5 On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion: A Survey Wallace E. Oates Wallace E. Oates lectures at the Departmenr of Economics and Bureau of Business and Economic Research, U niversiry of Maryland. This chapter was written during sabbatical leave at Resources for the Future. I am grateful to RFF and to the Sloan Foundation for their support of this work. I am also indebted to Dennis Mueller, Paul Porrney, and Robert Schwab for some most helpful commenrs on an earlier drafto It is both a pleasure and an honour to contribute to this volume in recognition of the valuable and wide-ranging contributions of Russell Mathews to the study of fiscal strucrure and behaviour. Under Mathews's careful guidance, the Centre for Research on .Federal Financial Relations at the Australian National U niversiry has provided a steady stream of published research on federal finance that occupies a central place in the field. Scholars throughout the world draw regularly on Mathews's and the Centre's work both for its substantive findings and for the rich bodies of comparative institutional information and data that~ they provide. All of us in the field are deeply in his debt. For my contribution, I have chosen the very tantalising, but empirically the notion that the systematic elusive, phenomenon of 'fiscal illusion' misperception of key fiscal parameters may significantly distort fiscal choices by the electorate. Various elementS of the tax structure, for example ~ay be largely hidden so that voters do not perceive the entire cost of providing certain public services. There is now a small literature on this issue: itS historic rootS lie in Puviani (1903) and other Italian writers; and it has received imperus moreorecently from James Buchanan (1967). - . The most recent work on fiscal illUsionis largely empirical in charaaer: it seeks to find particular manifestations of fiscal illusion in existing fiscal 65 - - -- .0 --- Taxation and Fiscal Federalism 66 structUre and choices. A central theme of my paper will be that this literatUre has been less successful than it might appear in establishing the presence and importance of various forms of fiscal illusion. For reasons that I will try to make clear, the detection and measurement of fiscal illusion is a difficult enterprise. In several instances where stUdies claim to find empirical support for a particular form of fiscal illusion, I believe that there are alternative, and more compelling explanations for the findings. In other cases, the evidence simply is not consistent with the illusion hypothesis. This is not to say that elements of fiscal illusion are nOt present in fiscal I suspece they are - but rather that the existing empirical systems literatUre has not as yet made a persuasive case for their existence and importance. The chapter begins with a general consideration of the natUre of fiscal illusion and then tUrns to empirical efforts to substantiate various illusion hypOtheses. Five forms (or sources) of fiscal illusion have received attention in the literatUre: - 1. complexity of the tax structUre; 2. renter illusion with respect to property taxation; 3. income elasticity of the tax structUre; 4. debt illusion; 5. the flypaper effect. I shall summarise and evaluate the work on each of them in turn.l But first we need a brief overview of fiscal illusion and of the general empirical approach to testing illusion hypotheses. The Nature of Fiscal Illusion Almost 30 years ago, Anthony Downs (1957) argued convincingly that the representative voter is likely to have highly imperfect information on which to base his decisions on public-sector activities. The costs of acquiring information imply, of course, less than perfect knowledge for private-sector choices as well. But as Downs pointed out, the incentives to obtain" information on the benefits and costs of government programs are much less than for private activities. Since an individual ballot is unlikely to have a discernible effect on public-sector outcomes, there is little reason for the vOter to invest substantial resources in learning about the relative costs and benefits of the various alternatives in the government sector. The individual determines his own pattern of purchases and consumption of private goods so that some investment in the acquisition of information is worthwhile. But for public-seceor choices," his impotence with regard to outcomes implies that there will typically be little effort expended to learn about government progams. As Downs (1957) concludes: 'Ignorance of politics is not a result of unpatriotic apathy; rather it is a highly rational response to "the faces of political life in a large democracy' (p. 147). - - - --- On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 67 Imperfect information is not, however, synonymous with fiscal illusion. It is a necessary, but not a sufficient, condition for its existence. More specifically, fiscal illusion refers to a systematic misperception of fiscal a recurring propensity, for example, to underestimate one's parameters tax liability associated with certain public programs. Imperfect information alone might well give rise to a random pattern of over- and underestimation of such tax liabilities. Fiscal illusion, in contrast, implies persistent .and consistent behaviour. As such, it will give rise to recurring, and presumably predictable, biases in budgetary decisions. It is by no means clear in which direction fiscal illusion will tend to bias public-sectOr outcomes. In the earlier literature on this matter, Downs (1960) and Galbraith (1958) argued that imperfect information would tend to make the public budget too small. It was Downs's contention that the benefits of most government programs tended to be 'remote' and largely unrecognised by the electorate, while the taxes to support these programs are more directly experienced and understood.2 The more pronounced tendency towards a systematic underestimation of public-seCtor benefits than costs would lead the electorate to support an unduly small allocation of resources to the government sector. However, in the more recent public choice literature, the view has shifted radically. The attention to special interest groups and associated lobbying efforts has called into question the presumed lack of support for public spending. At the same time, studies of revenue structure and 'tax consciousness' suggest that significant elements of the tax system are largely hidden and 'underperceived' by taxpayers. From this perspective, it is the costs of government programs, not their benefits, that are subject to significant and regular underestimation. This may stem, in part, from deliberate efforts by public agencies (of the sort Niskanen envisioned) to disguise the full costs of their programs and, where possible, to exaggerate the associated benefits. The tax system, in consequence, has come to include important elements like tax withhol4ing and forms of taxation with obscure patterns of incidence that conceal the real cost of public programs (Brennan and Buchanan, 1980). Fiscal illusion, under this view, results in a public sector of excessive size. Not surprisingly, the recent empirical literature on fiscal illusion has focused exclusively on the revenue side of the budget; it consists of studies of tax and debt illusion. These studies search for evidence linking relatively hidden elements in the revenue structUre to higher levels of taxes or spending. Before turning to this body of research, there is one general property of fiscal illusion that is worthy of note and that has some implications for' empirical testing. Fiscal illusion (or at least tax illusion), by its very nature, .can only operate over a limited range. Certain kinds of taxes may remain hidden while they absorb relatively modest fraCtions of personal - . u.. _. _. .. _ _..... Taxation and Fiscal Federalism 68 income. But as they come to constitute larger and larger chunks of income, they become progressively harder to hide. To take a specific example, it has been argued that more income-elastic revenue systems are conducive to more rapid growth in the public sector, because they generate larger 'automatic' increases in public revenues as the economy grows (Oates, 1975). if the tax system were However, there are obviously limits to this sufficiently income elastic, the argument would imply that the public sector could come to absorb virtually all of the taxpayer's income with little opposition. Fiscal illusion obviously cannot persist to such extremes; its potential is limited to some range of tax bills. Empirical work on tax illusion may, in consequence, need to make provision for various types of 'threshhold' effects or, more generally, for varying magnitudes of illusion over different values of the tax parameters. - Empirical Studies of Fiscal Illusion: The General Approach The bulk of the empirical work on fiscal illusion consists of econometric studies based upon some kind of model of public spending. The models range from ad hoc expenditure equations to more rigorously founded demand functions for public goods (e.g., Bergstrom and Goodman, 1973). In both cases, these studies end up regressing a measure of budgetary size (either or, in some instances, changes in spending or spending or revenues revenues) on a set of explanatory variables including income, often some kind of price term, and a series of 'taste' variables. In the Bergstrom and Goodman formulation, for example, this set of explanatory variables represents the determinants of the demand of the median voter for local public outputs. These are the variables that would determine public outputs in the absence of any fiscal illusion. The next step is to add to the equation variables that will capture any illusion effects. As we shall see in the subsequent sections, these variables take a number of different forms in the attempt to test for the presence of tax or debt illusion. The typical model is thus of the form: - 1. E = aX + /3F + u, where E is a measure of budgetary size, X is a vector of explanatory variables in a' world without fiscal illusion, F is a vector of variables designed to measure various types of fiscal illusion, and u is the usual disturbance term. The null hypothesis for each form of fiscal illusion is taken to be a zero coefficient on the relevant variable in the F-vector; since the illusion hypotheses usually imply particular signs for the variables, the alternative hypothesis is associated with either a positive or negative sign on /3, and a one-tail test is employed to accept or reject the null hypothesis. Case I: Complexity of the Revenue System The first source of fiscal illusion that we shall examine is the complexity of the revenue system. Buchanan, incidentally, attributes the revenue- - - - On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 69 complexity hypothesis to Puviani (1903). As Buchanan puts it 'To the extent that the total tax load on an individual can be fragmented so that he confronts numerous small levies rather than a few significant ones, illusory effects may be created' (1967, p. 135). According to this hypothesis, the more complicated the revenue system, the more difficult it is for the and the more taxpayer to determine the 'tax-price' of public outputs likely it is that he will underestimate the tax burden associated with public programs. In short, the hypothesis implies that, other things equal, the more complex the revenue system, the larger will be the public budget. Richard Wagner (1976) undertook the first test of the revenue-complexity hypothesis. Wagner's approach, as discussed in the preceding section, was to regress total current expenditure for a sample of 50 large US cities on a set of socio-economic variables and a measure of the complexity of the revenue system. For the Wagner. study, the vector F in equation (1) collapses into a single variable, f. Just how one measures the complexity of a revenue system is far from obvious. Wagner, interestingly, chose an index, the Herfindahl index, that is widely used in the industrial-organisation literature to measure the degree of concentration within an industry. More specifically, Wagner's measure of revenue-complexity is: - 4 2. f = k i = rj 1 where rj is the fraction of total city revenue generated from tax source i. For the rj, he adopted the Census Bureau classification of city-owned revenues into four categories: property taxes, general sales taxes, selective excise taxes, and charges and fees. The Herfindahl index will achieve its maximum value of unity if a city generates all of its own revenues from a single source; the minimum possible value would be one-fourth if revenues were divided equally amoung the four categories. A higher value of the index is thus associated with a less complex revenue system so that the revenue-complexity hypothesis posits a negative coefficient for the variable f. Wagner's choice of the Herfindahl index has been an influential one, for, as we shall see shortly, every subsequent study of the revenue-complexity hypothesis has used this index as the measure of the illusion variable. In his estimated regression equation, Wagner found that the sign of the coefficient on the revenue-complexity variable was indeed negative and that he could reject the null hypothesis of non association at a .01 level of significance. Moreover, the point estimate of the coefficient suggested a very substantial magnitude for the effect: lower values of the Herfindahl index.were associated with sizeable larger levels of public expenditure. However, as Wagner acknowledged, the Herfindahl index has some serious deficiencies as a measure of tax illusion. In particular, the 'visibility' of the four classes of revenue is likely to vary greatly: a heavier reliance on charges and fees, for example, will surely provide a more direct sense 70 Taxation and Fiscal Federalism of the cost of public outputs than a similar reliance on selective excise taxation. We might expect a city making extensive use of charges and fees to generate a lower level of spending than one which made relatively the same use of selective excise taxes. This absence of a measure of the visibility of various revenue sources suggests that Wagner's regression equation may be misspecified, raising the likelihood of biased estimators of the coefficients.3 Subsequent econometric work on the revenue-complexity hypothesis has yielded somewhat mixed results. Munley and Greene (1978), using a sample of cities much like that of Wagner, found that the resultS were quite sensitive to the specification of the equation. Making what appear to be some sensible alterations to the form of the regression equation, they found that the estimated coefficient of the revenue-complexity variable was no longer significantly different from zero, suggesting that Wagner's results may not be very robust. In another study exploring public spending for higher education, Clotfelter (1976) could find no evidence supporting a fiscal illusion. The estimated coefficient on the Herfindahl index was not statistically significant. Moreover, Clotfelter went a step further by trying to control for the visibility of different revenue sources. His results run counter to the illusion hypothesis; a heavier reliance on more visible revenue sources (direct taxation) was associated with more, not less, spending. However, three other studies, drawing on samples from quite different sorts of jurisdictions, have found support for the hypothesis. Using data from 110 large Swiss municipalities, Pommerehne and Schneider (1978) estimated a series of multiple-regression equations in which the coefficients on the Herfindahl index had the hypothesised negative sign and were consistently significantly different from zero. Interestingly, they found that this result was much stronger in a subset of municipalities with representative democracy but no public referenda than where direct democracy or referenda were used. Baker (1983) regressed state and local tax revenues on the usual sortS of variables and obtained a negative and marginally significant estimated coefficient on his Herlindahl index. And, finally, Breeden and Hunter (1985), in a stUdy of levels of tax revenues in 37 large US cities, found a negative and significant relationship betWeen these revenues and the Herfindahl index. While the results from the various studies of the revenue-complexity hypothesis are somewhat mixed, there appears to be considerable evidence, based on the Herlindahl-index variable, in support of this type of fiscal illusion. As we have seen, this evidence takes the form of a negative partial association betWeen some measure of budgetary size and the value of the Herfindahl index. However, some further reflection suggests another, and I believe more compelling interpretation of this association. State and local officials tend to be painfully aware of tax rates in other jurisdictions and try to resist getting too far out of line with rates elsewhere. Levels of On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 71 sales taxation in excess of those in neighbouring jurisdictions, for example, can induce shoppers to avoid local purchases of taxed goods. Likewise, relatively heavy taxation of business capital is often thought to deflect business investment and jobs away from the state or local economy. In consequence, as expenditUres in a jurisdiction rise relative to those in nearby areas, officials are likely to seek out new sources of revenue to prevent tax rates on existing revenue bases from becoming excessively high relative to other jurisdictions. We thus tend to find that jurisdictions with relatively high levels of spending adopt more diversified revenue systems. The argument here is that the structUre of the tax system is itself an endogenous variable, and, in particular, that the desired level of public expenditUre influences the community's choice of a tax structUre. If this is true, the existing econometric tests of the revenue-complexity hypothesis are subject to simultaneous-equation bias ~ and must be viewed with serious reservatlons. We have twO competing hypotheses here: the revenue-complexity hypothesis and what I will call the 'revenue-diversification hypothesis'. To discern between them is a difficult task, for they both imply a negative association betWeen the level of the budget and the diversity (or complexity) of the revenue system. What we really need, of course, is a theory of the determination of the tax struCtUre that would explain community choices among alternative sources of revenues. However, we are a long way from such a comprehensive theory. Let me offer a couple of other suggestions. First, there are now some standard econometric tests for endogeneity (e.g., Wu, 1983). It would seem sensible to subject the revenue-complexity variable in the earlier stUdies to such testing to get some indication of whether or not this is a real issue. Second, and more fundamentally, it would be helpful to find some way to get at the revenue-diversification hypothesis empirically. One possibility suggests itself. Consider a period of rapid budgetary growth (like the decade of the 1960s for state and local governments in the United States). If we compare the revenue system at the beginning and at the end of such a period (especially for relatively high-spending jurisdictions), the revenue-diversity hypothesis would suggest that we should observe a shift from a more simplified revenue system initially to a more diversified system at the end of the period. The pressures of budgetary growth would, from this perspective, lead to the introduction of new sources of revenue. Such a test is admittedly not wholly free of some potential illusion effects, but it does seem to me that in a period of general growth (like that associated with the 'baby boom'), the presumption of a finding of increased revenue diversity would constitUte support for the revenue-diversification hypothesis. As things stand now, I think that we must conclude that 'the jury is still out' as concerns the empirical verification of the revenue-complexity hypothesis. -- - ---- Taxation and Fiscal Federalism 72 Case II: Renter Illusion In the course of estimating demand functions for local public goods, a variety of authors have consistently turned up a very striking result: other things equal, jurisdiCtions with a relatively large fraction of renters tend to spend more per capita on local public services (see, for example, Bergstrom and Goodman, 1973, and Peterson, 1975). This pervasive and intriguing finding has generally been attributed to a kind of 'renter illusion'. Property taxes, the primary source of local tax revenues, are levied on owners of not on tenants. While such taxes may be passed forward rental dwellings in the form of higher rents to tenants, the renter-illusion hypothesis contends that renters do not perceive this to be the case. Illusion, in this instance, takes the form of a failure on the part of tenants to understand the link betWeen the level of local spending and the level of rent that they pay. Renters thus misperceive their tax-price for local public outputs they believe it to be zero, or at least less than the tcue tax-price and, hence, support levels of local expenditure in excess of their counterparts who own homes and pay property taxes directly. This empirical finding appears in multiple-regression studies of the general form discussed earlier. Referring back to equation (1), the F-vector in these studies consists of a single variable indicating the proportion of the residents in the jurisdiction who are renters. This variable has, in and typically nearly all such studies, a positive and significant coeffIcient implies a substantial effect on levels of public spending. Here again, however, the illusion interpretation of this finding is open to serious question. In one recent paper, Martinez-Vazquez (1983) suggests that there is no illusion here at all. Rather, he argues that renters do, in fact, have a lower tax-price than owner-occupants, because 'renters consume less housing than do homeowners of the same income level' (p. 244). Since one's property-tax liability is a function of the amount of housing consumed, it follows that the local tax share of a renter will be less than his home-owner counterpart. There are additional reasons for scepticism concerning the illusion view. There is considerable uncertainty concerning the incidence of property taxes on rental housing. There are certainly circumstances under which one would expeCt forward shifting Onto tenants; if the higher revenues are associated with improved local services, then the tax-expenditure increase should translate into a higher demand for rental housing in the jurisdiCtion that will drive up rents in a world of mobile consumers. Where tax differentials do not reflect service differentials, in contrast, the burden of the tax may remain on the owner. Moreover, even if forward shifting occurs ultimately, .it may take a considerable period of time. The functioning of rental housing markets with leases for tenants may introduce substantial time lags into the process of tax shifting. In some ongoing research, Ellen Roche (1985) contends that these lags are, indeed, significant, and that their effect is - - - ------- On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 73 to reduce the present discounted value of any increase in tax liability to tenants. The extreme case, of course, is that of rent control where, depending on the specific ordinances, owners may be limited in the extent to which they can pass along increases in property taxes into higher rents. What all this suggests is that renter support for expanded budgets may not be based on fiscal illusion at all. Instead, it may well reflect quite rational behaviour: under local property taxation, renters may, in fact, have significantly lower tax-prices than do owner-occupants. If true, incidentally, this phenomenon has some troubling implications, for it suggests that renters may to some extent be getting a 'free ride' at the expense of homeowners. Perhaps voting on local budgetary measures (as suggested by Sonstelie and Pormey [1978]) ought to be limited to those who own property? Case III: Income Elasticity of the Revenue System The third instance of fiscal illusion that has been examined empirically involves the income elasticity of the revenue system. The revenue-elasticity hypothesis has been stated succinctly by Buchanan (1967), who argues that: 'In a period of rapidly increasing national product, that tax institUtion characterized by the highest [income] elasticity will tend, other things equal, to generate the largest volume of public spending' (p. 65). On first inspection, this proposition appears to imply some rather peculiar behaviour on the part of taxpayers. As I have put it earlier: We would expect that individual demands for public services would be based upon tastes, levels of income, and the cost of these services. With a given costsharing scheme (or set of tax shares), we could then determine the pattern of individualdemands at some moment in time. But why should people care about the income elasticiryof the tax struCtUre? What the proposition under study seems to imply is that people will not object to increases in public expenditure if they can be funded with no increases in tax. rates (that is, from increments to revenues resulting solely from growth in income), but they will not support an expanded public budget if it requires a rise in tax rates. This suggests what people care about is not their tax bill, but rather their tax rate. Viewedthis way,the hypothesis simply is not consistent with our conventional descriptionof rational behaviour;it implies that consumertaxpayers are subject to a kind of 'fiscalillusion' [Oates, 1975,p. 141]. However, in the context of existing fiscal institUtions, the hypothesis IS surely plausible (Goetz 1977). As Richard Wagner has argued: There also exists a large body of casual evidence supporting the existence of faulry fiscal perception. Whenever a legislative assembly considers changes in tax rates, tortuous discussion takes place and considerable publiciry is given to the deliberations. Yet no similar agonizing takes place over the continual, automatic increase in tax rates that is produced by progressiviry in the national ----- 74 Taxation and Fiscal Federalism tax structure. Everyoneis aware of a consciouslyenacted tax surcharge; a similar surcharge is enacted each year when income grows under progressive taxation, but many taxpayers remain unconsciousof this surcharge [po87]. The issue at this point becomes an empirical one: do revenue systems with a relatively high income elasticity tend, during periods of economic growth, ro be associated with more rapid budgetary expansion? The initial empirical test of this issue (Oates, 1975) examined the growth in spending, first, by state governments in the US, and, second, by a sample of US ciry governments over the decade 1960 ro 1970, a period of unusually rapid budgetary growth in the state and local sector. The srudy followed the general approach outlined earlier except that the dependent variables were changes in spending (over the decade) and the independent variables likewise rook the form of changes instead of absolute levels. The mulripleregression equations thus seek to explain the growth in spending as a function of changes in the levels of the independent variables and of a measure of the income elasticity of the revenue system. In the cross-sectional equations both for state governments and for a sample of 33 large cities, I found a positive and statistically significanr partial association of tax elasticity with expendirure growth, providing support for the revenueelasticity hypothesis. However, the magnitude of the effect, as calculated from the point estimates, was, in my judgmenr, modest. Subsequenr empirical work has produced mixed results. In a study of US state government spending, Craig and Heins (1980) found a positive and significant relationship between tax elasticity and the !eve! of expenditure. They claim, incidentally, that because of 'bounds' on spending, the appropriate dependenr variable is the level of public spending, not the growth (or change) in expendirure. This is a tricky matter. As I suggested earlier, there are indeed limits to illusion effects. Fiscal illusion is likely ro operate over certain ranges of budgetary variables, but all changes in these variables surely cannot go unnoriced. Thus, it is not entirely clear juSt how illusion relationships should be specified. My conjecture is that neither simple growth nor level measures are fully adequate; we probably need to think in terms of threshold effects, or, more generally, in terms of effects that vary in magnirude with budgetary levels. At any rate, Craig and Heins did find support for the revenue-elasticity hypothesis in terms of expendirure levels of state governments. In conrrast, Dilorenzo (1982) found a negative and significant relationship berween his measures of tax elasticiry and expendirure growth for a sample of 66 US county governments. Dilorenzo attributes this to Tiebour-like migration effects in response to fiscal differentials, which he . contends could offset any illusion effects at the local level. However, it is hard ro see how this could result in a negative effect! Other studies include Baker (1983), who finds only marginally significant effects of his tax-elasticiry variables in explaining levels of tax revenues in the state- --- -- On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 75 local sector, and Breeden and Hunter (1985), whose results on this issue I find a little hard to interpret. Once again the evidence in support of the hypothesis is somewhat mixed. But there are certainly some results suggesting that tax elasticity matters. One problem that plagues all of these studies is measuring the income elasticity of the revenue system. This is not a simple matter where the system consists of a diverse set of tax bases with varying rates. In the United States, the Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations (1968, Table 7; 1974, Table 173) has published some information on tax elasticity. But the ACIR estimates are seriously incomplete and typically apply only to a single year. Craig and Heins used the ACIR estimates, but Oates tried to develop some other proxy measures involving the extent of reliance on income taxation. There is a real need in this work for improved measures of revenue elasticity. . Ignoring these measurement problems, suppose that we accept the findings of Oates and Craig-Heins of a positive and significant association of expenditure growth (or level) with revenue elasticity. As mentioned earlier, there is still the troublesome issue of the endogeneity of the tax structure. Jurisdictions that prefer relatively high levels of spending may, for example, opt for more elastic revenue systems. The elasticity variable may itself be endogenous. There is a further matter of interpretation that I find even more troublesome. Suppose that we were to conclude that the evidence supports che revenue-elasticity hypothesis. Can we infer from this che presence of fiscal illusion? I chink noc. There is another explanation for this phenomenon chat I find ac leasc as compelling as che illusion view: che transactions cOltI inherent in modifying budgetary- parameters. Wagner (1971) argues chat: As viewed by legislators, the cost of thus changing tax structures may exceed the benefits, in which case the required change in relative tax collections will not occur. Such legislative behavior may be interpreted as a form of habitUal behavior, and may very well be rational. There is a cost incurred in failing to routinize many types of activity the value of the resources consumed in examining the consequences of the alternative choices, in this case, choices among possible tax structUres. If the costs incurred by continual reexamination exceed the benefits received from taking more timely actions, habitUal behavior is efficient it is the least inefficient of the attainable alternatives [pp. 8586]. - - Note thac the transactions-cost explanation does nOt rely on imperfect voter information or misperceptions. It simply recognises that there are costs associated with the legislative actions needed to raise tax rates. Such costs may impede desired rate increases, whereas with a more elastic revenue system the increase in 'effective' rates will be forthcoming automatically. The illusion and transaCtions-cost explanations for the revenue-elasticity ... 76 . . -- ... .. --. -.- -.. ... -.. -. .. - - .- -- - -.. .-- - ---.--- Taxation and Fiscal Federalism phenomenon are certainly not mutually exclusive. But we cannot, I think, make an unequivocal leap from the verification of the revenue-elasticity hypothesis to the conclusion that we have discovered a form of illusion in the fiscal system. Case IV: Debt Illusion A further potential kind of fiscal illusion involves the choice between debt and tax finance. The argument here is that individuals are more likely to perceive the costS of public programs if they pay for them through current taxation than if tax liabilities are deferred through public-sector borrowing. Vickrey (1961), for example, has referred to '... "a public debt illusion" under which individuals pay no attention to their share in the liability represented by the public debt..: (p. 133). Reliance on debt, rather than tax finance should, from this perspective, tend to result in a larger public budget. For rational and informed taxpayers, the choice between these tWOforms of finance (assuming a similar pattern of incidence) should make no difference. There is obviously an equivalence (Buchanan, 1964 calls it the 'Ricardian equivalence') between a current tax payment and the present discounted value of the future tax liabilities in the event of debt finance.4 There is now a large literature on the nature of public debt and its effects on decisions (e.g., see Barro, 1974), which I shall not try to summarise. But the central proposition here is a straightforward one: there is a fiscal illusion present when taxpayers tend to underestimate the present discounted value of their future tax liabilities under bond finance. And with imperfect knowledge, the failure to recognise such furore tax liabilities, at least to their full sum, seems a real possibility.~ The determination of the existence and the extent of such a debt illusion is an empirical issue. Once again, this is not an easy matter to get at empirically. There is, however, a straightforward approach in terms of local finance. As Daly (1969) and Oates (1972) have pointed out, the furore tax liabilities associated with local public debt should be capitalised into local property values. Consider two otherwise identical communities that undertake identical capital projects. One community, call it A, finances the project Out of current revenues, while community B chooses to employ bond finance so as to spread out the payments for the project over future years. At the end of the current year, the sole differences between a 'typical resident' of A and B will be that the latter will have a furore tax liability whose present discounted value equals the recent differential tax payment by the resident of A. In a world of mobile consumers, this future tax liability associated with residing in community B will become capitalised into lower property values in B.6 This suggests an empirical test of the debt-illusion hypothesis. Other things equal, we should find, if there is a debt illusion, that the furore ..- --. -.. --. --- On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 77 tax liabilities associated with the debt are not fully capitalised into local property values. There has, in fact, been such a study by Epple and Schipper (1981) in which they examined the partial association betWeen differentials in local property values across a sample of jurisdictions in the Pittsburgh metropolitan area and the extent of deferred funding for pensions for municipal-government employees. Epple and Schipper find no evidence of debt illusion. Their results suggest that unfunded pension obligations tend to be fully capitalised into local property values. We obviously cannot place great confidence in the findings from a single stUdy, but, as yet, there is not to my knowledge any solid, systematic evidence supporting the debt-illusion hypothesis. Case V: The Flypaper Effe<:t Our final example of fiscal illusion involves what is known in the public finance literature as the 'flypaper effect'. This is a phenomenon that has been regularly observed in econometric stUdies of inter-governmental grants-in-aid. More specifically, these stUdies have found that there is a significantly higher propensity for recipients to increase public expenditUre in response to lump-sum inter-governmental grants than in response to equivalent increases in private income. In principle, as Bradford and Oates (1971) have shown, there is no reason for rational and informed individuals in a particular jurisdiction to regard increases in income from grants any differently from increases in income from other sources. From this perspeaive, inter-governmental grants are simply a 'veil' (hence the 'veil hypothesis') for transfers of income directly to individuals. However, existing econometric findings do not support the veil hypothesis. Instead, they indicate that communities direct much larger fractions (40 to 50 per cent) of revenue from lump-sum inter-governmental grants into state and local outlays than from private income (roughly 10 per cent ). How can we explain the flypaper effect? Courant, Gramlich, and Rubinfeld (1979) and Oates (1979) have proposed a form of fiscal illusion that can account for this phenomenon. In their models, budget-maximising public officials effectively conceal the lump-sum character of the grant revenues. What the electorate sees is a reduction in tax rates needed to finance local spending programs, and this reduction is erroneously viewed as a reduction at the margin in the 'tax-price' of these programs. The budgetary process thus transforms what is, in truth, a lump-sum inter-governmental grant into what is perceived by individuals as a reduction in the tax-price of local public goods. The result is a willingness on the pare of the local electorate to support higher levels of spending than if they correctly perceived the relevant fiscal parameters. Such an explanation for the existence of the flypaper effect is plausible. 78 Taxation and Fiscal Federalism But once again, there are competing explanations. It is by no means necessary to posit the existence of a fiscal illusion to rationalise such behaviour. Romer and Rosenthal (1979), for example, have shown that where public officials set the budgetary agenda, excessive public spending can result. In their model, the public agency takes advantage of a relatively unattraCtive alternative, the 'reversion level' of the budget which obtains if the eleCtorate rejects the agency's proposed budget. The proposed budget is larger than that most preferred by the representative voter but still emerges viCtorious relatively because it is preferred by the electorate to the alternative unappealing reversion level of public output. Note that this explanation does not presume any lack of information or 'illusion' on the part of taxpayer voters. Moreover, as Romer and Rosenthal (1980) show, their model generates a different budgetary response to an increase in income than to an equivalent increase in lump-sum grants. The model can give rise to a flypaper effeCt (although other outcomes are also possible). The basic point is simply that it doesn't require any sort of fiscal illusion to generate a flypaper result. Plausible forms of local budgetary processes can do the trick. There is no real evidence that I know supporting the illusion explanation of the flypaper effect. It is one of the possibilities, but it needs empirical support. - Conclusion In this chapter, we have examined five distinct forms that fiscal illusion might take, each of which has been explored in the public-finance literatUre.7 Although forms of illusion are surely possible on the expenditUre side of the budget, all five cases involve instances of revenue illusion. They are thought to be cases where individual taxpayers are likely to underestimate their true tax-prices and consequently to support excessively large levels of public outlays. It is my contention that although all five cases entail plausible illusion hypotheses, none of them has very compelling empirical support. In this regard, I wish to offer tWo concluding observations. First, the general grounds on which I have expressed reservations about the existing econometric findings are two: endogeneity of the illusion variables and alternative explanations of the resultS. These are such commonplace objeCtions to econometric stUdies that one might regard them as a 'cheap shot'. It is typically not hard to find some grounds for questioning the exogenous natUre of an independent variable. Moreover, as we all know, statistical associations do not demonstrate causation there is always room for another hypothesis. While this is true enough, the issue is really one of judgment and additional evidence. How compelling is the other explanation for the observed result? How likely and how serious is the potential endogeneity of the suspect variable? It is my sense, as I have tried to indicate in the paper, that these are probably serious matters in the fiscal-illusion literarure. The likelihood of endogeneity in certain cases - -- -- - -- On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 79 like the revenue-complexity hypothesis seems to me quite high. Further, the alternative explanations of a number of the findings strike me to be at least as persuasive as the illusion rationale. In short, I think that there really are sources of serious reservation that suggest the need for further, carefully designed empirical testing both to deal with the endogeneity issue and to distinguish among the various hypotheses. My second observation concerns the theory of fiscal illusion. This survey has focused on empirical studies of illusion hypothesis for a good reason: there is very little underlying theory. The fiscal-illusion literature has identified a number of instances of potential illusion, but it has not explored with much care or rigour their conceptual underpinnings. To take a case in point, consider the revenue-complexity hypothesis. The assertion here is that as the revenue system becomes more 'complex' (meaning that it encompasses a more diverse set of revenue sources), individuals exhibit an increasing tendency to underestimate their true tax-prices. But how does this occur? One could imagine a very fragmented revenue system in which each revenue source was tied closely to a particular government activity. Such a system could provide quite accurate price signals to taxpayer voters on the costs of various public programs. There is also the important distinction between marginal tax-price and total tax liability (see Carter, 1982). What is presumably important is the individual's perception of his tax-price at the margin which may be fairly clear even though some illusion may be present as to total tax liability. Although the public sector employs numerous revenue sources, if it is clear where the marginal funds come from, tax-price may be readily evident (see Flowers, 1977). My point here is simply that the study of fiscal illusion requires a careful statement of the way in which tax-price is perceiv~d and how this perception depends on revenue structure. The existing literature is suggestive and points to some important and tantalising hypotheses, but the supporting theoretical and empirical work remains, for the most part, to be done. Nates 1. Since my concern in this paper is with fiscal illusion, I will not address a major source of potential illusion operating through the monetary sector: money creation and inflationary finance as an alternative to tax or bond finance. 2. Galbraith argued along somewhat different lines. It is his contention that extensive advertising aaivities in the private sector introduce a 'bias' in resource allocation away from publicly provided services toward private goods. On the potential for illusion on the benefit side, see also Musgrave (1981). 3. Robert Schwab has pointed out to me that there may well be a systematic relationship between the value of the Herfindahl index and the degree of revenue visibility. A high value of the index (indicating heavy reliance on a single revenue source) might well be correlated positively with the fraaion of revenues from -."" 80 4. 5. 6. 7. - Taxation and Fiscal Federalism property taxation. If the property tax is a relatively visible source of revenues, then the Herfindahl index might be serving as a proxy for visibility as well as a measure of revenue simplicity. There are, of course, circumstances that will distUrb this equivalence, as, for example, where public-sector borrowing can be undertaken at an interest rate other than that available to the individual tax-payer in the private market. But the basic point remains. For a careful examination of the Ricardian equivalence theorem, see Brennan and Buchanan (1980). According to Buchanan (1967, pp. 132-3), Puviani (1903) had a somewhat more subtle view of debt illusion. While acknowledging the Ricardian equivalence of debt and tax finance, Puviani contended that taxpayers would still have a preference for debt finance, because they would retain 'control' over a captial value (even though it would be offset by a corresponding liability). The preference for bond finance based on this control consideration is called by Buchanan an 'asset illusion'. This is a particularly straightforward case of debt finance: the issue of bonds to finance a capital project. Debt finance can, however, take other forms. One increasingly prevalent mode involves 'borrowing' from current public employees in the form of relatively low wages with compensation in the form of generous pensions to be paid upon retirement. Because of favourable tax treatment, this is an attraCtive way for local governments to compensate their employees; 'underfunding' of public pension programs may be a rational course of action for a community. On this, see Mumy (1978). There are a few other cases of fiscal illusion that have received isolated study. Dilorenzo (1982), for example, has found that where municipal utilities use their profits to subsidise local spending, budgetary levels tend to be higher than in the absence of such subsidisation. References Advisory Commission on Inter-governmental Relations, Federal-Slate-Local Finances: Significanl Features of Fiscal Federalism Washington, D.C.: ACIR., Feb., 1974. Advisory Commission on Inter-governmental Relations, Sources of Increased Slale Tax CoJJeaion: Economic Growlh vs. Polilical Choice, Report M-41 Washington, D.C.: AOR, Oct., 1968. . Baker, Samuel H., 'The Determinants of Median Voter Tax Liability: An Empirical Test of the Fiscal Illusion Hypothesis', Public Finance Quarterly 11 Jan., 1983, 95-108. Barro, Robert]., 'Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?', Journal of Polilical Economy 82 Nov.-Dec., 1974, 1095-1117. Bergstrom, Theodore c., and Goodman, Robert P., 'Private Demands for Public Goods', American Economic Review 63 June, 1973,280-96. Bradford, David, and Oates, Wallace, 'The Analysis of Revenue Sharing in a New Approach to Collective Fiscal Decisions', Quarterly Journal of Economics 85 April, 1971 416-39. On the Nature and Measurement of Fiscal Illusion 81 Breeden, Charles H., and Hunter, William J., 'Tax Revenue and Tax StruCtUre', Public Finance Quarterly 13 April, 1985,216-24. Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan,James M., 'The Logic of the Ricardian Equivalence Theorem', Finanzarchiv 38 No.1, 1980,4-16. Brennan, Geoffrey, and Buchanan, James M., The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundation! of a Fiscal Constitution Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1980. Buchanan, James M., 'Public Finance in Democratic Proceu' Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1967. Carter, Richard, 'Beliefs and Errors in Voting Choices: A Restarement of rhe Theory of Fiscal Illusion', Public Choice 39 1982,343-60, Clotfelrer, Charles T., 'Public Spending for Higher Education: An Empirical Tesr of Two Hypotheses', Public Finance 31 No.2, 1976, 177-95. Courant, Paul, Gramlich, Edward, and Rubinfeld, Daniel, 'The Stimularive Effecrs of Intergovernmental Grants: Or Why Money Sticks Where It Hits', in P. Mieszkowski and W. Oakland, eds" Fiscal Federalism and Grants-in-Aid Washingron, D.c.: The Urban Insrimre, 1979, 5-2l. Craig, Eleanor D" and Heins, A. James, 'The effect of Tax Elasticity on Government Spending', Public Choice 35 No, 3, 1980267-75. Daly, George G., 'The Burden of the Debt and Furure Generations in Local Finance', Southern Economic Journal 36 July, 1969,44-51. DiLorenzo, Thomas J., 'Tax Elasricity and the Growth of Local Public Expendirure', Public Finance Quarterly 10 July, 1982,385-92. Dilorenzo, Thomas J" 'Utility Profirs, Fiscal Illusion, and Local Public Expendimres', Public Choice 38 No, 3, 1982,243-52. Downs, Anrhony, An Economic Theory of Democracy New York: Harper and Row, 1957. Downs, Anthony, 'An Economic Theory of Polirical Acrion in a Democracy', Journal of Political Economy 65 April, 1957, 135-50. Downs, Anthony, 'Why rhe Government Budget is Too Small in a Democracy', World Politics July, 1960. Epple, Dennis, and Schipper, Katherine, 'Municipal Funding: A Theory and Some Evidence', Public Choice 37 1981, 141-78. Flowers, Marilyn R., 'Multiple Tax Sources, Voting Equilibrium, and Budgerary Size', Public Finance 32 No.2, 1977,210-24. Galbrairh, John K., The Affluent Society Boston: Houghton-Mifflin, 1958. Goetz, Charles J., 'Fiscal Illusion in Srate and Local Finance', in T, Borcherding, ed., Budgets and Bureaucrats: The Sources of Government Growth Durham, North Carolina: Duke University Press, 1977, 176-87. Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge, 'Renters' illusion or Savvy?', Public Finance Quarterly 11 April, 1983,237-47. Mumy, Gene E., 'The Economics of Local Government Pensions and Pension Funding', Journal of Political Economy 86 June, 1978, 517-28. Munley, Vincent G., and Greene, Kenneth V., 'Fiscal Illusion, the Namre of Public Goods and Equation Specification', Public Choice 33 No.1, 1978,95-100. Musgrave, Richard A., 'Leviarhan Cometh - Or Does He?', in H. Ladd and T.N, Tideman, eels., Tax and Expenditure Limitation! Washington, DC: The Urban Insrimte, 1981, 77-120. Oates, Wallace E., Fiscal Federalism New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, 1972. _--- .- ----_.....- 82 Taxation and Fiscal Federalism - Oates, Wallace E., 'Automatic Increases in Tax Revenues The Effea on the Size of the Public Budget', in W. Oates, ed., Financing the New Federalism: Revenue Sharing, Conditional Grants, and Taxation Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1975, 129-60. Oates, Wallace E., 'Lump-Sum Intergovernmental Grants Have Price Effeas', in P. Mieszkowski and W. Oakland, eds., Fiscal Federalism and Grants-in-Aid Washington DC: The Urban Institute, 1979,23-30. Peterson, George E., 'Voter Demand for Public School Expenditures', in J. Jackson, ed., Public Needs and Private Behavior in Metropolitan Areas Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger, 1975,99-120. Pommerehne, Werner W., and Schneider, Friedrich, 'Fiscal Illusion, Political InstitUtions, and Local Public Spending', Kyklos 31 No.3, 1978,381-408. Puviani, Amilcare, Teoria del/a 1//usione Finanziaria Milan: Remo Sandon, 1903. Roche, Ellen, 'The Incidence of Property Taxes on Renters', unpublished paper 1985. Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard, 'Bureaucrats vs. Voters: On the Political Economy of Resource Allocation by Direct Democracy', Quarterly journal of Economics 93 Nov., 1979,562-87. Romer, Thomas, and Rosenthal, Howard, 'An InstitUtional Theory of the Effect of Intergovernmental Grants', National Tax journal 33 December, 1980, 4518. Sonstelie, Jon C, and Portney, Paul R., 'Profit Maximizing Communities and The Theory of Local Public ExpenditUre', journal of Urban Economics 5 April, 1978, 263-77. Vickrey, William, 'The Burden of the Public Debt: Comment', American Economic Review 51 March, 1961, 132-37, Wagner, Richard E., The Fiscal Organization of American Federalism Chicago: Markham, 1971. Wagner, Richard E., 'Revenue StructUre, Fiscal Illusion, and Budgetary Choice', Public Choice 25 Spring, 1976,45-61. Wu, D.M., 'Alternative Tests of Independence berween Stochastic Regressors and Disturbances', Econometrica 41 July, 1973, 733-50.