Lecture 4 ~ Macroeconomics Basic Elements of Macroeconomics Macroeconomic Objectives • Distinction between microeconomics and macroeconomics • The major macroeconomic issues – economic growth – unemployment – inflation – balance of payments and exchange rates • balance of payments deficits and surpluses • exchange rate movements Economic growth (average % per annum), Unemployment (average %), Inflation (average % per annum) France Germany Italy Japan UK USA EU(15) OECD Brazil Malaysia Singapore Growth 1960-9 1970-9 1980-9 1990-9 7.5 3.2 2.2 1.7 4.4 2.6 1.8 2.1 5.3 3.8 2.4 1.4 10.9 4.3 4.0 1.3 2.9 2.0 2.4 2.2 4.3 2.8 2.5 3.3 3.5 3.2 2.2 1.9 4.6 3.6 2.6 2.4 5.4 8.1 3.0 3.2 6.5 7.9 5.8 7.8 8.8 8.3 6.1 8.6 Unemployment 1960-9 1970-9 1980-9 1990-9 1.5 3.7 9.0 11.2 0.9 2.3 5.9 7.5 5.1 6.4 9.5 10.6 1.3 1.7 2.5 3.0 2.2 4.5 10.0 5.8 4.1 6.1 7.2 5.8 2.5 4.0 9.3 9.9 2.5 4.3 7.3 7.2 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 6.2 3.9 n/a n/a 3.6 2.6 Inflation 1960-9 1970-9 1980-9 1990-9 4.2 9.4 7.3 1.9 3.2 5.0 2.9 2.5 4.4 13.9 11.2 3.9 4.9 9.0 2.5 1.1 4.1 13.0 7.4 3.5 2.8 6.8 5.5 2.8 3.7 10.3 7.4 3.2 3.1 9.2 8.9 4.9 46.1 38.6 227.8 300.9 -0.3 7.3 2.2 3.8 1.1 5.9 2.5 2.0 Macroeconomics • MACRO is concerned with economic aggregates and averages. • Aggregates: Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is a standard measure of aggregate economic activity The rate of unemployment • Averages: The Average level of prices & the rate of inflation Gross Domestic Product: GDP • Gross Domestic Product (GDP) is a standard measure of aggregate economic activity GDP measures the total value of the economy’s output of final goods & services. GDP also measures the income earned by the economy’s factors of production – labour, land & capital. GDP • GDP can be measured in NOMINAL or in REAL terms Nominal: the € value of the economy’s output Real: Nominal GDP divided by the average price of all goods & services. The economy’s rate of growth is measured by the annual percentage change in real GDP. Average Growth Rates (%): 1960-2002 IRL EU USA JPN 1961-70 4.2 4.9 4.2 10.1 1971-80 4.7 3.0 3.2 4.4 1981-90 3.6 2.4 3.2 4.2 1991-00 7.0 2.1 3.4 1.3 1998-02 8.7 2.9 3.7 0.7 Source: European Commission Growth Rates (%): 1960 – 2002. 12 10 Ireland 8 6 EU 4 2 0 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Source: European Commission Measuring GDP • GDP can be defined as: • The market value of all final goods & services produced in a given time period (one year) • Market value simply means the money value of the economy’s output If we produce 1m computers at a price of €1,000 each the market value is €1,000m • To aggregate over different goods we must measure in money terms – market value Measuring GDP • Final Goods: Goods & services which are purchased & consumed by the final user • Other goods & services which are used in the production of final goods are not counted in GDP – intermediate goods • Including intermediate goods would imply double counting & overstate GDP Measuring GDP • Consider the following example • Three stages in producing a litre of milk Farmer produces raw milk & sells it to a dairy for processing Dairy sells it to a retailer who then sells it to the consumer In € terms what contribution does the litre of milk make to GDP? Measuring GDP • Suppose the farmer has zero costs and: Processor pays farmer €0.70 Retailer pays the processor €1.20 Consumer pays the retailer €1.50 • Total value of all transactions is €3.40 • The contribution to GDP is the value of the final purchase (€1.50) not the total value of all transactions (€3.40) WHY? Measuring GDP • The processor pays the farmer €0.70 per litre As the farmer has zero costs his income = €0.70 • The processor sells to the retailer at €1.20 per litre Hence the processor’s net income = €0.50 • The retailer sells to the consumer at €1.50 Hence the retailer’s net income = €0.30 Measuring GDP • Hence the net income or VALUE ADDED at each stage is: Farmer: €0.70 Processor: €0.50 Retailer: €0.30 • Total: €1.50 • Which equals final expenditure by the consumer Measuring GDP • The purchase of raw milk by the processor from the farmer is an intermediate purchase • It is part of the farmer’s income but not the processor’s income • To include it in both would lead to double counting & overstate GDP • The same holds for the purchase of processed milk by the the retailer Measuring GDP • GDP is the sum of the net income or value added at each stage of production • This sum equals the market value of the final purchase • The economy's GDP is measured in two ways The Expenditure Method The Income Method Calculating GDP: Expenditure Method • GDP = total amount spent on all final goods in a given year • Final goods & services are bought by 4 sectors: Individual Consumers or Households Firms Government The Foreign Sector or Rest of the World (ROW) Calculating GDP: Expenditure Method Expenditure by: Households: Consumption (C) Firms: Gross Investment (I) Government: Purchases of goods & services (G) ROW: Expenditure on exports (EX) less domestic expenditure on imports (IM): net exports NX = (EX – IM) • Total expenditure on GDP = C + I + G + NX Calculating GDP: Expenditure Method • Consumption (C): Household or personal expenditure on goods & services • Investment (I): Expenditure by firms on fixed capital formation plus changes in inventories • Government Expenditure (G) includes: Wages & salaries paid to all government employees Expenditures on office supplies, military equipment, roads etc. • It does not include transfer payments Calculating GDP: Expenditure Method • Net Exports (NX) = Exports - Imports • Exports : sales of domestically produced goods & services to foreigners • Imports: domestic purchases of foreign produced goods & services • Denote GDP as Y: Hence Y is the sum of four different types of expenditure. That is: • Y = C + I + G + NX Origins of GDP, 2001 Ireland UK US Sector of the Economy % of GDP % of GDP % of GDP Agriculture 3.7 1.1 1.4 Mining 0.4 3.3 1.4 Manufacturing 40.8 18.4 15.8 Utilities 0.9 1.6 2.3 Construction 4.3 5.2 4.7 Wholesale & retail trade, Restaurants & Hotels 7.7 15.9 15.9 Transport, Storage & Communications 3.8 8.0 6.0 Finance, Insurance, Real Estate & Business Services 13.0 24.1 19.6 Community, personal & social services 9.5 11.3 22.1 Other 55.5 11.1 10.8 Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 Nominal & Real GDP • GDP is measured in money terms (€’s) • Suppose the economy produces n different final goods & services (computers, potatoes, phones etc.) • Let Qi = the output of any good i (number of computers etc) • Let Pi = the price of good i in €’s • PiQi = nominal or money value Qi Nominal & Real GDP • As there are n goods & services, nominal GDP is: Y = P1Q1 + P2Q2 + … + PnQn • Suppose we want to compare GDP in two years 1 & 2 • Suppose there are two goods A & B • QAi & QBi = production in each year, i = 1,2 • PAi & PBi = prices in each year, i = 1,2 Nominal & Real GDP • • • • Nominal GDP in each year is: Y1 = PA1QA1 + PB1QB1 Y2 = PA2QA2 + PB2QB2 Y1 & Y2 measure nominal GDP at current year prices • Y can change for two reasons • Production changes and/or prices change • If we want to compare economic activity in the two years we need to exclude the effects of price changes. Nominal & Real GDP • • • • • QA1 = 10, QB1 = 15, PA1 = €10, PB1 = €5 Y1 = €175 QA2 = 20, QB2 = 30, PA2 = €12, PB2 = €6 Y2 = €420 Production of each good has doubled (100% increase) but Y has increased by 140% • The rise in nominal GDP overstates the increase in economic activity Nominal & Real GDP • Real GDP corrects for this by measuring the value of each year’s production at constant prices • Suppose we use Year 1 prices: the base year • Year 1 GDP at year 1 prices is €175 • Year 2 GDP at year 1 prices is: • PA1QA2 + PB1QB2 = €350 Nominal & Real GDP • Hence: evaluating each year’s production at constant (year 1) prices gives: Real GDP in year 1 = €175 Real GDP in year 2 = €350 • Increase = 100% which reflects the increase in production only • Nominal GDP evaluates production at current prices • Real GDP evaluates production at constant prices Nominal & Real GDP • • • • • Note: we can also use year 2 as the base year: Y1 at year 2 prices = €210 Y2 at year 2 prices = €420 Increase = 100% The following graph shows Irish nominal & real GDP over 1995-2000: Real GDP is measured at 1995 prices Irish Nominal & Real (1995 prices) GDP £billion Nominal Real 100 80 60 40 20 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Source: National Income & Expenditure GDP & Economic Welfare • Real GDP is a measure of economic activity • It is not necessarily a good measure of economic welfare or economic well-being • Increases in real GDP imply that the economy is producing more goods & services & that we can increase consumption • However GDP excludes activities which may affect overall economic welfare GDP & Economic Welfare • Pollution: Increases in real GDP may result in increased pollution which reduces economic welfare. The cost of pollution is not included in GDP • GDP does not reflect the distribution of income and economic inequalities. • Non-Market Activities such as home-making & volunteer services may increase welfare but are not included in GDP GDP & GNP • GNP is Gross National Product: • GNP = GDP + Net Factor Income from the Rest of the World (NFI) • In any given year Irish residents & firms make and receive payments to & from the ROW (other than those for exports & imports) – interest, dividends, profits etc. GDP & GNP • Irish households may own foreign assets: Shares in UK or US firms & receive annual dividends Deposits in foreign banks & receive annual interest payments • Irish firms may receive profits from investment in other countries • These payments are an income flow from the ROW to Ireland GDP & GNP • Foreign households may own Irish assets: Shares in Irish firms & receive annual dividends Deposits in Irish banks & receive annual interest payments • US firms operating in Ireland may send the profits back to their parent firm in America • These payments are an income flow from Ireland to the ROW GDP & GNP • Net Factor Income (NFI) is: • NFI = interest, dividends profits etc. received from the ROW minus similar payments to the ROW • GNP = GDP + NFI • In large countries the difference tends to be small. • For Ireland it is large: Typically NFI < 0 & GDP > GNP • In 2000 NFI was approximately -£12.8b or 16% of GDP Irish Real GDP & GNP (1995 prices) £billion GDP GNP 100 80 60 40 20 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Source: National Income & Expenditure Real GDP and GNP growth rates compared, 1991 – 2002 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% 1991 1996 GDP 2001 GNP Real GDP and GNP compared (1995 prices) 105 GDP 95 billion € 85 75 GNP 65 55 45 35 25 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 10 Growth rates in selected industrial countries UK France Annual growth rate (%) 9 8 Germany USA 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 -1 -2 -3 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Irish and US growth rates compared, 1991 – 2002 12% IRL 10% 8% 6% USA 4% 2% 0% -2% 1991 1996 2001 Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Growth in actual and potential output • Economic growth and the business cycle – fluctuations in actual growth The business cycle National output Potential output Actual output O Time Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Growth in actual and potential output • Economic growth and the business cycle – fluctuations in actual growth – the phases of the business cycle The business cycle National output Potential output 3 2 3 4 2 1 1 O Time 4 Actual output Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Growth in actual and potential output • Economic growth and the business cycle – fluctuations in actual growth – the phases of the business cycle – trend growth The business cycle Potential output National output Trend output Actual output O Time Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Economic growth and the business cycle – fluctuations in actual growth – the phases of the business cycle – trend growth – the business cycle in practice • the irregularity of the cycle • the length of the phases • the magnitude of the phases Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Causes of actual growth – aggregate demand – aggregate demand relative to potential output • Actual growth in practice – experience since 1970 Real GDP Ireland 1960-99 (£ Billion, 1998 Prices) £100 Celtic Tiger 50 61 Recession Mid 80’s 1973-75 Recession Recession Early 90’s 11 £10 1960 1963 1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996 1999 Fig. 24.1 Fluctuations in U.S. Real GDP, 1920-1999 Economic Growth and the Business Cycle • Causes of potential growth – increases in the quantity of factors • • • • capital labour land and raw materials the problem of diminishing returns – increases in factor productivity • Policies to achieve growth – demand-side and supply-side policies – market-orientated & interventionist policies Macroeconomic Policies • Crucial to distinguish between: • Growth policies (long-run) and Stabilisation policies (short-run) Growth policies attempt to increase the longrun or average growth rate Stabilisation policies attempt to dampen the business cycle – keep actual GDP close to the trend Macroeconomic Policies • Growth Policies – support for education, training, R&D etc. • Stabilisation Policies: Two types Fiscal or Budgetary Policy – changes in rates of taxation, government expenditure plans etc. Monetary Policy – changes in interest rates & exchange rates. Macroeconomic Policies • We will see that Irish participation in the euro means: • A complete sacrifice of monetary independence Irish interest rates etc. now determined in Frankfurt • Strict limitations on fiscal policy The Stability Pact Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve Price level Aggregate demand and aggregate supply AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect Price level Aggregate demand and aggregate supply AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect Price level Aggregate demand and aggregate supply AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect • savings effect Price level Aggregate demand and aggregate supply AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect • savings effect • The aggregate supply curve Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Price level AS AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect • savings effect • The aggregate supply curve – Why aggregate supply curves generally slope upwards Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Price level AS AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect • savings effect • The aggregate supply curve – Why aggregate supply curves generally slope upwards • Equilibrium Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Price level AS Pe AD O National output Aggregate demand and aggregate supply Price level AS Pe P2 b a AD O National output Aggregate Demand and Supply • The aggregate demand curve – Why aggregate demand curves slope downwards • import effect • interest-rate effect • savings effect • The aggregate supply curve – Why AS curves generally slope upwards • Equilibrium – Effect of a shift in the AD curve Unemployment • Unemployment is the total number of people not working but seeking employment in the economy • The rate of unemployment is the percentage of the labour force who are unemployed Labour force: Number employed plus the number unemployed Unemployment Rates (%): 1960 – 2002. 18 16 Ireland 14 12 10 8 EU 6 4 2 0 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Source: European Commission Unemployment rates in selected industrial countries UK France Unemployment (% of workforce) 14 Germany USA 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Unemployment • Unemployment and the labour market – the aggregate demand and supply of labour – equilibrium in the model Aggregate demand and supply of labour Average (real) wage rate ASL We ADL O Qe No. of workers Unemployment • Unemployment and the labour market – the aggregate demand and supply of labour – equilibrium in the model – disequilibrium unemployment Disequilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL B A W2 We ADL O Q 2 Q 1 No. of workers Unemployment • Unemployment and the labour market – the aggregate demand and supply of labour – equilibrium in the model – disequilibrium unemployment – equilibrium unemployment Equilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL e We ADL O Qe No. of workers Equilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL N e We d ADL O Qe Q2 No. of workers Equilibrium and disequilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL e We ADL O Qe No. of workers Equilibrium and disequilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL Disequilibrium unemployment b a W2 e We ADL O No. of workers Equilibrium and disequilibrium unemployment Average (real) wage rate ASL Disequilibrium unemployment b a W2 N c e We Equilibrium unemployment ADL O No. of workers Unemployment • Disequilibrium unemployment – real-wage (classical) unemployment – demand-deficient (cyclical) unemployment – unemployment arising from a growth in the labour supply Unemployment • Equilibrium unemployment – frictional (search) unemployment – structural unemployment • changing pattern of demand • technological unemployment • regional unemployment – seasonal unemployment The CPI & Inflation • Inflation is normally measured by the annual percentage change in the Consumer Price Index (CPI) • The CPI is an average price of a standard basket of goods & services • It is measured by comparing the cost of a fixed basket at each year’s prices The CPI & Inflation • Example; Consider three goods: A, B & C • Suppose that in a given year (year 1) the typical household purchases: • 1 unit of A at €100 per unit: €100 • 10 units of B at €8 per unit: €80 • 20 units of C at €6 per unit: €120 • Total cost at Year 1 prices = €300 The CPI & Inflation • Suppose in a subsequent year (year 2) the prices are: • €105 for A, €10 for B & €6.25 for C • The same quantities will cost: • A: 1 at €105 €105 • B: 10 at €10 €100 • C: 20 at €6.25 €125 • Total cost at Year 1 prices = €330 The CPI & Inflation • Cost of the fixed basket (same quantities of each good) • At year 1 prices: €300 • At year 2 prices: €330 • Hence relative to year 1, the average price of the same basket in year 2 is 330/300 = 1.1 • Hence the CPI compares the cost of a fixed basket of goods & services at the prices in each year The CPI & Inflation • Note that the CPI is a price index • A price index measures the average price of a fixed basket of goods & services relative to the prices in the base year. • In Ireland the CPI is computed in two stages A price index is computed for each commodity group – housing, fuel, clothing, food etc. The CPI is the weighed average of these indices using base year expenditure weights. The CPI & Inflation • Price index for each commodity group is: • Current year price divided by • Base year price • Year 1 (base year) prices: A €100: B €8: C €6 • Year 2 prices: A €105: B €10: C €6.25 The CPI & Inflation • Year 1 Indices (base year) A 100/100 = 1 B 8/8 = 1 C 6/8 = 1 • Year 2 Indices: A 105/100 = 1.05 B 10/8 = 1.25 C 6.25/6 = 1.04 The CPI & Inflation • Base year expenditure weights: • Base year expenditure on each good Divided by • Total base year expenditure (€300) A: 100/300 = 0.33 B: 80/300 = 0.27 C: 125/300 = 0.4 Price Indices Year 2 A Base Year 1 1.05 B 1 C 1 Weights Price Indices times Weight Year 2 0.33 Base Year 0.33 1.25 0.27 0.27 0.33 1.04 0.40 0.40 0.42 1.00 1.1 CPI = Sum of Indices times the Weights 0.35 Irish CPI Weights: % (Base Dec. 2001) • • • • • • Food Alcohol Tobacco Clothing Fuel & Light Housing 20.8 11.9 4.4 4.9 3.3 9.7 • Durable Household Goods 3.6 • Other Goods 5.8 • Transport 15.4 • Services 20.2 • TOTAL: 100% Inflation Rates (%): 1960 – 2002. 25 Ireland 20 15 10 EU 5 0 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 Source: European Commission Inflation rates in selected industrial countries Inflation (% increase in retail prices) 26 USA UK EU 15 24 22 Japan 20 18 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 -2 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Inflation • Types of inflation – demand pull Demand-pull inflation Price level AS P1 AD1 O Q1 National output Demand-pull inflation Price level AS P1 AD2 AD1 O Q1 National output Demand-pull inflation Price level AS P2 P1 AD2 AD1 O Q1 Q2 National output Inflation • Types of inflation – demand pull – cost push • wage push • profit push • import-price push Cost-push inflation Price level AS1 P1 AD O Q1 National output Cost-push inflation AS1 Price level AS2 P1 AD O Q1 National output Cost-push inflation Price level AS2 AS1 P2 P1 AD O Q2 Q1 National output Inflation • Types of inflation – demand pull – cost push • wage push • profit push • import-price push – the interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation The interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation Price level AS1 P1 AD1 O National output The interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation Price level AS2 AS1 P2 P1 AD2 AD1 O National output The interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation AS3AS Price level 2 AS1 P3 P2 AD3 P1 AD2 AD1 O National output Inflation • Types of inflation – demand pull – cost push • wage push • profit push • import-price push – the interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation – structural (demand shift) Inflation • Types of inflation – demand pull – cost push • wage push • profit push • import-price push – the interaction of demand-pull and cost-push inflation – structural (demand shift) – expectations and inflation Inflation • Policies to tackle inflation – demand-side policies – supply-side policies Nominal & Real Quantities • A nominal quantity is measured in current euro terms • A real quantity is measured in physical terms – quantities of goods & services • Two examples: Real wages & incomes Real interest rates Nominal & Real Quantities • Suppose a household earns €30,000 in 2001 and €31,500 in 2002 (a 5% increase) • Is the household better-off? Does the 5% increase in nominal income permit it to buy more goods & services? • The answer depends on the CPI • In any year the household’s real income is: Its nominal income/CPI Real & Nominal Interest Rates • Suppose you save €100 at a bank with an annual deposit interest rate of 5%. • After 1 year you will have €105: €100 capital plus €5 interest. • The €5 the nominal interest on your savings • Question: are you better or worse off by saving €100 for 1 year? • OR: Does €105 buy more or less than €100 would one year ago? Real & Nominal Interest Rates • Suppose that over the year the CPI increases by 5% • This means that the real purchasing power of €105 at the end of the year is the same as the real purchasing power of €100 at the start of the year • OR: the real return on your saving is zero. Real & Nominal Interest Rates • To be more formal let: • i = the nominal interest rate (5% in the previous example) • π = rate of inflation (% change in CPI) • The the real rate of interest (r) is: r=i–π Real & Nominal Interest Rates • • • • Let i = 5% & π = 4% The the real rate of interest (r) is: r = i – π = 5 – 4 = 1% Hence if you save €100 at 5% your real return is 1% • That is: €105 buys 1% more than €100 did a year ago. Real & Nominal Interest Rates • • • • Let i = 5% & π = 6% The the real rate of interest (r) is: r = i – π = 5 – 6 = -1% Hence if you save €100 at 5% your real return is 1% • That is: €105 buys 1% less than €100 did a year ago. Actual & Expected Inflation • Many contracts are agreed in nominal terms You deposit €100 in a bank at a nominal fixed interest of 5% Unions agree to a nominal wage increase of 5% etc. • When the contract is agreed the expected real return is: The nominal or money increase minus the expected inflation rate over the contract period Actual & Expected Inflation • For example: If you expect inflation to be 3% then saving at 5% nominal interest means that you expect a real return of 2%. • However the expected real outcome will only be realised if the actual inflation rate equals the expected inflation rate • Two examples: Savers & Borrowers Workers & Employers Savers & Borrowers • Normally the nominal interest rate for borrowing is greater than the nominal rate for saving • Let saving rate = 5% • And borrowing rate = 7% • Suppose both savers & borrowers expect inflation to be 4% over the coming year. • Expected real return to saving = 1% per year • Expected real cost of borrowing = 3% per year Real & Nominal Interest Rates • Suppose the expected or forecasted inflation rate turns out to be incorrect & actual inflation is 6% rather than 4% • That is: inflation is 2% higher than expected • Actual real return to saving = 5 – 6 = -1% • Actual real cost of borrowing = 7 – 6 = +1% • Hence, an unanticipated rise in inflation makes savers (lenders) worse-off and borrowers betteroff. Real & Nominal Interest Rates • Conversely actual inflation is 3% rather than 4% • That is: inflation is 1% lower than expected • Actual real return to saving = 5 – 3 = 2% • Actual real cost of borrowing = 7 – 3 = 4% • Hence, an unanticipated fall in inflation makes savers (lenders) better-off and borrowers worse-off. Real & Nominal Interest Rates • • • • The the real rate of interest (r) is: r = i – π OR the nominal rate is: i=r+π Hence, given r, nominal interest rates (i) will be positively correlated with inflation • The Fisher Effect: Nominal interest rates tend to be high (low) when inflation is high (low) Workers & Employers • Suppose workers (unions) & employers expect inflation to be 5% and agree a nominal wage increase of 5%. Hence: • Workers expect their real standard of living to be maintained • Employers expect the real cost of hiring labour to be constant Workers & Employers • Suppose actual inflation turns out to be 6% over the contract period. • That is: unanticipated inflation = +1% • Result: real wages fall by 1% • Workers are worse-off because real living standards have declined • Employers are better-off because the real cost of hiring labour has fallen Workers & Employers • Suppose actual inflation turns out to be 4% over the contract period. • That is: unanticipated inflation = -1% • Result: real wages increase by 1% • Workers are better-off because real living standards have increased • Employers are worse-off because the real cost of hiring labour has increased The Costs of Inflation • These examples suggest that so long as inflation is correctly forecast it is not a problem. • Let π = actual inflation, πe = expected inflation • Suppose: π = πe: Inflationary expectations are always correct • So long as nominal interest rates, wages etc. change with expected inflation • Real interest rates & real wages will be constant The Costs of Inflation • • • • • • • Suppose savers will accept a real return of 3% If π = πe = 2% A nominal interest rate i = 5% Gives a real rate: r = i – π = 3% If π = πe = 10% A nominal interest rate i = 13% Gives a real rate: r = i – π = 3% The Costs of Inflation • Likewise, if money wages always rise in line with inflation then real wages will be constant at all inflation rates • If the % change in money wages = πe and π = πe • Then the real wage will be the same irrespective of the rate of inflation • Why then is high inflation considered a problem? The Costs of Inflation • High inflation can impose costs especially if it is unexpected. • We have seen that when contracts are fixed in money terms an unanticipated rise in inflation leads to a redistribution of income: From savers to borrowers From workers to employers The Costs of Inflation • Irish wage bargaining process – Social Partnership • Fixes nominal wage increases for a 2/3 year period • If inflation is higher than expected real wages & incomes will be lower than expected • This happened in 2000-01 & the current agreement (PPF) had to be renegotiated. The Costs of Inflation • Inflation can also distort the tax system. • Suppose: First €10,000 of income is tax exempt & all additional income is taxed at 20% • A household earning €20,000 would pay Zero on the first €10,000 20% or €2,000 on the next €10,000 Total tax = €2,000 or 10% of total income The Costs of Inflation • Suppose: Over time income doubles to €40,000 but real incomes remain the same (money income rises with inflation) • A household earning €40,000 would pay Zero on the first €10,000 20% or €6,000 on the next €30,000 Total tax = €6,000 or 15% of total income The Costs of Inflation • Hence unexpected increases in inflation can lead to a redistribution of income & wealth: Between savers & borrowers Between workers & employers Between taxpayers & government The Costs of Inflation • To avoid these problems interest rates, wages, pensions and tax bands are sometimes indexed to the rate of inflation • In the previous example the tax exempt band would be raised to €20,000: • A household earning €40,000 would pay Zero on the first €20,000 20% or €4,000 on the next €30,000 Total tax = €4,000 or 10% of total income The Costs of Inflation • Inflation has other costs: • “Shoe-Leather” Costs: • Inflation erodes the real value or purchasing power of cash holdings • The higher the inflation rate, the greater the amount of cash required to finance a given volume of transactions – see example 19.8 The Costs of Inflation • • • • • Distorting the Price System: Let P = CPI, Px = price of good X Px/P = the relative price of X Suppose P rises in line with wages, costs etc. An increase in Px/P is a signal that it is profitable to increase the production of X • In an efficient economy resources will be allocated towards goods whose relative prices are rising & away from those whose relative prices are falling The Costs of Inflation • When inflation is high & variable there is “noise” in the price system • More difficult to interpret relative price changes • Leading to distortions in resource allocation Is The CPI a Good Measure of Inflation? • Inflation is normally measured by the % change in the CPI. • The CPI suffers from the problems of Substitution Bias and Quality Adjustment Bias • Boskin Commission (US, 1996) estimates that these effects can overstate inflation by 1-2% per year. Is The CPI a Good Measure of Inflation? • Substitution Bias • The CPI is a weighted average of the prices of goods & services in the “typical” consumption basket • This basket may change over time because: • Relative prices change – less expensive goods are substituted for more expensive goods • Tastes change or new goods become available – how much olive oil was bought in Ireland 30 years ago? Is The CPI a Good Measure of Inflation? • Quality Adjustment Bias: • The CPI does not adjust for changes in quality • Suppose that the price of this year’s computer is 10% higher than last year’s. • This years’s model may have more memory, faster processing speed etc. • The price per unit of computing power may have increased by less than 10% over may have fallen