How to Use Partnerships: An Imaginary Conversation Robert Klitgaard1 December 2004 Thanh speaks. “We’re being told that our government agency should set up a ‘partnership’ with some businesses and a couple of civic associations. Why isn’t clear to me. How isn’t clear to me. Frankly, I’m not even sure if this partnership talk isn’t just another fad. I admit I’m confused about partnerships.” Thanh is a public manager in one of the GMS countries. He used to work as a volunteer with a non-government organization (NGO). Now he is a highly regarded civil servant, whose identity and job will be confidential. Not because Thanh would mind, since he’s a fictional invention, but because the specifics of his challenges might distract or even deter you, dear reader. Like Thanh’s, your problems and your country’s are distinctive. But perhaps we can use an imaginary conversation with Thanh as a vehicle to focus on some important issues about partnerships. From now on, Thanh’s comments and questions will be indented in italics. THANH: Let’s begin with the arguments in favor of partnerships. I used to hear a lot about this when I was in the NGO, but not so much in government. Now they’re telling us about all these good things that will happen if our agency partners with the private sector and with community groups. They say that our partners will bring to the table things we don’t have, or don’t have enough of, such as resources and technical know-how in the case of the businesses, and credibility and local knowledge, in the case of the civic associations. We’re told that from partnerships, all kinds of good things will flow, besides making our anti-poverty efforts more effective—things with big names like legitimacy, participation, and empowerment. I don’t know where to begin thinking all this through, but I admit I’m a little skeptical. You’re right that the synergies of partnership can be exaggerated. One evening at a dinner, George Bernard Shaw was seated across from Isadora Duncan, the celebrated and beautiful dancer. She flirted with him outrageously. Finally she said 1 A talk presented at the summit of the Mekong Delta countries, Vientiane, Laos, Dec. 2004. I am grateful to Gregory Treverton for valuable discussions of the topics in this paper. loudly for all to hear, “Oh, my dear Bernard, wouldn’t it be simply wonderful if you and I should have a child? Just imagine—a child with your brain and my body.” To which Shaw replied: “But what if it should be the other way around?”2 The “Shaw and the Dancer Problem” abounds in partnerships of other kinds. Yes, partnerships have potential benefits. But partnerships may not work out as planned. So, how can leaders of government agencies, international organizations, businesses, and NGOs decide whether to partner, with whom, how much, and how? THANH: Well, those are questions I’m asking all right. Since you seem to see what’s bothering me, let’s speak frankly. Is “partnership” just another development fad, or is it something we’ll be seeing more and more? It’s hard to say, in advance, that a partnership will really pay off. There are many different benefits and costs. In my country, we don’t have much experience with partnerships. What can we learn from other countries? These questions are increasingly important. I believe that the lines between public and private are eroding fast, that we are entering an era of “hybrid governance.” Around the world a remarkable transition is underway • • from layer-cake governance, where tasks are taken on separately by different sectors (public, private, non-profit), to marble-cake governance, with new partnerships across sectors. The government of the territorial state was a doer; students of public administration and public policy learned that government’s choice was “make, buy, or regulate.” For tomorrow’s public managers the triad will be “carrots, sticks, or sermons”—or all three, simultaneously. The shift in mind-set this will require of government can hardly be overstated. Governments will not come easily to the idea that they work with, and sometimes for, local NGOs and businesses. The transition will also challenge the private sector. Private actors are more and more responsible for public purposes, often in partnerships with governments. That responsibility will run through issues ranging from tourism to agriculture, from communications to transportation, from fighting terrorism to countering cultural imperialism. What Are “Partnerships”? THANH: I believe you that something significant is going on, and government’s 2 Isadora Duncan’s sister Irma denies the traditional identification of her sister as the dancer. “As for the anecdote which connects her name with George Bernard Shaw, he himself admitted that the ‘dancer’ in question was not Isadora. The latter had no occasion to meet G.B.S. nor did she correspond with him. Her letters and writings give ample proof of her own native intelligence and wit.” Irma Duncan, Duncan Dancer: An Autobiography (Middletown, CT: University of Connecticut Press, 1965): 159. 2 going to have to work more closely with the private sector and community groups and international institutions. But what does that mean? When people say “partnership,” it just seems so vague. How can I get my head around the concept? The word “partnership” has been applied to relations between rich and poor countries.3 More to our point, public-private-citizen partnerships are increasingly advocated.4 The World Bank’s James Wolfensohn has been among the most enthusiastic. “I cannot stress enough the importance of partnerships,” he declared. “The task ahead is too formidable for any single institution or set of institutions to tackle. Every one of us has a role to play. Halving poverty by 2015 is possible, but only if we concert our efforts in a new way.”5 But what is meant by “partnership”?6 Partnership is one label for better ways to manage cooperation and conflict to mutual advantage. Theoretically, you may think of the prisoners’ dilemma, where proceeding without “partnership” leads both players to worse outcomes than they can have if they properly take into account their strategic interaction. Or you might think of a game of coordination, as when GMS countries agree on standards for highways. You might think of gains from trade, where one partner is good at wheat and the other partner is good at iron. You might think of complementarities, where one partner is good at marketing and the other is good at 3 For a review of recent usage, see Simon Maxwell and Tim Conway, “Perspectives on Partnership,” OED Working Paper Series No. 6. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2000; and John Eriksson, The Drive to Partnership: Aid Coordination and the World Bank. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2001. Three decades ago the Pearson report talked about partnership for development. This led to a stream of titles contesting aid as partnership. In 1973 Paul Albert wrote a book called Partnership or Confrontation? Poor Lands and Rich (New York: The Free Press, 1973). This was two years after Joan Nelson published a review article on foreign aid. Its title: “The Partial Partnership.” (Joan M. Nelson, “The Partial Partnership: Trends in Multilateral Aid and Aid Coordination” International Organization, Vol. 25, No. 1 (Winter 1971): 79-96.) 4 An internal document from the World Bank defines partnership as “a collaborative relationship between entities to work toward shared objectives through a mutually agreed division of labor,” including specific programs and “ongoing, often open-ended relationships.” “Partnership Oversight and Selectivity: A Discussion Note,” March 2000, p. 2. For a review of recent usage, see Simon Maxwell and Tim Conway, “Perspectives on Partnership,” OED Working Paper Series No. 6. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2000; and John Eriksson, The Drive to Partnership: Aid Coordination and the World Bank. Washington, DC: The World Bank, 2001. 5 http://www.worldbank.org/partners/ 6 My favorite rhetorical flight on “partnership” is the title of a publication by The Copenhagen Centre: Partnership Alchemy. The alchemy metaphor is designed, perhaps unsuccessfully, to describe situations where “Participants seek to achieve more than the sum of their individual parts by creating leverage and synergy based on and between key components of the partnership—context, purpose, participants, organisation, and outcomes.” The Copenhagen Centre, Partnership Alchemy. Copenhagen: The Copenhagen Centre, April 2000. http://www.copenhagencentre.org/TCCWEB/TCCWEB.NSF/K_Concepts/K222?OpenDocument 3 production and they decide to join forces. All these approaches recognize strategic interdependence—and the importance of not thinking like myopic individuals.7 Many Types of Partnerships THANH: Are partnerships occurring in many policy areas? Yes. Table 1 shows how E.S. Savas characterizes partnerships in various areas of public policy. Service delivery arrangements range from complete government provision (no business participation) to complete business provision (no government provision)—and beyond that, to citizens’ providing their own services (without government or business). Note the last column of Table 1. Urban transportation services simultaneously include every degree of public-private partnership. There is pure government provision, as in a public transit authority that runs a bus service. There is the free market or pure business provision model, as when there is a competitive market for rental cars. And there is pure citizen self-provision of transportation services, as when one drive’s one’s own car or bicycle. And there are many hybrids in between. Insert Table 1 about here THANH: One of my colleagues said something the other day that was blunt, but it rang true to me. He said, “The first question we have to ask about this proposed partnership is how it will help our agency do what we’re supposed to do?” He said he didn’t really care about all the so-called social benefits. He said our agency has a mission and our own way of doing things—and we have to see what the partnership would accomplish in our agency’s terms. Your colleague’s question is a good one. It is worthwhile distinguishing two levels of questions regarding partnerships. Level 1 focuses on the benefits and costs for a specific partner. Like your colleague, it asks, “How good is this partnership for our agency or organization or country?” Level 2 tries to estimate the social benefits and costs from the partnership as a whole. 7 This question opens vast areas of theoretical inquiry. It invites typologies, the theories of teams and of clubs, analogies to vertical and horizontal integration, studies of networks, and analyses of gains from trade. And this is only through the lens of the rational actor, or Model I in the sense of Graham Allison. Model I looks at each partner as a rational player seeking its own benefits. Allison’s Model II looks at the each partner’s organizational repertoires, standard operating procedures, and cultures, and assesses the likely complementarities and conflicts. Model III evaluates the interactions among individual players sitting in particular positions, and how they matter for the success of the joint endeavor. Graham T. Allison and Philip Zelikow, Essence of Decision: Explaining the Cuban Missile Crisis, 2nd Ed. Reading, MA: Longman, 1999. 4 Each Partner’s Benefits and Costs The first question for all possible partners is “What’s in it for my institution?” Put somewhat more precisely, the question becomes: “What are the costs and benefits to us and our mission from various kinds of partnerships, structured how, managed how?” Benefits A recent publication of the World Bank’s Business Partnership and Outreach Group lists eight possible benefits for business, among them “to enhance or rebuild brand image/corporate reputation” and “to address public accountability issues or market failures.” Among the seven possible benefits for “communities/our clients” are 8 efficiency, effectiveness, equity, and sustainability. Other hoped-for benefits are often not enunciated publicly, including prestige, political insulation, and cooptation. These motives have been dominant in many recent business-NGO partnerships. They are probably crucial in the popularity of partnerships at international financial institutions; for example, partnerships with NGOs may be designed in part “to enhance or rebuild brand image/corporate reputation.” Costs THANH: Partnerships can’t all be good, though. Have you ever tried to coordinate things among government agencies, or even different parts of a local office? What a hassle. It must be even more difficult across the public-private divide, no? It is remarkable how often costs are overlooked in many discussions of partnerships. For example, the alliance called InterAct “believes that the shift to a focus on collaborative processes is key to democratic renewal, social inclusion, sustainable development and a vibrant civil society.” But its paper “Evaluating Participatory, 9 Deliberative, and Co-operative Ways of Working” lists none of the costs. Practitioners worry about partnerships. The transactions costs of partnering and 10 coordinating can loom large. A recent survey found that the World Bank was a 8 Business Partnership and Outreach Group, “Partnering with Business: Questions and Answers.” Briefing Note No. 2. Washington, DC: The World Bank, Nov. 2000. http://www.worldbank.org/business/files/note2.pdf It is of course a long way from a typology of benefits to their careful measurement in a specific case, and in international development we know of no exemplar. 9 Brighton, England: InterAct, June 2001. 10 A point once made by Robert Chambers could be made about “partnership” substituted for “coordination.” “’Integration’ and ‘co-ordination’ can be seen to have heavy costs as well as benefits… The word ‘co-ordination’ provides a handy means for avoiding responsibility for clear proposals. It is perhaps the reason that it is much favoured by visiting missions who are able to conceal their ignorance of how an administrative system works or what might be done about it 5 member of 87 global and regional partnerships. Worried about the costs of too many partnerships, the Bank’s management asked how such partnerships could be evaluated. How should the Bank decide in advance which partnerships to join and how to participate? [I]n order to ensure that the Bank fulfills its mission, it needs to be able to be selective in its role and only participate in initiatives with the greatest possible development impact, the best leverage of resources, and the strongest synergies with other partners. A clear direction for the Bank then is to make sure that its work at the global level contributes to poverty reduction, and builds on its core 11 expertise—developing and helping to implement country-based programs. NGOs fear that partnerships will dilute their mission, silence their voices, and 12 bureaucratize their cultures. Government agencies worry that they will be undermined by outsourcing, by public-private partnerships, even by regulation—consider the phenomenon of “regulatory capture,” where regulatory agencies are deviated from their 13 public purposes through their interactions with the regulatees. A would-be partner will want to ask: what will a partner contribute, and why is that good for me? This begins to address a critical issue: what are the distinctive advantages (and defects) of particular sectors? The Evolution of Partnerships THANH: Let’s talk a little more about the different degrees of partnership. How do you deal with that? Business school professor James Austin notes a progression from “philanthropic” to 14 “transactional” to “integrative” partnerships between businesses and NGOs. At the first stage, companies give money to the non-profits, but there is little interaction. The by identifying ‘a need for better co-ordination.’ Indeed, a further research project of interest would be to test the hypothesis that the value of reports varies inversely with the frequency with which the word ‘co-ordination’ is used.” Robert Chambers, Managing Rural Development. Uppsala: Scandinavian Institute of African Studies, 1974: 24-25. 11 “Addressing Global Dimensions in Development, A Discussion Note,” The World Bank, March 20, 2000: 9. The document later notes (p. 10) that “Key aspects of the Bank’s comparative advantage are global reach and a broad developmental mandate, ability to mobilize and manage resources, and operational competence at the country level.” Again, it is easier to list these aspects than to monitor and evaluate them across a range of potential partnerships. 12 For example, NGOs, States and Donors: Too Close for Comfort? ed. David Hulme and Michael Edwards. London: Macmillan, 1997. 13 Jean-Jacques Laffont and Jean Tirole, “The Politics of Government Decision-Making: A Theory of Regulatory Capture.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106, 4 (Nov. 1991): 1089-1127. 14 See James E. Austin, The Collaboration Challenge: How Nonprofits and Businesses Succeed through Strategic Alliances. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass Publishers, 2000, especially chapter 2. 6 for-profits get the benefits of having been good citizens, benefits that are at this stage as much directed toward the company’s staff as toward its potential customers. At the second stage, business gets a “branding” benefit from visible association with a highly regarded non-profit. The non-profits got more predictable funding from the companies. Depending on the institutions involved, the non-profits may also receive leadership training, publicity, jobs for its trainees, and so on. Few partnerships reach the integrative stage. At that point, the alliance becomes truly strategic and the boundaries between “us” and “them” blur. The partnership resembles a joint venture that is critical to the strategies of both partners. Exchanges multiply of everything from money to people to ideas. The partnership is able to withstand shocks. From the perspective of government, partnerships with business promise more resources and more efficiency. But government managers may fear a loss of accountability. Indeed, one of the unstated arguments for privatization is that the government’s concerns over accountability and equity can generate so much red tape that it is next to impossible to actually do or build anything. In that sense, privatization is a flight from accountability, and government managers may worry on precisely those grounds. Government managers may be tempted to look to the not-for-profit sector. NGOs may bring many benefits: 15 • Cost. The most visible cost advantage is volunteer labor, though NGOs may have some innovative process or service delivery mechanism as well. • Quality. Non-profits are sometimes expected to deliver higher quality service. Providing the service may be a mission, not simply a way to make a profit. In his study of nursing homes and handicapped facilities, for instance, Burton Weisbrod found some evidence of quality advantages in not-for-profits, at least those that were church-related.16 • Access. NGOs may be more able to serve a hard-to-reach target population because the NGO is perceived as “one of us.” Evaluating Partnerships as a Whole This is helpful in thinking about what we’d like our business and NGO partners to do with us. What else I’m taking away from the discussion so far is that it is easy to be myopic about partnerships. Easy just to praise the benefits and ignore the costs—or I have to admit, the other way around. Easy to focus just on the deliverables and leave out other benefits and costs—for example, I’m See Pauline Vaillancourt Rosenau, ed. Public-Private Policy Partnerships. Press, 2000: especially chapter 13. 15 Cambridge: MIT Burton Weisbrod, “The Future of the Nonprofit Sector: Its Entwining with Private Enterprise and Government,” Journal of Policy Analysis and Management. 16(4): 541-55 (1997). 16 7 impressed by the risks of collusion and corruption. And I’m beginning to see how a larger social purpose could be advanced by partnerships. Can you help me think harder about that second level of benefits and costs, at the social level? How should we take those into account in deciding where and how and with whom to partner? A second level of evaluation of partnerships focuses on the social benefits and costs accruing to the partnership as a whole, as compared with alternatives. Under what conditions, and for what problems, would it be socially useful for government, business, and NGOs to partner? Consider agricultural development in Africa. To enable new seeds to make a difference in Malawi, it has been suggested that some parts of the solution belong to the state (funding R&D), some to the market (distributing new seed varieties), and some to NGOs (mobilizing farmers to enable group credit). As another example, consider welfare-to-work programs in the United States. Some social experiments have created a competition among government agencies, NGOs, and private employment companies to see which one will do the best at placing welfare recipients on jobs. But is competition the best way to proceed? Instead, might government, business, and NGOs have comparative advantages with different kinds of welfare recipients? For examples, NGOs might do best in bringing certain kinds of participants in and giving them confidence in the process of job seeking. Private firms might have an advantage in teaching marketable skills and work habits to another clientele. And we could also imagine various kinds of partnership, instead of competition. Then we would ask how it might be possible to blend the distinctive features of business, government, and non-profits in this endeavor—for example, trying to draw on the efficiency of private providers and the commitment or superior access of non-profit institutions.17 At the social level, the list of potential benefits and costs changes. If you think as an economist again, you might imagine a production function for social benefits, and also a cost function. The production function refers to the outcome of interrelationships among different goods and services. The outcome may be as grandiose as “homeland security” or “provision of relief services,” or as narrow as “nursing home services.” The different goods and services might be provided by a government agency, an international institution, a private business, and an NGO. Each combination of these different goods and services “produces” an outcome. The question is, what is the nature of this production function? How much “homeland security” or “nursing home services” is produced by what combinations of public, private, and non-profit inputs? The second function is a cost function. It displays the (various kinds of) costs that 17 See, for instance, Paul C. Light, Making Nonprofits Work: A Report on the Tides of Nonprofit Management Reform. Washington: The Brookings Institution, 2000. 8 accrue to each combination of public, private, and non-profit inputs. The costs would be financial, as when the government provides a certain number of soldiers, the private sector a certain amount of medicine, and the NGO a certain number of volunteer physicians, each with a financial cost. The costs could also be transactional—including the management and administrative costs of combining, coordinating, creating a hybrid, or otherwise entering into a partnership. The optimal partnership would take into account both the production function and the cost function. Theoretically, we would need a way to find a common metric, such as the economist’s social welfare function. More practically, we would weigh the various levels of production against the costs of providing them. Practitioners have developed useful checklists to guide the analysis of benefits and costs in a partnership. An example is the outline for a benefit-cost analysis distributed by The 18 Prince of Wales Business Leaders Forum (please see Table 2). [Insert Table 2 about here] Table 2 omits some potentially important considerations. On the positive side, partnerships may build trust, enable negotiation, reduce violence, undergird a social contract, inhibit government discretion, and enable freer flows of information. For example, InterAct’s “Evaluating Participatory, Deliberative, and Co-operative Ways of Working” lists as possible benefits increases in information and understanding, trust among stakeholders, ownership, “capacity” among stakeholders, openness and transparency, “representativeness of participation,” and “level of understanding about the process and the specific project—as well as “changes in values, priorities, aims and objectives” and new relationships between organizations (formal and informal). At a more practical level, InterAct says to look for reduced vandalism, better maintenance, leverage for additional funding, and impact on the policy process. The document admits that “there remains insufficient hard evidence on these benefits for them to be widely acknowledged.” On the negative side, partnerships may spawn corruption and cronyism, reduce diversity, and inhibit innovation. For example, Jose Edgardo Campos and Hilton Root studied various public-private policy partnerships in East Asia, especially “deliberation councils” involving people from industry, the government, academia, and in some cases, 19 Campos and Root extolled the benefits of the press, consumer groups, and labor. these partnerships as the key to the East Asian economic miracle. But after the East Asian economic crisis of 1997, some critics cited these same partnerships as catalysts of crony capitalism and corruption, which rendered these countries more vulnerable. The conclusion: experience indicates that partnerships may have important benefits and 18 “Measures for Success: Assessing the Impact of Partnerships.” London: The International Business Leaders Forum, August 2000. http://www.pwblf.org/csr/csrwebassist.nsf/content/f1d2a3b4c5.html 19 The Key to the Asian Miracle: Making Shared Growth Credible. Washington, D.C.: Brookings, 1996. 9 costs that go beyond the level of service provided and the financial costs. Using Checklists How would you suggest using a checklist like Table 2 in an organization like mine? A colleague of mine who’s been a CEO of both a private company and a non-profit recently said, “In today's world, the role of the CEO is no longer to huddle behind the crystal ball and oracle out strategic directions, but rather one of coach (and be the accountability boss) of a team of unit managers around him. He gets his team to work through the analysis together.” The same is true for the analysis of partnerships. It isn’t a job for the leader to do alone and tell others the results. Nor should the analysis be left to a technical evaluator alone. Rather, I recommend participatory diagnosis, facilitated perhaps by the leader and with inputs from the technical evaluator, where the agency’s leaders and managers work through the checklist. For each heading on the checklist, there is a discussion. What does this category trigger in your imaginations? How big might this category of benefits be, and what does it depend on? Which benefits and costs seem most important to our agency’s mission? Which of the synergies or complementarities across partners seems most crucial? Which most fragile? And so forth. In other words, a two-hour meeting built around a checklist like Table 2 can yield shared insights and creative ideas about whether and how to proceed. I suggest that for a particular issue of partnership you and your colleagues work through the questions in checklists like Table 2. Probe each dimension, together. The result may be that you conclude that a particular benefit (or cost) is paramount, and then you can actively focus on it with your partners. Or you may find that there are angles of the problem that you had overlooked—and by talking them through together, you can design and manage them more effectively. 10 Table 1 Partnerships in Municipal Services Type of Partnership (or Not) Education Government service Parks and Recreation Hospitals Housing Protection Streets and Highways Conventional public school system Traditional police department Municipal highway department Municipal parks department County hospital Public housin authority Government vending Local public school accepts outof-district pupil and is paid by parents Sponsor pays city for crowd control by police at concert Circus pays town to clean streets after parade Sponsor pays town to clean park after company picnic Intergovernmental agreements Pupils go to school in the next town; sending town pays receiving town Town buys patrol services from county sheriff County pays town to clean county roads located in town City joins special recreation district in the region City arranges for residents to be treated at regional hospital Town contracts with count housing authority Contracts City hires private firm to conduct vocational training program City hires private guard service for government buildings City hires private contractor to clean and plow city streets City hires private firm to prune trees and mow grass County hospital hires firm for cafeteria service Housing authority hires contractor for repairs and paintin Franchises Police Firm is authorized to operate cityowned golf course and charge fees Grants Private colleges get government grant for every enrolled student Government grant to expand nonprofit hospital Grant to private firm to build an operate low income housing Vouchers Tuition voucher for elementary school, GI Medicaid card permits holder to get medical Voucher enables low income tenant to 11 Bill for college care anywhere rent any acceptable affordable unit Free market Private schools Banks hire private guards Local merchant association hires street cleaners Commercial tennis courts and golf driving range Proprietary (for-profit) hospitals Ordinary private housing Voluntary Service Parochial schools Block association forms citizens’ crime-watch unit Homeowners’ association hires firm to clean local streets Private tennis club and fitness center Communitybased nonprofit hospital Housing cooperativ Self-service Home schooling Install locks and alarm system, buy gun Merchant sweeps sidewalk in front of his shop Swimming pool at home Self medication, chicken sup, other traditional cures Do-it-yourse home constructio 12 Table 2 Outline of Some Benefits and Costs of “Cross-Sector Partnerships” Needs Inputs Process O Societal Needs Inputs Outputs of p • equitable economic growth • human capital • developm social capital • improved supporting human development • Greater Efficiency • • man-made capital • • organizat • protecting the environment • natural capital pooling resources and optimizing “division of labor” • • increased • • encouraging good governance decreasing costs associated with conflict resolution and societal disagreement on policies and priorities more effe services • creating economies of scale • assisting social cohesion • promoting technological cooperation enhanced credibility creation o upholding human rights facilitating the sharing of information • • • • • accountability to all stakeholders overcoming institutional rigidities and bottlenecks • Private Sector Needs Inputs—Private Sector • finance and other resources • human resource development • formation of local supply chain • setting and raising standards • access to and impact on policy dialogue • making social investment Outputs—Pri Improved Effectiveness a. leveraging greater amounts and a wider variety of skills and resources than can be achieved by acting alone b. accommodating broader perspectives and more creative approaches to problem-solving c. shifting away from “command and control” to more informed joint goalsetting d. obtaining the “buy in” of recipients and local “ownership” of proposed solutions, thereby ensuring greater sustainability of outcomes 13 • increased societal v • greater co long-term • enhanced employee stakehold Public Sector Needs Inputs—Public Sector • regulatory framework • physical infrasructure • social infrastucture • safety nets • security and protection of people and environment • offering more flexible and tailored solutions • speeding the development and implementation of solutions • acting as a catalyst for policy innovation Outputs—Pu national gover competitivene less bureaucra perception cost reduction Increased Equity Civil Society Needs Inputs—Civil Society Sector b. individual expression c. tools for empowerment d. guardians of heritage and culture e. campaigning f. service delivery g. grassroots knowledge h. legitimization • improving the level and quality of consultation with other stakeholders in society • facilitating broader participation in goalsetting and problem-solving • building the trust needed to work towards shared responsibilities and mutual benefit • building community-level institutional structures, networks, and capacities to enable local control and ownership From “Measures for Success: Assessing the Impact of Partnerships.” London: The International Business Leaders Forum, August 2000. http://www.pwblf.org/csr/csrwebassist.nsf/content/f1d2a3b4c5.html 14 Outputs—Civ a. socia b. huma c. empo d. acces a. reput