility of the survey and model When valuing oil spill impacts on behalf of public trustees, the data collected and analysis developed must withstand the scrutiny of opposing parties and potentially a judge or magistrate, if the case is ultimately litigated. The adversarial context highlights any vulnerabilities of a study, particularly those vulnerabilities that are simple to understand or appear to contradict a commonsense understanding of what people value and the choices they make. For the survey, the key vulnerabilities involved contradictions, apparent or real, between responses to different questions by a given individual, or between responses by different individuals. For the model, the key vulnerabilities involved complex economic concepts that cannot be explained simply and intuitively, and aspects of the model for which a common practice is not firmly established in the literature. References English, E. (2008), Recreation Nonparticipation as Choice Behavior Rather than Statistical Outcome. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 90(1):186-196. Hausman, J.A., G.K. Leonard, and D. McFadden. (1995), A Utility Consistent, Combined Discrete Choice and Count Data Model: Assessing Recreational Use Losses due to Natural Resource Damage. Journal of Public Economics 56:1-30. Morey, E.R., R.D. Rowe, and M. Watson, (1993), A Repeated Nested-Logit Model of Atlantic Salmon Fishing. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 75(3):578-592. Phaneuf, D., and K. Smith. (2005), “Recreation Demand Models.” In K. Maeler and J. Vincent, eds. Handbook of Environmental Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier, pp. 671-751. 4 The Role of Marketing in Driving the Sustainable Consumption of Seafood Judith Kildow, Centre for the Blue Economy, Monterey Institute for International Studies Introduction The field of marine policy and coastal management began in the early 1970s in the US, following the release of a Congressionally mandated study, The Stratton Commission Report (Stratton Commission, 1969). It was partially fuelled by the growing environmental movement and partially by growing attention to the economic possibilities offered by US coasts and oceans. Striking a balance between developing the riches of the coast and oceans and protecting them so they remained healthy over time has dominated much of the policy world of the oceans for the past 50 years. economy of California’s ocean sector. There had been a few brief national studies on the US Ocean Economy (Pontecorvo, Giulio, et al, 1993) and the coastal economy, yet these were one-off efforts, establishing only a baseline year, and the beginnings of a methodology for building a long term database. However in 1999, Judith Kildow, then at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, began what has become The National Ocean Economics Program, currently part of the Center for the Blue Economy at the Monterey Institute for International Studies (www.oceaneconomics.org) The struggles between onshore and offshore development and environmental protection fuelled record-breaking legislative initiatives, creation of state and local coastal programs, and international and federal law of the sea actions. One would have thought that the health of the oceans and coasts would have dramatically improved. However by the mid-nineties, the field of marine policy and law, and studies by resource economists focusing on the oceans indicated that problems were increasing, not decreasing along certain shorelines. Shorelines were becoming more unstable, pollution was still problematic, estuaries were being filled, depriving society of the wealth of services they had provided, however there was only anecdotal evidence to prove that things were not improving, not the hard evidence used by natural scientists and engineers. Figure 1. Aerial View of Monetary Bay What engineers and scientists used to build theory and which formed the foundations for their fields was missing from the social sciences, especially marine policy and coastal management. There were no time series of quantitative information that could indicate trends in human activities along the shore and their impacts on natural systems, only data about changing natural systems. In 1997, the state of California held one of its first California and the World Oceans Conferences in San Diego California. That conference and the report that followed included something quite revolutionary in the marine policy field: a report on the The National Ocean Economics Program With a research team including chief market economist, Professor Charles Colgan, regional economist from the University of Southern Maine, chief non-market economists, Professor Linwood Pendleton, and later Professor Jason Scorse, the program and its methodology has become a standard for other nations doing their own ocean or marine accounts. The goal of that program was to develop an accurate ocean and coastal economy time series, taking an ocean slice of the US national Income accounts. Those accounts had a history going back to 1933 when 5 they were established to help the US government track the US economy to avoid another 1929 depression. These accounts, albeit respected and the official economic activity accounting system in the US, were never intended to measure the ocean or coastal economies, so the NOEP took on the task to formulate a reliable set of measurements and legitimate categories of economic activity that fairly reflected the ocean and coastal economies for which users could have confidence. Over the past 12 years, the NOEP has become a reliable on-line queriable time series of information for users in more than 100 nations, tracking economic, natural resource and demographic activities along the US coast and in the coastal ocean. The NOEP website also provides 1) a non-market heavily annotated bibliography of reliable studies that reflect environmental and recreational values, that fall outside of the market place and are often neglected or undervalued, and 2) US government ocean expenditures, revealing the funds spent by agency over the years and as a portion of the US GDP. The structure of the NOEP The structure of the NOEP includes: 1) Annual Market Data consisting of the A) Ocean Economy, which uses four indicators – employment, earned wages, number of establishments, and Gross Domestic Product to track activities in six ocean dependent sectors: Maritime Transportation, Offshore Oil and Gas, Coastal Tourism, Coastal Construction, Ship and Boat Building, and Commercial Fishing. B) Coastal Economy, which uses the same indicators and tracks US Government-derived 12 Supersectors (all aspects of the economy), by geography: coastal zip codes, coastal counties, watershed counties, inland counties. 2) Natural Resources categories are A) Annual fisheries landings and values, and B) offshore oil and gas production and values. Ports and Cargo information are also available annually, by import and export categories of cargo, tonnage, and value and on a separate page. Value of Marine Economic Data The values derived from these accounts have been helpful in estimating losses from natural disasters such as Hurricane Katrina and unnatural ones like the Gulf Oil Spill. Knowing the value that the oceans and coasts contribute to the national economy has provided the US Congress with information to help them with programs and budgets for ocean agencies. And, knowing that the US coastal states contribute more than 83% of the US Gross Domestic Product and almost as large a percentage of jobs and wages, has given ocean and coastal resources a new importance in debates about conservation and preservation versus development along the nation’s coasts. Demographic and economic trends along the coastal and in the coastal ocean have helped planners and government officials for many years. We have learned that economic indicators are probably more important that demographic ones when seeking a better understanding of what is happening in these valuable and heavily populated areas. With the US and other developed nations now keeping ocean accounts and revealing their importance, increasing numbers of nations are anxious to do the same so they can protect their valuable resources from the onslaught of climate change impacts and natural disasters, and from unintended consequences of decisions made without proper information. References Luger, Michael, et al. (1993), The Economic Value of the Coastal Zone. Pontecorvo, Giulio, et al. (1980), Contribution of the Ocean Sector to the United States Economy. Science, May 30, 1980. 208(4447):1000‐1006. Stratton Commission. (1969), Our Nation and the Sea: A Plan for National Action. www.oceaneconomics.org 6 The Potential for an Irish Maritime Transportation Cluster: An InputOutput Analysis Karyn Morrissey, School of Environmental Sciences, University of Liverpool Introduction Central to world trade, the maritime transportation sector has undergone dramatic changes in the last two decades. On one hand, fuelled by the globalisation of economic activity the international shipping sector grew dramatically from the mid-1990s. However, the onset of the global recession in 2007 resulted in the sector presenting marked declines in output. Furthermore, structural changes in the market; including the flagging-out of vessels from high tax industrialised countries, the introduction of open ship registers, the hiring of seamen from low-wage countries, extended vessel lives, and relocation of ship building capacity from high-cost European countries to lower cost locations like South Korea and China has meant that most European maritime transportation sectors are in decline. In Ireland, acknowledging the need for direct measures to halt the decline in the shipping industry and to prevent the migration of the industry to alternative jurisdictions the Irish government introduced a range of policies aimed at stimulating the sector. Core to these policies is the development of a maritime transportation cluster. Broadly defined a cluster is a population of geographically concentrated and mutually related business units, associations and public organizations centred on a distinctive economic specialisation. In terms of developing industrial clusters, it is important to note that their formation is not `natural’, rather they are constructed by both scientists and policy makers. Thus, the first step in developing cluster policy involves identifying the cluster core. A cluster core should comprise of a sector that has a relative abundance of firms within a spatial concentration, has a relatively high share of national or regional output, has a high level of exports and most importantly have strong pre-existing linkages with related economic sectors (De Langan, 2002). Based on this set of criteria and using input-output (IO) analysis, this paper seeks to empirically examine the potential for cluster formation within the maritime transportation sector, based on the strength of its linkages with its support services and with the wider economy. Input-Output Analysis An important dimension of industry and cluster development is the nature or strength of buyer– supplier link. Sectors do not exist in a vacuum; rather they rely on other sectors for inputs (backward linkages) into their production process, while simultaneously selling their output to sectors (forward linkages) to generate profit. Backward linkage effects are strongly induced by industries with high intermediate input coefficients, such as manufacturing industries. Symmetrically, strong forward linkages are generally induced by the primary and material industries, whose outputs are used by other industries as intermediate goods. The intensity of inter-sectoral linkages between related industry groups has been highlighted as a key determinant of the technical and competitive progress of an economy. As such, the identification of sectors that display strong linkages is believed to be a useful planning tool for stimulating overall economic growth. Developed by the economist Wassily Leontief, IO models may be used to trace the entire backward (or forward) linkages within a sector. However, while the computation of linkages is straightforward within an IO framework and these tables are produced to document the national accounts of most countries, data limitations surrounding marine based sectors have meant that there has been limited use of IO analysis within the sector. However, recent research on devising and utilising a methodology to value the commercial value of the Irish marine resource found that the maritime transportation sector generated €697 million in turnover and provided €197 million in gross value added (GVA) to the Irish economy in 2007 (Morrissey et al., 2011). With regard to maritime support industries, there were approximately 200 commercial companies which provided a range of services to the shipping sector. These services included banking, finance, insurance, port services and management consultancy. In 2007, these industries generated approximately €292 million in turnover and €182 million in GVA and employed 1,100 individuals in FTEs. Geographically, the sector is spread along most of the coastline; however recent research has identified a specific cluster of maritime industries around the greater 7 Dublin area (Brett and Roe, 2010). Using this data this paper presents the strength of linkages within the maritime transportation sector. Results Using the IO methodology, it was found that the magnitude of the water transportation sectors backward linkage is €1.09. This implies that for every €1 produced within the water transportation sector, €0.09 is backward linked to its direct and indirect upstream suppliers. Four cents of this €0.09 belongs to the water transportation sectors direct suppliers and €0.05 belongs to its indirect suppliers (e.g. the suppliers of its direct suppliers). Continuing the analysis it was found that the sector has high backwards linkages (excluding itself) with auxiliary transportation services, computer and related services, maritime specific auxiliary transportation services (these services include berthing, liner and port services and facilities), financial intermediation services, post and telecommunications, insurance and pension, petroleum and other manufacturing products and motor fuel and vehicle trade and repair. These results indicate that for the maritime transportation sector the most important input suppliers are within the professional service sector. In terms of forward linkages maritime transportation has a forward linkage greater than one (120). This implies that every €1 produced by the maritime transportation sector is forward linked to €0.20 to the production of the sectors direct and indirect downstream demanders. In detail, for €1 of the production of water transportation services, €0.49 is sold directly for final consumption, including €0.08 for local consumption and €0.41 for exports. The rest €0.20, are bought by the water transportation sectors downstream demanders. and beverages (2), motor fuel and vehicle trade and repair (2) and services auxiliary to financial intermediation (2). It was further found that the sector was an important input supplier to four of the five sectors with the highest turnover in 2007, construction (€47.5 billion), wholesale trade (€20.8 billion), financial intermediation (€20.2 billion) and food and beverages (€19.1 billion). It was also an important input supplier to two of the five sectors with the highest exports in 2007, (€13.9 billion) and wholesale trade (€9.2 billion). Discussion The main objective for developing cluster policies is to improve the business environment, capabilities, and performance of local firms in targeted industries. It is within this context, that Irish public policy in the maritime transportation sector is focused on the development of a maritime transportation cluster. This cluster would include shipping operations at its core and with potential linkages to high value added, technological based professional services in areas such as banking, law, maritime commerce, ship finance and insurance. Using input-output analysis, it was found that the maritime transportation sector had the second highest backward linkage and highest forward linkage in the Irish economy in 2007. The sector also demonstrated strong linkages to the best performing sectors in the overall Irish economy. Based on these results there is a clear rationale for the development of an Irish maritime transportation sector. References Brett, V., and Roe, M. (2010), The potential for the clustering of the maritime transport sector in the Greater Dublin Region, Maritime Policy & Management, 37(1), 1-16. Morrissey, K., O’Donoghue, C., Hynes, S. (2011), Quantifying the value of multi-sectoral marine commercial activity in Ireland. Marine Policy, 35(5), 721-727. De Langen, P. W., (2002), Clustering and performance: the case of maritime clustering in The Netherlands, Maritime Policy & Management, 29(3), 209-221. Examining the sectors with which the maritime transportation sector has high forward linkages, (excluding itself) it was found that the sector has high forward linkages with wholesale trade (15), post and telecommunications (10), construction work (10), auxiliary transportation services (6), hotel and restaurant services (3), fishing (2), food 8 Valuing the Dead Sea and Peaceful Cooperation in the Middle East Alberto Longo, Anil Markandya and Ramon Ortiz, School of Biological Sciences, Gibson Institute for Land, Food and the Environment, Queen's University of Belfast This paper provides the results of a payment card Contingent Valuation study carried out surveying 9,047 respondents in 18 countries to assess the non-use value of protecting the Dead Sea from further decline and to promote peaceful cooperation between Israelis and Palestinians. The paper also explores issues of ordering when using several contingent valuation questions in the same questionnaire. The Role of Marketing in Driving the Sustainable Consumption of Seafood Ann Walsh, Department of Marketing and SEMRU, NUI Galway Being market oriented centres on having an in-depth understanding of the customer, in order to meet or exceed the needs of the target market better than the competition. The academic literature states that market orientation is a critical determinant of business performance and competitive advantage. With the global population set to rise to 9bn (from 7bn today) by 2050 and many of the earth’s natural resources under threat, the issue of sustainable food production and consumption has moved to the top of the political agenda internationally. Marketers in the US point to a segment of consumers who practice LOHAS – an acronym for ‘lifestyles of health and sustainability.’ One organisation that tracks this group estimates that they make up about 16% of the adults in the US, or 35 million people and rising. There is a lot of evidence to suggest that this segment of the market is growing internationally. Hence, consumers are driving food markets and are demanding food production to be more sustainable. Hence this presentation focuses on sustainability from the perspective of sustainable consumption, more specifically on “The Role of the Consumer in Driving Sustainable Consumption of Seafood”. 9 Site Choices in Recreational Demand: A Matter of Utility Maximization or Regret Minimization? Marco Boeri1, Alberto Longo1, Edel Doherty2, Stephen Hynes2 1.School of Biological Sciences, Gibson Institute for Land, Food and the Environment, Queen's University of Belfast 2. Socio-Economic Marine Research Unit, J.E. Cairns School of Business and Economics, National University of Ireland, Galway Introduction The use value of recreational activities of bathing, boating, fishing, hiking, camping, kayaking, horseback riding, and cycling within natural resource systems such as beaches, rivers, lakes, parks, and mountains has been widely investigated using the travel cost model. After Hotelling’s (1947) intuitive recreation demand model, and initial works by Clawson (1959), Trice and Wood (1958), and Burt and Brewer (1971), Hanemann (1978) presents the first application of the Random Utility Model (RUM) to analyse the demand for recreation when users have to choose among several alternative sites to visit. Since then, the RUM has been widely used to model the demand for recreation. On a given choice occasion, the Random Utility multinomial logit model (RU-MNL) models the sitechoice of one out of a number of alternative sites, as a function of attributes of the site, and central to its application, it assumes that a user visits the site that gives him/her the highest utility (Haab and McConnell, 2002). As it is widely acknowledged, the RUM’s popularity is mainly due to its strong economic foundations, its conceptual elegance and its formal tractability. Many RUM based models have closed-form formulations for choice probabilities, and most can be easily coded and estimated using standard discrete choicesoftware packages. However, some observers have pointed out that at least some of the assumptions behind the RUM might lack in behavioural realism. For example, research from psychology and consumer behaviour claims that decision-makers process information through limited capabilities and resources, trying to make the best possible choices within operational constraints (Ford et al, 1989). Various attempts have been made to relax the RUMNL assumptions, mostly by adapting the RUM, rather than by proposing completely new representations of the choice process. Resulting models, however, are, without exceptions, less parsimonious and less tractable than the RUM’s workhorse, the Mixed Multinomial Logit model. Furthermore, they generally require researchers to develop specific-purpose code for estimation. Methodology As an alternative to the RU-MNL, this paper employs the Random Regret Minimization Multinomial Logit model (RR-MNL). This is a relatively new choice paradigm that relaxes the assumption of utility maximization – and of fully compensatory decision makers – while remaining econometrically as parsimonious and tractable as its utilitarian counterpart, the RUM (Chorus, 2010). The RR-MNL model is built on the idea that, when choosing, individuals aim to minimize their regret rather than to maximize their utility – regret being defined as what one experiences when a nonchosen alternative performs better than a chosen one, on one or more attributes. The RR-MNL model implies semi-compensatory behaviour: improving an alternative in terms of an attribute on which it already performs well relative to other alternatives generates only small decreases in regret, whereas deteriorating to a similar extent the performance on another equally important attribute on which the alternative has a poor performance relative to other alternatives may generate substantial increases in regret. As a result, the extent to which a strong performance on one attribute can make up for a poor performance on another depends on the relative position of each alternative in the choice set. This choice set composition-effect, which has been well established empirically in the field of consumer choice (e.g. Kivetz et al., 2004), is called the compromise effect. This effect states that alternatives with an ‘in-between’ performance on all attributes, relative to the other alternatives in the choice set, are generally favoured by choicemakers over alternatives with a poor performance on some attributes and a strong performance on others. In this paper, we explore how the RR-MNL can be used to determine site-choice for recreational goods by modelling travel cost data elicited from a sample of kayakers in the Republic of Ireland. We further explore whether choices are driven by a 10 utility maximization or a regret minimization paradigm by running a binary logit model to explain the likelihood of the two decision choice paradigms using site visits and respondents characteristics as explanatory variables. To our knowledge, this is the first application of the RRMNL to a revealed preference dataset eliciting recreation site-choice. Furthermore, this is the first attempt to assess, at the choice level (as opposed to the overall model fit), which model, the RUMNL or the RR-MNL, better describes the decision process underlying each choice. This novel application of the model potentially reveals very useful information for policy makers interested in the management of recreational sites. This paper is also one of the first attempts to compute the Logsum based on RR-MNL and to compare it to the Logsum based on RU-MNL to assess the impacts of hypothetical changes to the quality of recreational sites. Results We find that the RU-MNL model performs slightly better than the RR-MNL, although the difference is relatively small. We also find some illuminating factors that contribute to the RR-MNL’s ability to describe choice behaviour more accurately, in some instances, than the RU-MNL. In the recreational site choice context that was considered in this study, we find that the more familiar a site is (denoted by the frequency of visits to a site for recreation), the more likely the choice of this site is better explained by utility maximization (RU-MNL) than regret minimization (RR-MNL). For many of the less familiar sites compared to the Liffey, the choice of these sites are better described by the RR-MNL than by the RU-MNL. This can have important management implications because it suggests that site managers may require different management strategies if they aim to increase kayakers’ visits to specific sites. Also, intermediate and advanced skilled kayakers’ choices would appear to be better described by regret minimization rather than utility maximization, reflecting the fact that this group of recreationists may give more consideration to the difference in the level of attributes between sites compared to their basic skilled level counterparts. The analysis of the Logsum formulae under hypothetical changes in recreation quality highlighted both similarities and differences in impacts arising from the two modelling approaches. Both models show that the increase in crowding at a site negatively impacts kayakers’ experience. For all respondents under the RU-MNL the introduction of a parking fee reduces kayakers’ utility. However, the RR-MNL is able to show that the introduction of a parking fee has some positive effects, as it decreases the regret for a quarter of kayakers. Conclusions Similar to previous studies that have applied both RU-MNL and RR-MNL, the two approaches retrieve similar model fits and estimate the same number of parameters. However, they do imply slightly different conclusions arising from the research. This begs the question about which modelling approach the researcher should apply. We would argue that, given the ease with which RR-MNL models can also be estimated using the standard econometric approaches, the analyst should consider applying both modelling approaches to their data. Moreover, the results from this study suggest that, since some choices are better described by utility maximization and some by regret minimization, then it may be prudent to apply the model that best reflects the particular choice behaviour. This approach would capture the behavioural influences on choices more accurately than assuming in all instances that individuals always make choices within a utility maximization framework. References Burt, O. & Brewer, D., (1971), Estimation of Net Social Benefits from Outdoor Recreation Econometrica,39(5):813-827. Clawson, M., (1959), “Methods of Measuring the Demand for and Value of Outdoor Recreation,” Reprint No. 10, Resources for the Future: Washington, D.C. Chorus, C., (2010), A New Model of Random Regret Minimization, EJTIR 10(2):181-196. Haab, T. & McConnell K., (2002), Valuing Environmental & Natural Resources, Northhampton MA: Edward Elgar. Hanemann, M., (1978), A Methodological and Empirical Study of the Recreation Benefits from Water Quality Improvement, Ph.D. Dissertation, Harvard University (Economics). Hotelling, H., (1947), “Letter to the National Park Service,” Reprinted in An Economic Study of the Monetary Evaluation of Recreation in the National Parks [1949]. U.S. Department of the Interior, National Park Service and Recreational Planning Division, Washington, DC. Kivetz, R., Oded N., & Srinivasan, V., (2004), Alternative Models for Capturing the Compromise Effect, Journal of Marketing Research 41 (August). Trice, A & Wood, S., (1958), Measurement of Recreation Benefits, Land Economics , 34(3):195207. 11 Coral-Fisheries Interactions in Bioeconomic Modelling – Comparing Norway and Iceland’s Redfish Fisheries Naomi S. Foley & Claire W. Armstrong, Norwegian Fishery College, University of Tromsø, Norway Introduction There is very little bioeconomic modelling work that explicitly takes into account the interaction between marine habitats and fisheries. Within the bioeconomic setting, habitat can influence commercial stocks or fisheries upon these stocks in a number of ways. Habitat may positively contribute to stock growth through the provision of breeding, spawning or refuge sites. It is possible that the price of species harvested over particular habitats may also be affected, not directly by habitat, but indirectly through market and consumer preferences. Some habitats may encourage the concentration of commercial species thus reducing harvest costs (see Foley et al (forthcoming) for an overview of interactions. Specifically habitat can be (1) facultative, (2) essential, or have (3) a positive effect on the catchability or finally (4) a potential price increasing effect. The former two are grouped under biophysical effects, while the latter two under bioeconomic effects as illustrated in figure 1. FISHERY BIOECONOMIC EFFORT HARVEST HABITAT MANAGEMENT BIOPHYSICAL FISH STOCKS Figure 1: Habitat interactions presented. Interactions drawn in the ovals represent biological entities associated with habitat while squares and triangles are human behavioural entities. Source: Foley et al (forthcoming) Of particular interest to this study are the functional values or indirect use values associated with cold water coral (CWC) ecosystems, such as habitat, nurseries or areas of refuge. Within the MEA framework such services are classified as supporting services, i.e. the functions that are necessary for the production of all other ecosystem services. Two cases of coral-fisheries interactions are studied in a bioeconomic model setting: Norwegian and Icelandic redfish fisheries. The cases are studied using time series data of catch and effort in the fisheries, while estimating for possible outer limits of cold water coral decline. The two countries have applied different types of management, where Norway’s management has been closer to open access, while Iceland has had a property rights system of individual transferable quotas (ITQ) in the time period studied. The Model Focusing on the biophysical effects of habitatfish connections we apply the production function approach to two case studies, one Norwegian and the other Icelandic. The application can potentially link CWC to fisheries, identifying to what degree profits from commercial species are affected by the loss of CWC. Given the identification of such a link, this can then be modelled in order to ascertain the losses involved when this link is not included in management or conservation decisions. An essential fish habitat model is presented, as used in Barbier and Strand (1998) and Foley et al (2010). Defining Xt as the stock of fish, changes in growth can be expressed as: Xt+1 −Xt = F(Xt ,Ht ) −h(Xt , Et ), FX >0, FH >0, F(X,0) =0 (1) The net expansion of the stock occurs as a result of biological growth in the current period, F(Xt, Ht), net of any harvesting, h(Xt,, Et) 12 1 , which is a function of stock as well as effort. The influence of the coral area, Ht, as a habitat, on the growth of the fish stock is assumed to be positive ( ∂F / ∂H t = FH > 0 ) and the effect of coral loss is greater in Norway than Iceland. In both countries, however, there are indications of economic losses due to cold water coral decline. The open access nature of the Norwegian fishery seems to exacerbate these losses. The assumed loss of 30-50% of cold water coral gives an estimated annual loss in harvest of approximately 400014000 tonnes of redfish in Iceland, resulting in losses of between 2,5-8,4 million Euros. essential ( F ( X ,0) = 0 ). The logistic growth function is adjusted to allow for the influence of the CWC habitat, denoted by H, as in Foley et al (2010): F ( X , H ) = rK ( H ) X (1 − X ). K (H ) (2) For Norway the same cold water coral decline explains harvest losses of between 2 and 7 thousand tonnes of redfish, worth between 2 and 6 million Euros. Though the losses in Norway are lower than in Iceland, they make up a much larger percentage of actual harvests and revenues, as the fishery in Norway is on average less than a fourth of the Icelandic fishery. Figure 2 illustrates the effect of assuming both the carrying capacity and the intrinsic growth rate are functions of H; i.e., a fall in CWC will cause a reduction in both. F(X,H) K(H) K Figure 2: Logistic growth function, impact of reduced habitat. Analysis: Comparison of Norway and Iceland Two management conditions are considered for our comparative static analysis. The major difference between the two case studies is the management applied to the fishery. During the period of the Norwegian analysis the fishery was de facto open access and thus we assume total revenues are equal to total costs, i.e. all profits are dissipated, and this is used to elicit costs. The Icelandic fishery has been managed by ITQs. Icelandic harvest of redfish is about four times that of the Norwegian harvests. We therefore conduct a comparative static analysis for an MEY fishery for the Icelandic case. The MEY comparative static analysis indicates that harvest decreases at a decreasing rate with losses of habitat area. X References Barbier EB and Strand I. (1998), Valuing mangrove-fishery linkages – a case study of Campeche, Mexico. Environmental and Resource Economics, 12: 151-166. Foley NS, Kahui V, Armstrong CW and van Rensburg T. (2010), Estimating linkages between cold water corals and redfish on the Norwegian coast. Marine Resource Economics, 25: 105-120. Foley NS, Armstrong CW, Kahui V, Mikkelsen E and Reithe, S. (Forthcoming). A review of bioeconomic modeling of habitat-fisheries interactions. International Journal of Ecology. The results indicate higher technological development in Iceland than Norway, while 1 The Schaefer harvest function is assumed; h = h ( E , X ) = qEX , where q denotes the constant catchability coefficient, X is the stock biomass and E is fishing effort 13 Valuing Marine Environmental Characteristics Associated with Changes to the EU Bathing Water Directive Stephen Hynes, Caitriona Scully and Alphonsus Browne, SEMRU, NUI Galway Introduction This paper reports the results of a Choice Experiment (CE) study of the economic value of potential improvements to coastal water quality that may result from implementation of changes to the European Union’s Bathing Waters Directive in 2015. The focus is on potential benefits to recreational users of coastal waters, and how these vary according to the extent of exposure to risks. The Choice Experiment method has been applied in a number of recent studies to coastal water quality changes and allows the researcher to estimate separate values for different aspects, or attributes, of water quality improvements which are relevant both from a water quality management perspective, and from the viewpoint of peoples’ preferences over water quality improvements and the benefits of coastal zone protection. Methods such as choice experiments help build a picture of the economic values of protecting and enhancing ecosystem services, thus contributing to the evidence base for better management of marine resources, and for improved policy-making and regulation. For example, environmental valuation methods allow the quantification of the benefits of policies such as the EU Bathing Waters Directive, which can then be compared with the costs of implementing a policy in order to judge the overall social efficiency of new regulation and the desirability and targeting of “derogations” from uniform targets. A new European Union Directive on bathing water (Directive 2006/7/EC) came into force on 24 March 2006. It repeals the existing 1976 Quality of Bathing Waters Directive with effect from 31 December 2014. The 2006 Directive establishes a new classification system for bathing water quality based on four water quality classifications: ‘poor’, ‘sufficient’, ‘good’ and ‘excellent’ and requires that a status of ‘sufficient’ be achieved by 2015 for all bathing waters. Environmental regulators must place warning signs on beaches which fail to meet this standard. Repeated failures to meet the standard will result in beaches being dedesignated. The new Directive on bathing water establishes microbiological standards for two new parameters, namely intestinal enterococci and Escherichia coli. Since 2011, these two microbiological parameters have been monitored and used to classify bathing waters. In Ireland, the Environmental Protection Agency is charged with monitoring and testing the compliance status of Irish bathing waters with EU bathing water quality standards. The quality of Ireland’s bathing waters is high, with 97% of bathing areas (127 of 131 areas monitored) complying with the minimum EU mandatory values and achieving ‘sufficient’ water quality status. However, other European countries face more of a challenge in complying with the Directive; in England, for example, around 7% of beaches currently do not comply with the new ‘sufficient’ standard. Survey design The focus of the CE was on the valuation of changes in coastal water quality to those who use beaches in Ireland for recreation, principally “active” recreationalists such as surfers, swimmers and sea kayakers. This group of respondents are likely to be particularly affected by improvements to water quality which result from revisions to the Bathing Waters Directive, since many of the water quality parameters which the directive focuses on are linked to human health. As water quality improved, the exposure of beach users to illness from contact with water-borne pathogens such as faecal coliforms will decline. The identification of attributes for the CE design was based upon the changes being made to the Directive. A number of other aspects of a recreational trip to a beach were identified at the piloting stage which individuals considered to be important, such as weather and surf conditions, crowding on the beach and the use being made of the beach by other users. However, these were excluded from the CE design as they will not be directly changed by implementation of the Directive. Verification that the attributes included in the analysis were appropriate and understandable was carried out through a pilot survey of a sample of 40 active beach recreationalists. 14 The attributes chosen for the CE describe three aspects of coastal water quality: benthic health, human health risks, and beach debris. The interviews for the main survey were conducted face-to-face at beaches on the west coast of Ireland from June to August 2011. The surveys were conducted both during the week and at weekends. A total of 382 individuals were interviewed, yielding 365 observations which could be used in the final analysis. Results Using the collected data, a 2 class latent class model was employed to explain the preferences of marine recreationalists in Ireland for a number of beach and water related attribute levels that can be associated with the recent changes to the EU’s Bathing Waters Directive. Results showed that people are willing to pay for all of the improvements modelled, since they were willing to incur higher travel costs to access “hypothetical” beaches with these higher quality levels compared with the status quo choice of recreational location. Whilst it is not possible at present to aggregate these numbers to a national benefits figure – due to a lack of reliable national data on participation in coastal water-based recreation – the economic benefits of implementing the Directive would clearly be substantial. Should national participation data become available, per-trip estimates such as this could be combined with such data and count models of participation change as a function of the higher utility from improved beach quality to generate national willingness to pay estimates. Non-use and “informal” recreational use values for these improvements would also need to be estimated (for an example of the former for coastal water quality in the context of the original Bathing Waters directive). National benefit estimates could then be compared to national cost figures for making these improvements in water quality, for example through modifications of sewage treatment, storm water overflows and pathogen run-off from farmland. Whilst the Irish government does not have choice over whether to implement the revised directive, it could use such information at the regional level in targeting water quality improvements at sites of high use in terms of on-water recreational activity. Benefit estimates at the level of specific beaches could be used to help make decisions on which beaches should be targeted for improvements, and which should be no longer designated as bathing waters. This would be the case if the economic costs of improving a site to a “sufficient” water quality level outweighed the benefits. A national, aggregate benefits figure substantially less than aggregate costs would imply more attention needing to be paid to finding more costeffective ways of achieving target improvements in water quality. In the LC analysis, in-water recreationalists were found to be more likely to be in class 1, which has a lower positive coefficient value for health risk reduction to zero than class 2. However, the smaller coefficient for cost (in absolute terms) for class 1 than class 2 results in a higher marginal valuation of reductions in health risks relative to latent class 2. This result is being driven by the sensitivity of the participants in each class to the price associated with a management option rather than their preference for the actual health attribute level. The reduced sensitivity to health risk reductions, as shown by the preference parameters in the LC model echoes results found by Hynes et al. 2008 and Boeri et al. (2012) who suggest that water quality and the implied health risk is not generally an important aspect of a dedicated water sports recreationalist’s choice of site, unless the level of water pollution is extreme. These water users, and especially those with the higher skill levels, are more interested in the recreational experience that the site can offer rather than the marginal health risks involved from using the site. However, there may be a complex relationship between selection in type of activity, subjective assessment of personal risk and valuation of risk reduction underlying these potentially contradictory findings. Results from the RPL and LC models also showed considerable variation in preferences across the different recreational user groups. This suggests that beach and coastal recreation site managers and policy makers in charge of such sites should think carefully about the particular type of recreationalist utilising any site and the attributes and facilities that such users value, in developing site-specific management plans. Finally, at a more general level, Ronnback et al. (2007) have argued that “the evaluation of ecosystem goods and services from both economic and ecological perspectives is a necessary ingredient in practical policy”. Stated preference methods, such as that used here, provide one important means of arriving at such economic evaluations. 15 Port and Shipping Data as Economic Indicators Fergal Curtin, Shipping Market Analyst, Irish Maritime Development Office, Marine Institute Introduction The Irish Maritime Development Office (IMDO) is Ireland’s national dedicated development, promotional and marketing agency for the shipping services sector. The office was established in 1999 and is part of the Marine Institute which is a state agency responsible for researching the potential of Ireland’s vast marine resources. The Irish Maritime Development Office operates under the auspices of the Department Of Transport, Tourism & Sport, and is charged with the responsibility for undertaking the following activities through its statutory remit: • • • To promote and assist the development of Irish shipping, Irish shipping services and seafarer training. To liaise with, support and market the shipping and shipping services sector. To advise the Minister on the development and co-ordination of policy in the shipping and shipping services sector so as to protect and create employment The Irish Maritime Development Office: Economic Data Analysis: The Irish Maritime Development Office (IMDO) produces a number of key economic and shipping reports for industry. The IMDO Weekly Market Review is produced in-house and offers an in depth analysis into international/national shipping markets and provides a national & global economic overview of the week’s events. The annual Irish Maritime Transport Economist is published in April of each year. This is a statistical bulletin and a comprehensive source of maritime traffic, trade and global shipping markets data. A capacity report is produced bi-annually on Lifton/Lift-off, Roll-on/Roll-Off, and Passenger capacity in the Irish market. This update provides the IMDO with information on operators, routes, frequency of service, and destinations served from Ireland. On a quarterly basis a traffic report is published which provides ports, operators, government and the general transport industry with up-to-date information on how the market is performing individually and as a whole. The IMDO also produce a number of “Shipping Tradelinks” reports which provide a succinct analysis of Ireland’s trade with over a dozen European Countries. Port and Shipping Data as Economic Indicators: The IMDO gather monthly, quarterly and annual shipping market statistics which is then analysed and reported to industry stakeholders. The IMDO quarterly reports are generally released just over a month after each quarter’s end. This provides a vital insight into how the economy is performing as nearly 99% of goods are transported by sea. Analysing any of the major Irish shipping sectors before and during the current recession will accurately inform any reader of the demise in the volume of commodities moving through Irish Ports during this period. The IMDO data is analysed in core market segments. Bulk Traffic is subdivided into Dry, Liquid, and Break Bulk. Lift-On/Lift Off traffic is subdivided into laden and unladen traffic by import/export traffic. Finally Roll-On/Roll-Off traffic is analysed into accompanied and unaccompanied traffic again by imported or exported traffic. These traffic segments individually and combined are able to provide a vital overview of how the shipping sector and general economy are performing at any given moment. Recent Trends in the Irish Shipping Sector: 2010/11 A notable feature in the IMDO traffic analysis in 2010 was the continued growth in exports as there was a wider recovery in global economic demand. The IMDO estimated that export volumes on the principle routes to the UK, Asia and US were up overall by 7 per cent in 2010. Roll-On/Roll-off volumes through all Irish ports recovered by 5 per cent, lift on/lift –off declined by 4 per cent while dry bulk volumes were up 18 per cent, and liquid bulk increased by 2 per cent. Part of the return to growth in the Dry Bulk sector was attributed to strong global demand for ore and mineral products such as alumina, while domestic demand in the agricultural sector led to a rise in the imports of grains, feeds and fertilizers. Moving onto 2011, there was very little growth in volumes terms. Total bulk volumes increased by 1 per cent. After a relatively strong start to 2011, the majority of ports witnessed a slowdown in bulk volumes in the 16 second half of 2011 compared to 2010, with only three ports showing bulk volume growth in the fourth quarter of 2011. This volume decline can be mainly attributed to the global slowdown in demand. The current prevailing economic uncertainties are clearly reflected in the load-on/load-off (lo/lo) traffic volumes in 2011 which saw container volume demand pick up early in the year before falling away in the latter half of 2011, as underlying concerns about the pace of recovery in the domestic and global economy continued. Rollon/roll-off (ro/ro) traffic through All-Island Ports remained relatively static in 2011. Ro-Ro volumes have now declined by 10 per cent when compared to 2007 levels but remain higher than levels witnessed in 2009. Continued austerity programs in both Ireland and the United Kingdom affected disposable income which led to further downward pressure on freight volumes between the two nations as business sentiment, especially in the United Kingdom, remained weak. The United Kingdom accounts for 93 per cent of Ro/ro volumes through Irish ports while the remainder is made up of Continental traffic. Passenger volumes through the Island of Ireland in 2011 declined by 6 per cent to 4.6 million while tourist cars volumes showed a 4 per cent reduction compared to 2010 figures. Port Financials: The focus of the IMDO’s analysis is to extrapolate key data from the annual company financial reports in order to provide a comparative review of Irish ports. The annual reports are analysed in three separate parts, overall performance of the ports, individual port analysis and composite ratio analysis in which ports are compared across a number of separate accounting ratios to measure core efficiencies. Analysis from the IMDO “Review of Port Financial Accounts” was utilised by the Government’s Review Group, chaired by Colm McCarthy, in its report on “State Assets and Liabilities”, published in April 2011. All-Ireland Freight Forum (AIFF) Project: The AIFF was established by the North/South Ministerial Council in April 2009 and held its first meeting in January 2010. The main priorities of the AIFF are: being competitive in a sustainable manner; safer, compliant, eco-efficient, road freight transport; Rail freight and other alternatives; International connectivity and Network management. The IMDO has been charged with the remit of establishing a strong and accurate baseline of international connectivity from the Island of Ireland and has to date researched a number of area’s in both maritime and aviation freight movements. Conclusion: Reports by the IMDO are being used at the very highest level by government and industry bodies (both shipping and economic). Shipping data collected by the IMDO on a daily, weekly, quarterly and yearly basis is a vital tool for understanding how the shipping industry/economy is performing and is an essential tool in examining how shipping markets will perform in the future. Stakeholders in the Irish shipping industry look for the most up-todate data analysis in order to make key decisions on how they will operate their businesses in the future and the IMDO is well positioned to provide such analysis. References: Irish Maritime Development Office Website: http://www.imdo.ie The Irish Maritime Transport Economist: (IMDO) http://www.imdo.ie/IMDO/newsroom/recentpublications/ IMDO Weekly Market Review: http://www.imdo.ie/IMDO/newsroom/WeeklyMa rketReview.htm Shipping Trade links: (IMDO) http://www.shippingtradelink.com/ 17 Valuing the Non-Market Benefits of the WFD Implementation in Ireland Daniel Norton, Stephen Hynes, Edel Doherty SEMRU, NUI Galway; Cathal Buckley, Teagasc; Danny Campbell, Queens University Introduction The Water Framework Directive (WFD) aim is for EU waters to be at least ‘good ecological status’ (GES) by 2015. These water bodies include inland surface waters, transitional waters, coastal waters and ground waters. GES is a broader measure of water quality than the physio-chemical indicators that previous EU legislation used as an indicator of water quality. In using the framework approach the EU is letting member states flexibility in how they achieve at least GES in waters or maintain waters which are currently at good or high status. The WFD calls for a consideration of the economic costs and benefits of improvements to ecological status in catchment management plans, along with the introduction of full social cost pricing for water use. Where achieving GES is ‘disproportionately expensive’ (often took to mean where costs outweigh benefits) then extensions to meeting GES may be allowed up to 2027 for such water bodies. Many of the benefits of achieving GES are nonmarket goods and services including water based recreation, angling, landscape values and non use or existence values. Therefore, non-market valuation studies may need to be undertaken to capture the value of benefits before deciding if cost of achieving GES is ‘disproportionately expensive’ Benefit Transfer There are a variety of non-market valuation techniques (travel cost models, hedonic pricing, contingent valuation, choice modelling, etc) (Hanley and Barbier, 2009) which can be used to estimate the value of non-market benefits. One of the disadvantages of these methods is that they are expensive and time consuming. An alternative of these primary methods is a method known as benefit transfer (BT). BT is a process of valuing a non-market good or service of a policy site by using values estimated for similar non-market services at another study site and applying these values to the policy site (Brouwer, 2000). There are three main types of BT. The unit value transfer can take two forms, a simple unit transfer is where one value is directly transferred from a study site to the policy site and an adjusted unit transfer where one or more study sites values are adjusted for various factors (income, exchange rates, inflation, etc) before being transferred to policy site. The second type is to transfer a value function from the study site to the policy site and the last BT type is the undertaking of meta analysis. The advantages of BT are that it is relatively cheap and fast to undertake. However, as it is a secondary valuation method it suffers from the risk that the values transferred may under or over estimate the actual value of the site. This difference is known as the transfer error. Using BT to rank value of Irish water bodies Ireland is divided into 8 River Basin Districts (RBDs) for the purposes of implementing the WFD. Within the Republic of Ireland these are subdivided into 151 Water Management Units (WMUs). Relevant populations for each of the WMUs were based on populations within the EDs which the WMU overlapped (Figure 1.) An adjusted unit BT was then carried out based on average adjusted values from five studies which measured the value of change in water status. The value of Irish WMUs achieving GES was estimated based on change from the current status to GES and on the relevant population within the WMU. Figure 1. EDs overlain by WMUs within Ireland As the values are driven by both poor initial water quality and population, it is not a surprise that the WMUs which achieved the highest value of attaining GES were those close to the urban areas of Dublin and Cork. The Tolka WMU was the 18 highest valued WMU with a value of complying with the WFD of €2.8 million. Note that some areas such as offshore islands and the area around Inner Dublin, which had the highest population, are not covered by WMUs. If the latter was considered a WMU it could have been the highest valued WMU (€2.3 - 4.8 million). If this area is included as a WMU then the total value of meeting the WFD could be €30.6 million. Further difficulties with this approach are that values of people outside the WMU are not considered and that this measures only the value in the change of water status and is not an estimate of the ‘total economic value’ of the water bodies within the WMU. Therefore WMUs currently at GES have a value of zero. Figure 2. Buffer zones for the Boyne Catchment Using BT to estimate value of an Irish water body The previous approach is useful to help rank various WMUs and help to allocate resources but when the value of achieving GES of one water body may be more important to a policy maker a slightly different approach is used. Conclusions While primary valuations offer the best approach in valuing environmental goods and services such as improved water quality, BT can be a quicker and cheaper methodology of estimating values of water bodies achieving GES. There is the risk of producing under or over estimates and economic analysis should not the sole determinant within the area of water policy in Ireland but used as a tool to help inform the decision maker. A previous study on the Boyne catchment was undertaken by Stithou (2011). Undertaking a BT exercise on the same water body would allow a transfer error to be calculated. Most of the policy site was at poor or moderate status and five UK studies values were transferred to estimate the value of achieving GES. Along with being adjusted for income differences between countries, exchange rates and inflations, the transferred values were adjusted to allow for distance decay. The concept of distance decay was used to estimate the difference someone closer to a study site will be willing to pay compared to someone who lived further away from the site. This phenomena has been observed for both use and non-use values. Buffer zones were setup around the policy site (Boyne River Catchment) (Figure 2) based on buffer zones described in Hanley et al (2003) and the average of the values transferred were adjusted based on the use and non-use figures reported for each buffer in the same paper. The total value for the catchment was calculated by summing the use and non-use estimates for the buffer zones together. The value estimated was €13.6 million which was less than the €19.1 million estimated generated by Stithou (2011). This was a transfer error of -29%. This is within the range as those reported for BT studies within the literature. Acknowledgement This work was funded under the EPA STRIVE Programme References Brouwer, R. (2000), Environmental Value Transfer: State of the Art and Future Prospects, Ecological Economics, 32: 137-152 Hanley, N., Schlapfer, F. and Spurgeon, J. (2003), Aggregating the benefits of environmental improvements: distance-decay functions for use and non-use values, Journal of Environmental Management, 68: 297–304 Hanley, N. and Barbier, E. (2009), Pricing Nature, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK Stithou, (2011), The economic value of improvements in the ecology of Irish rivers due to the Water Framework Directive, PhD Thesis, Stirling Management School, Economics Division, University of Stirling 19 The Impact of Cost Uncertainty on the Feasibility of Wave Energy Conversion Devices and the Implications for Policy Niall Farrell, SEMRU, NUI Galway Introduction Feasibility analyses of Wave Energy Conversion devices are subject to uncertainty as a lack of operating experience has led to sparse information availability for cost parameters. As such, approximate point estimates of uncertain parameters have been chosen for investment appraisals to date. Such an approach overlooks the potential extent of cost variability, and thus investment risk, resulting from cost uncertainty. This is an important consideration for both the appraisal of private investment and mechanisms of public support. This study uses statistical simulation to incorporate the risk presented by these uncertain cost parameters in profitability estimations. In doing so, the potential range of uncertain input values is used in favour of potentially subjective point estimates. The Conditional Value at Risk (CVaR) metric is used to derive probability estimates for certain cost and return values under different conditions. Taking Ireland as a case study, this methodology is applied to assess the adequacy of Renewable Energy Feed-in Tariff (REFIT) support mechanisms for the Pelamis WEC device. Motivation A Renewable Energy Feed-in Tariff (REFIT) is the policy support mechanism in place to provide an adequate return on investment for novel renewable technologies in Ireland. This operates by providing a hedge against market price fluctuations by offering a guaranteed price of €0.22 for each kilowatt hour (kWh) of electricity generated. The effectiveness of this mechanism depends on whether this provides sufficient support for private investment. Estimations of project cost are required in order for this to be determined. Current estimates have been calculated using deterministic methodologies, with Irish estimates varying from €0.05-€0.20/kWh. This range indicates a considerable degree of uncertainty as to the true cost value, making policy evaluation particularly difficult. Furthermore, employing point estimates in a deterministic analysis overlooks the impact that uncertainty, and thus exposure to risk, may have on the investment decision. This is an important consideration as although a deterministic analysis may suggest an adequate return, deviation of costs from assumed values may yield an inadequate return. The sensitivity of profitability to potential deviations is an important consideration as a prudent investor may abstain if there is sufficient possibility that financial return is inadequate. For policy appraisal, the exposure to risk under a given policy regime may be defined as the probability of effectively achieving the desired investment environment. Methodology A Monte Carlo Simulation Procedure is employed to elicit the probability of project cost and profitability from a known range of potential cost values. Monte Carlo simulation is a numerical process to estimate the probability density distribution of an uncertain parameter, such as project profitability. This is carried out by repeated calculation of project profitability, where each calculation uses a different value for each uncertain input. This value is sampled randomly from a known distribution. In doing so, the probability density distribution of project profitability may be calculated based on the proportional frequency of obtaining each profitability estimate. Specification of the full range of potential uncertain values in favour of subjective point estimates provides an objective estimation of project profitability, whilst allowing for the simultaneous consideration of all potential sources of cost variability. The simulation process employed in this study has 11 random variables. Once the Monte Carlo simulation is complete, there exists 10,000 iterations of project cost and profitability. One must determine the point in this distribution at which project profitability may be evaluated such that risk is mitigated. Thus, the Conditional Value at Risk (CVaR) metric is employed. CVaR is an augmentation of the standard value at risk (VaR) metric. The VaR states that with probability β the expected value will not be lower than a certain threshold α. The CVaR focuses on the tails of the distribution and averages the values which fall short of threshold α depending on the probability level β. Therefore, 20 the CVaR is a more conservative risk measure (Gass et al., 2011). Preliminary Findings: Cost Estimates This methodology gives greater interpretational power to existing uncertain cost estimations by providing a degree of likelihood for each. Preliminary results find that the most likely value for 100 unit steel-based devices in Ireland is €0.16/kWh. One can see that this central estimate is quite similar to that quoted by Dalton et al. (2010), where a cost of €0.15/kWh is quoted under similar conditions. This provides an element of validation for the model specification. The added value of this model is realised when one analyses the probability of achieving this cost value, and thus the exposure to risk. It is found that there is 74% chance of achieving an LCOE greater than or equal to €0.15/kWh, indicating that policy formulated on this central estimate is subject to a great deal of risk. As such, the cost of electricity is re-evaluated at the 90% CVaR threshold. At this point of estimation, this analysis recommends that prudent policy formulation consider a cost value of €0.187/kWh. Preliminary Findings: REFIT Appraisal The second goal of this paper was to ascertain the degree of certainty to which current REFIT policy of €0.22/kWh provides an adequate investment environment. It has been stated that an Internal Rate of Return (IRR) of 10% is required for Wave Energy to be an attractive investment (Dalton et al., 2010). For initial steel-based devices, it is found that only device installations of 80 units or greater provide the potential for positive rates of return, with a <1% probability of 100 unit steel-based devices yielding a negative rate of return. Preliminary IRR estimates lie within a range of 3%28% for 100 unit steel devices, with a most likely value found to be above the 10% threshold of viability. However, there is still a 50% chance that this policy results in a rate of return less than 10%. This is reflected in the requirements for a prudent policy formulation where IRR falls below 10% at the 90% CVaR threshold. As such, these findings indicate that current policy is potentially effective in achieving the required rate of return, if investors are certain that costs and outputs will be at their most likely value. However, this is not necessarily the case when one considers potential variability and deviation from this most likely value. This analysis finds that uncertain input costs create a risk that REFIT policy may yield an inadequate return for Wave Energy Conversion Device investment. Preliminary results recommend that a risk premium of €0.027/kWh be considered when evaluating the cost of initial 100 unit installations. This cost variability translates into considerable risk that investment will yield an inadequate rate of return. As such, it is recommended that a REFIT premium of 12-25% greater than that required for most likely cost estimates is required to take into account the risk presented by cost uncertainty. These findings relate to preliminary parameter estimates and 100 unit installations. This work will extend to consider the exposure to risk according to installation size, technological maturity and alternative parameter assumptions. References Allan, G., Gilmartin, M., McGregor, P. & Swales, K. (2011), Levelised costs of Wave and Tidal energy in the UK: Cost competitiveness and the importance of “banded” Renewables Obligation Certificates, Energy Policy 39(1), 23 - 39. Dalton, G., Alcorn, R. & Lewis, T. (2010), Case study feasibility analysis of the Pelamis wave energy convertor in Ireland, Portugal and North America, Renewable Energy 35(2), 443 - 455. Department of Communications Marine Natural Resources (DCMNR) (2005), Ocean Energy in Ireland, Dublin: Stationery Office. Gass, V., Strauss, F., Schmidt, J. & Schmid, E. (2011), Assessing the effect of wind power uncertainty on profitability, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 15(6), 2677 - 2683. Montes, G. M., Martin, E. P., Bayo, J. A. & Garcia, J. O. (2011), The applicability of computer simulation using Monte Carlo techniques in windfarm profitability analysis, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 15(9), 4746 - 4755. Previsic, M. (2004), System level design, performance, and costs of California Pelamis wave power plant, Technical report, EPRI, http://oceanenergy.epri.com/attachments/wave/r eports/006_San_Francisco_Pelamis_Conceptual_D esign_12-11-04.pdf. SQW (2010), Economic Study for Ocean Energy Development in Ireland: A report to Sustainable Energy Authority Ireland and Invest Northern Ireland. 21 Another Collective Tragedy? The Case of the Killary Mussel Farming Cooperative Peter Cush, School of Political Science and Sociology and SEMRU, NUI Galway Introduction The natural resource base of Ireland has become a critical component in addressing the rural development problem. With the demise of small scale farming in many rural areas, natural resources became a key focus in diversifying small local economies. ‘Inclusiveness’ and ‘Participation’ of those on the margins have become the policy focus and these have permeated into much of debate within the rural development discourse. This ideological framework has looked at ways of maximising community participation in resource development. Of course the major difficulty with this approach is that many of these resources are finite and with a greater number of people using the resources they become subject to depletion. Community participation and resource sustainability are then two interdependent variables with an inherent tension characterising their relationship. Critical to their survival is the ability of the users to draft cooperative agreements between them and limit their use of the resource. However cooperation is not a natural social phenomenon and relies heavily upon the local social context and the wider structural framework surrounding the resource users. The purpose of this paper is to examine cooperative action in one of Ireland’s largest aquaculture sites, Killary harbour, North West Connemara. The argument made is that while resources users demonstrated an ability to cooperate themselves, such collective action was ultimately undermined by a wider policy framework that placed less of premium on cooperative resource management. Cooperative action in this instance was swimming against the tide of the dominant ideological perspective that placed more of an emphasis on ‘big business’ than on cooperation as a form of economic organisation. From a policy perspective, this case study proves interesting and much can be learned from this about the policy focus surrounding natural resource management in Ireland. It was made clear that managing rural marine resources formed the basis of this paper, namely the question of whether there is sufficient evidence to justify moving from centralised command and control policies to local level community based management. Providing a clear answer to this question requires us to look at two things, firstly whether it can work and secondly if it can work why we should actively seek to promote it. Local level resource management Let us deal with the first issue of whether local level resource management can work. There is a mixed message emanating from the above case study as the co-operative showed a long period of success coupled with a rapid period of decline. However rather than giving a definitive answer to the question, this case study shows that there are numerous dynamics that make local level management a success or a failure in any given time and place. The 20 years of a success in Killary highlights that in the right set of circumstances, local people can develop cooperative strategies that allow for successful resource management. The issues that appear important here mirror much of what is outlined in the literature on cooperative management where communication, a history of positive social relations, trust amongst the participants and devolution of power from centralised control form a critical piece of the puzzle. However one issue that is not addressed is the issue of economic necessity. Discussion The case of the Killary mussel farming co-operative suggests that local level management will only succeed as long as the users can be convinced that it is in their economic interest to cooperate with locally established rules. Without such an economic incentive, local institutions legitimacy will be called into question and can ultimately fail. However if local institutions can balance these dynamics then there is sufficient evidence to justify the optimism attributed to local level management. The significant issue here is that it is important not to be reductive. We cannot categorically state that local level management is a good and positive thing and that it will always work in Ireland. It will not and examples provided in this study and by 22 Curtin (1993, 1988) show that the ‘rural’ is a contested space and cooperation over a use of a finite resource cannot be assumed to automatically ensue. However on the other hand, in certain instances it can work and when a group of resource users demonstrate an ability to develop cooperative strategies then the state should actively work with this group of people and provide technical, financial and legislative support. From a policy perspective, governments departments should be flexible and not base their decisions on predefined notions of what local people cannot do. Instead they need to develop the capacity to look at cases independently and understand the complex set of interpersonal relations present and whether they will imbue positive cooperative strategies. Only then, can policy surrounding the management of finite natural resources define itself as evidence based. There is no right or wrong answer and cooperative resource management can work in a given time and place, and when it does, its success will be determined by the political will to provide the necessary space to resource users. The next question that emerges is whether or not policy makers should actively seek to promote local level management. If policy makers can do the same job as the resource users why then should we seek to devolve power to a cooperative group? Is there anything achieved in this process? Does it not lead to unnecessary risk taking where we entrust power to a group who we perceive of as cooperative but who are ultimately individualistic, deviant and non complaint? Should policy as a result not just take the safe option and always rely on command and control policies? The problem with this argument is that there is nothing to suggest that the state acts in the best interests of the resource or the people who are reliant upon these resources for their survival. The case study presented above illustrated the folly in assuming that the state always works towards the optimum social outcome in the management of finite resources. The department of agriculture, fisheries and food took it upon themselves to severely over license Killary harbour in 1999/2000, a reality that has adversely affected the producers ability to make a living from the trade. For whatever reason, they felt that overstocking Killary harbour was a positive step in allowing the state to “manage an efficient and effective regulatory framework in respect of Aquaculture licensing and Foreshore licensing of Aquaculture and Sea Fishery related activities, and to secure a fair financial return from the state’s foreshore estate”. Conclusions The steps taken in Killary harbour by the department cannot in anyway be presented as an “efficient and effective regulatory framework”. Consequently this paper shows that the state is just as likely to fail as a regulatory authority as the resource users themselves. There is no ‘right’ or ‘wrong’, ‘proper’ or ‘improper’ in natural resource management and both the state and the resource users can fail as management agents. Managing finite resource is a difficult task to achieve for any regulatory authority, be it state or community based. If a locally established institution proves itself capable of managing a resource, policy makers should not seek to dismantle it as it is not in congruence with their pre-defined notions of what ‘sustainable management’ means and represents. If an agency proves itself successful at managing a resource over a period of time, then that surely justifies its legitimacy, and they should not be overridden by biases and snobbery surrounding ‘unsophisticated’ local level management practices. It is suggested that regulatory authorities be more open and positive about the potential of local level management and realise that resource users do have the potential to design rules that are better tailored to their own needs and that of the resource that they have regular interactions with. The difficulty with much of the natural resource policy in Ireland is that it is informed mainly by marine biologists who define what is ‘best’ in terms of managing the resources. However we are reminded that “resource management is people management” (Berkes and Folke 1998: 2) and that unless policy makers show a better understanding of people and the institutions that they can create, only then can it be said to be clear, well defined and supported by evidence. A key question that needs to be asked here is that when resource users demonstrate an ability to manage the resources on their own are they facilitated and given enough space to realise such potential? The case of the Killary mussel farming co-operative suggests that they are not. References Berkes, F. & Folke, C., 1998, Linking Social and Ecological Systems: Management practices and social mechanisms for building resiliance, Cambridge University Press. 23 Annex 1 Beaufort Marine Socio-Economic Workshop Agenda The 3rd Annual Beaufort Marine Socio-Economic Workshop Friday 11th November 2011 Venue: MY129, Aras Moyola, National University of Ireland, Galway 8.45 -9.25 Registration and Tea/Coffee Session 1. Welcome and Overview of Days Proceedings – Professor John McHale Ocean Economy Analysis: National and Sectoral Perspectives 9.30 - 9.55 9.55 - 10.20 10.20 - 10.45 10.45 – 11.15 11.15 - 11.35 Session 2. Chairperson: Geoffrey O’Sullivan, Marine Institute Some Observations about the US Ocean and Coastal Economies from the National Ocean Economics Program Habitat-Fisheries Linkages in Bioeconomic Models The potential for an Irish Maritime Transportation Cluster: An Input-Output Analysis Port’s and Shipping Data as Economic Indicators Tea/Coffee - Judith Kildow, The National Ocean Economics Program, USA. - Naomi Foley, Norwegian Fisheries College, University of Tromsø, Norway - Karyn Morrissey, University of Liverpool - Fergal Curtin, IMDO and SEMRU. Marine Ecosystem Service Valuation Chairperson: Edel Doherty, SEMRU, NUI Galway 11.35 – 12.00 12.00 - 12.25 12.25 - 12.50 2.00 - 3.00 12.50- 2.00 Session 3. 3.25 - 3.50 3.50 - 4.10 4.10 - 4.30 4.30 - 4.50 Valuing the Dead Sea and peaceful cooperation in the Middle East Valuing marine environmental characteristics associated with changes to the EU Bathing Water Directive Site choices in recreational demand: a matter of utility maximization or regret minimization? Valuing oil spill impacts in marine environments: The United States experience and the 2007 oil spill in San Francisco (Lecture Hall 1, St. Anthonys) Lunch - Alberto Longo, Queens University, Belfast - Stephen Hynes, SEMRU, NUI Galway - Marco Boeri, Queens University, Belfast - Eric English, Stratus Consulting, Colorado, USA. SEMRU PhD Presentations Chairperson: Dr. Judith Kildow, Estimating the value of achieving ‘good ecological status’ under the EU Water Framework Directive The Role of the Consumer in Driving Sustainable Consumption of Seafood Another collective tragedy? The case of the Killary mussel farming co-operative The Cost of Wave Energy Conversion Devices and Implications for Policy Close of Workshop - Danny Norton, SEMRU, NUI Galway - Ann Walsh, SEMRU, NUI Galway - Peter Cush, SEMRU, NUI Galway - Niall Farrell, SEMRU, NUI Galway Annex 2 Workshop Participants Name Organisation Email Mick O'Toole Marine Institute motoole@marine.ie Dave Reid Marine Institute david.reid@marine.ie Geoffrey O'Sullivan Marine Institute gosullivan@marine.ie Trevor Alcorn Marine Institute talcorn@marine.ie Patrick Tyndall Bord Iascaigh Mhara tyndall@bim.ie Sean Lyons Economic and Social Research Institute sean.lyons@esri.ie Cathal Buckley Teagasc cathal.buckley@teagasc.ie Naomi Foley University Tromso naomifoley@gmail.com Lava Yadav National University of Ireland, Galway lava.yadav@gmail.com Stephen O'Neill National University of Ireland, Galway stepheno_neill_1999@yahoo.com Ilaria Nardello Marine Institute/NUIG inardello@marine.ie Michael Cuddy SEMRU, NUI, Galway michealcuddy@eircom.net Colm Lorlan Marine Institute colm.lorlan@marine.ie Oliver Tully Marine Institute oliver.tully@marine.ie Ben Breen SEMRU, NUI, Galway B.BREEN1@nuigalway.ie Ed Hind SEMRU, NUI, Galway Ed.hind1@nuigalway.ie Will Maclennan Natural England willmaclennon@hotmail.com Kevin Kilcline National University of Ireland, Galway kevinkilcline@gmail.com Patrick Gillespie SEMRU, NUI, Galway/Teagasc patrick.gillespie@teagasc.ie Natasha Evers National University of Ireland, Galway natasha.evers@nuigalway.ie Paul Ryan National University of Ireland, Galway paul.a.ryan@nuigalway.ie Meadbh Seoighe Udaras na Gaeltacht meadbh.seoighe@udaras.ie Ann Walsh National University of Ireland, Galway ann.walsh@nigalway.ie Brendan Kennelly National University of Ireland, Galway brendan.kennelly@nuigalway.ie Thomas van Rensberg National University of Ireland, Galway thomas.vanrensburg @nuigalway.ie John McHale National University of Ireland, Galway john.mchale@nuigalway.ie Amaya Vega National University of Ireland, Galway amaya.vega@nuigalway.ie Brian O'Toole National University of Ireland, Galway N/A Edel Doherty National University of Ireland, Galway edel.doherty@nuigalway.ie Maeve Edwards National University of Ireland, Galway maeve.edwards@nuigalway.ie Pat Duggan Department of the Environment pat.duggan@environ.ie Peter Cush National University of Ireland, Galway p.cush2@nuigalway.ie Judith Kildow NOEP, USA judy@oceaneconomic.org Peter Howley Teagasc peter.howley@teagasc.ie Cathal O'Donoghue Teagasc cathal.odonnogue@teagasc.ie Eugene Nixon Marine Institute eugene.nixon@marine.ie Doris Laepple National University of Ireland, Galway Doris.Laepple@teagasc.ie Alberto Longo Queens University, Belfast a.longo@qub.ac.uk Marco Boeri Queens University, Belfast mboeri01@qub.ac.uk Fergal Curtin IMDO and SEMRU, NUI Galway fergal.curtin@marine.ie Eric English Stratus Consultants, Colorado eenglish@stratusconsulting.com Niall Farrell SEMRU, NUI Galway niallfarrell@gmail.com Paul Dunne Department of the Environment Paul_dunne@environ.ie Dave Reid Marine Institute david.reid@marine.ie Rebecca Corless SEMRU, NUI Galway rebecca.corless@nuigalway.ie Dermot Hurst Marine Institute dermot.hurst@marine.ie Wesley Flannery Geography, NUI Galway wesleyflannery@gmail.com Michael O'Brien BMW Assembly mobrien@bmwassembly.ie