The Role of Preference and Emotion in Environmental Risk Perception Charlene Xie1, Yang Liu1, Shengxiang She2, Dixi Song1 1 Shenzhen Graduate School, Harbin Institute of Technology, Shenzhen, China 2 School of Management, Guilin University of Technology, Guilin, China (shengxiangs@glite.edu.cn) Abstract - Environmental risks are becoming increasingly frequent and severe across the world, especially in China. An in-depth understanding of how public perceives risk is of crucial importance to effective environmental risk communication and management. Risk preference and emotion are two critical factors in environmental risk perception. This paper summarizes existing researches in risk preference and emotion, and reflects upon their roles in environmental risk perception. Based upon existing literatures, it argues that delay affects environmental risk perception more than time preference and proposes a research on disentangling time preference and risk preference, i.e. risk preference at different time periods. Under the guidance of Appraisal Theory, this paper explores the roles of emotion in environmental risk perception and attempts to combine it into the future examining of delay effect on risk preference. Keywords - Environmental risk perception, preference, time dealy effect, emotion, Apprial Theory I. risk INTRODUCTION The recent years has seen the sharp increase in environmental risk frequency and severity, causing casualty and financial loss. The petroleum leakage accident in the Bohai Sea and the cadmium pollution in Guangxi are typical examples of recent environmental risk events in China. Environmental risk management has become an important task for central and local governments in China. When reviewing upon public reactions in these environmental risk events, we find that common people typically lack objective judgment and usually overreact in panic. However, people are apparently ignoring environmental risks like air pollution, climate change, and soil contamination in daily life. Such an obvious contrast cannot be fully explained by existent theories in decision research, psychology and risk management. According to the results of latest researches in this field, risk preference and emotion are two important underlying factors in such an obvious contrast [1][2]. Traditional rationality paradigm in decision theory attributes people’s responses to risks to the probability and severity. For long-term risks like environmental risks which have noticeable time delays, scholars combine time preference into the decision process. As for the relationship between time preference and risk preference (manifested by subjective probability), most researches have treated them as independent from each other. Some scholars even simply equal subjective probability to statistical probability, absolutely ignoring the nonlinearity of people’s real risk preference. People have long felt that their instant emotion holds a great power on their perception of uncertainty, environmental risks included. Researches into emotion and risk perception in the past few decades have shown that the role of emotion in risk perception is more important than previously thought. Advancement in appraisal theory has brought many new and more convincing insights into how emotion is elicited, combined with appraisal, and why people’s emotional responses vary so much for the same environmental risk. To research further into the relationship between time and risk preference and combine emotion into it is of great importance to better understanding of environmental risks. This paper will review researches in risk preference and emotion in environmental risk perception. It will proceed as follows. Section Ⅱ will reflect on research development in the entangling relationship between risk preference and time preference, emphasizing its influence on environmental risk perception. Section Ⅲ will summarize theories and findings concerning emotion, its effect upon environmental risk perception in particular. Section Ⅳ will discuss our research plan to explore the time delay effect on risk preference, especially its influence on environmental risk perception, and its combination with emotion in specific environmental risks like nuclear leakage, and air pollution. Section Ⅴ will discuss our expected results, and the problems we meet in design our research plan. Also directions for future researches are shown in this section. II. RISK PREFERENCE IN ENVIRONMENTAL RISK PERCEPTION Environmental risks are typically intertemporal risks, with delayed consequences and high uncertainty [3]. Perception of environmental risks involves both objective factors and subjective factors. Risk preference is one of the two main subjective factors in environmental risk perception, together with time preference. Although it is generally accepted that people can be risk-averse, riskneutral, or risk-seeking, it is more practical to assume all human beings are averse towards environmental risks, since they cannot get any benefit from environmental risks. Also, it is reasonable to assume that all people require compensation for delayed benefit, i.e. people are averse to time delay. Risk preference manifests people’s attitudes towards risks. It is usually measured via the comparison between expected value and subjective certainty equivalent. When the subjective certainty equivalent of a risky option is equal to its expected value, the decision maker is riskneural; when lower than expected value, he is risk-averse; and when greater than expected value, he is risk-seeking. Extensive explorations have been conducted in this field. The first and perhaps most influential result is the expected utility theory. This model received widespread support and became the basis for decision under uncertainty in several decades, due to clarity and simplicity in both logic and form. While in financial field Markowitz proposed his risk–return model to explain the St. Petersburg Paradox. However, the findings of more and more anomalies, like framing effect, challenged the two theories. It was under this situation that prospect theory was proposed. Time preference shows people’s discounting of future gain or loss. Extensive researches have been conducted in time preference, bringing forth multiple theories and findings. The Discounted Utility (DU) model is the first widely accepted model, in which future utility is manifested by utility discounting factor. Later researches found many anomalies, greatly undermining the validity of the DU model. To better explain people’s real activities under time delay researchers proposed models like hyperbolic discounting [4], and hyperboloid discounting [5]. For intertemporal risks, discounted expected utility has long been the dominant model to explain people’s attitudes towards both time delay and uncertainty at the same time. However, its underlying assumption that people are risk neutral towards gains and losses is under criticize. Although both risk preference and time preference in intertemporal risks have been researched in detail, few have focused on the relationship between them, simply treating them as orthogonal dimensions. Recently, some studies have noticed that time delay can affect subjective probability judgment [6]. Some researchers treat time delay as an implicit risk, arguing that time delay increases aversion towards risk [7]. Some other researchers use impatience to argue that time delay makes people more risk-averse. While Construal Level theory [8] suggests that time delay reduces risk aversion. Latest behavioral experiments show that time delay makes people more risk tolerant. Anyhow, researches in neuroscience [9] and biology [10] strongly support that time has an impact on risk preference. Risk preference greatly affects people’s perception of environmental risks. Risk preference changes people’s subjective probability of a risk event. For example, higher risk aversion increases people’s subjective probability of environmental risk. Studies have found that people with different risk preference levels exhibit greatly different attitudes towards environmental risks and relevant policies and measures [11]. In a cross-cultural research as for environmental risk perception, Duan and Fortner found that Chinese people are more risk averse than Americans, and consequently more concerned with environmental risks [12]. Combing the fact that time delay affects both time preference and risk preference, we can logically deduce that time delay affects people’s perception of long-term risks like environmental ones more than time preference does. Our finding can improve our understanding of environmental risk perception in a more precise way. This new finding can better explain and predict people’s environmental risk related behavior. III. EMTION IN ENVIRONMENTAL RISK PERCEPTION In the traditional rationality paradigm, emotion was treated as an external interference in risk perception, like many other subjective factors. With the psychological researches in environmental risk field, it has been found and widely accepted that environmental risk perception is closely related to individual traits, besides that objective condition of environmental risks [13]. In fact, many studies have shown that emotion is very important in environmental risk perception, more than only being external interference. The newly proposed Appraisal Theory has attempted to combine both cognition and affection into environmental risk perception, in favor of a dual-process model. Appraisal theory has found that feelings involved in environmental risks are more than simply bad or good affect [14]. Anger, fear and other specific emotions have been found very important in perception of environmental risks. The role of emotion in environmental risk perception can be analyzed from three kinds of different models — relational, process, and structural models. Relational models attempt to explain why individual’s emotional responses to the same environmental risk are so different [1]. It has been found that values, abilities, goals and needs are valid reasons for the difference in environmental risk related emotions [15]. Process models aim at finding how people’s emotion is elicited when faced with risks. However, no specific research in environmental risk perception has been conducted under this type of model. Structural models explore the implicit relationship between emotion and environmental risk appraisal. These three kinds of models have the potential to be integrated as tried by Peters and his colleagues [16]. Studies have confirmed that emotion is closely related to environmental risk appraisals [17]. Causes of emotion in environmental risks can be classified as the agency, coping potential, fairness, certainty, and outcome desirability [17]. Emotion is one of the causes of behavioral tendency [1] . Different emotion in risk perception can cause different environmental risk actions, implying the important role of emotion in environmental risk management. However, emotion is far from being the sufficient condition of behavior [3-5]. Environmental risk types and cultural factors coordinate the relationships between emotions and behaviors. In addition, different people have different ways to express their emotions. It requires further researches to find what emotions are relevant in specific environmental risks, and what are the effects of appraisals on emotional reactions in specific environmental risks. In brief, future research can focus on the particular factors in emotion in specific environmental risks, like nuclear leakage, water pollution, and soil contamination. IV. FUTURE RESEARCH The intertwinement of time preference and risk preference in environmental risk perception requires the effort to disentangle them. The research into the effect of time delay on risk preference is the key, since it has been found that time preference is stable under different uncertainties [3]. The following simple question can show the existence of time delay effect upon risk preference. If a man treats $1,000 which is to be paid one year later as equivalent to $800 today, and treats $800 as the certainty equivalent to a $2,000 or $0 risky option with probability of 50 to 50, will he be indifferent to the same risky option to be resolved and paid one year later and a certain amount of $640 ($800/ ($1,000/$800))? Some recent studies have found people will prefer risky option to certain amount of $640 [18]. We will extend the study in this topic, and expects to get reasonable and convincing result on time delay effect upon risk preference. The further research plan would consist of two types of research, laboratory behavioral experiments and questionnaire survey. For laboratory behavioral experiments, we will design a bunch of lotteries with different probabilities and results under both gain and loss situations. A possible design for loss situation is shown in following table. TABLE I BEHAVIORAL EXPERIMENT LOTTERY DESIGN 1 2 3 4 5 X -1200 -1200 -600 -1200 -600 P 1/6 2/6 2/6 2/6 2/6 y 0 6 0 7 0 8 -600 9 -400 10 X -1000 -1200 -1200 -1200 -1200 P 2/6 2/6 3/6 4/6 5/6 y -900 0 0 0 0 As shown by the table, we will use 10 different lotteries with different combination of results and probability. Each lottery will be exercise under four different time delays, 0 day, 6 week, 12 week, and any uncertain time between 0 day and 12 weeks. Therefore, participants in the experiment will face 40 different choices. Different from Noussair and Wu [18], we will assume no specific models on expected values, especially the linear relationship between probability and probability weighting function, i.e. subjective probability. We will ask subjects to report certainty equivalent on exercise date for each lottery rather the present value. Data will be collected and analyzed, comparing the certainty equivalents for the same lottery under different time delays. By imposing specific form on probability, we will be able to analyze further into the structure of time delay effect on risk preference. Given the influence of emotion on risk perception, we will also test how different emotions affect people’s risk preference under delay. We will try to elicit different emotions among subjects with different contents and ask them to answer questions which are designed to test their emotions. By comparing the certainty equivalents of the same lottery with the same time delay under different emotions, it is able to catch insight into how specific emotions affect risk preference. The questionnaire survey will feature specific environmental risks, like nuclear leakage, water pollution, soil contamination or air pollution. With properly designed questionnaire, we will gain data reflecting both people’s risk preference in a specific environmental risk, and how their instant emotion affects time delay effect on risk preference. The subjects will include students, teachers, and white collar workers. Those who join in laboratory behavioral experiments will be well guided before the experiments to well understand the effect of their choice and get some amount of money as reward according to their performance. V. CONCLUSION The roles of risk preference and time preference in environmental risks are crucial. The finding that risk preference can be affected by time delay is of value in understanding people’s environmental risk perceptions. We expect to find that time delay makes people more risk tolerant. Based upon this, we will gain a new approach to explain people overreaction towards temporal environmental risks, and their neglect for long-term environmental risks like global warming. As for emotion, we anticipate to find that overwhelming emotions can greatly change people’ risk preference and time delay effect on risk preference. This research will be the first study to explore the effect of time delay on environmental risk perception. It is also supposed to be the first study that combines risk preference and emotion in environmental risk perception. Also, it will provide evidence for identifying the difference between people’s risk preference under gain situations and that under loss situations. We hope to catch insight into the role of risk preference and emotion in environmental risk perception, especially the effect of time delay on risk preference with application in environmental issues. Our research will provide deeper insights to people’s attitudes towards environmental risks, and thus offer better guidance for relevant environmental risk communication and management. [12] DuanHongxia and Fortner Rosanne, “A cross-cultural study [13] ACKNOWLEDGMENT This work was supported by the National Science and Technology Support Program (2009BAK53B06), the National Natural Science Foundation of China (71101035) and the Humanities and Social Sciences of Education Ministry (12YJA880130). [14] [15] REFERENCES [1] [2] [3] [4] [5] [6] [7] [8] [9] [10] [11] K.R. Scherer, “The dynamic architecture of emotion: Evidence for the component processmodel,” Cognition & Emotion Vol. 23, no. 7, pp. 1307-1351, July 2009. C. Keller, A. Bostrom, M. Kuttschreuter, L. Savadori, A. Spence and M. White, “Bringing appraisal theory to environmental risk perception: areview of conceptual approaches of the past 40 years and suggestions for future research,” Journal of Risk Research, Vol. 15, no.1, pp.237256, January 2012. A. Gattig, L. Hendrickx, “Judgmental discounting and environmental risk perception: dimensional similarities, domain differences and Implications for sustainability,” Journal of Social Issues, Vol. 63, no.1, pp. 21-39, January 2007. Pender, L. John, "Discount rates and credit markets: Theory and Evidence from Rural In-dia," J. Devel.Econ. Vol. 50, no.2, pp. 257-96, Feburary 1996. Green, Leonard, Joel Myerson and Edward McFadden, "Rate of temporal discount-ing decreases with amount of reward," Mem-ory& Cognition Vol. 25, no.5, pp. 715-723, May 1997. Epper, T., H. Fehr-Duda, A. Bruhin, “Uncertainty breedsdecreasing impatience: The role of risk preferences in time discounting.Working paper, Institute for Empirical Research in Economics, University of Zurich, Zurich, 2009. Baucells, M., F. H. Heukamp, “Common ratio using delay,” Theory Decision Vol. 68, no. 12, pp. 149–158, December 2010 N. Liberman and Y.Trope, “The psychology of transcending the here and now,” Science, Vol. 11, no.11, pp.1201-1205, November 2008. Loewenstein, G.F., E.U. Weber, C.K. Hsee, and N. Welch, “Risk as feelings,” PsychologicalBulletin Vol. 127, no.2, pp. 267–286, Feburary, 2001. P.Boyer, “Evolutionary economics of mental time travel?” Trends in Cognitive Sciences, Vol. 12, no. 6, pp. 219-224, June 2008. Rundmo, T., B.E. Moen, “Risk perception and demand for risk mitigationamong experts, politicians and lay people in Norway,” Journal of Risk Research Vol. 9, no.6, pp. 623– 640, June 2006. [16] [17] [18] on environmental risk perception and educational strategies:Implications for environmental education in China,” International Electronic Journal of Environmental Education, Vol. 1, no.1, pp. 1-19, Janury 2010. Vastfjall, D., E. Peters, and P. Slovic, “Affect, risk perception and future optimism afterthe tsunami disaster,” Judgment and Decision Making Journal, Vol. 3, no.1, pp. 64-72, Janury 2008. Peters, E.M., B. Burraston, and C.K. Mertz. An emotionbased model of risk perceptionand stigma susceptibility: Cognitive appraisals of emotion, affective reactivity, worldviews, and risk perceptions in the generation of technological stigma. Risk Analysis, Vol. 24, no. 5, pp. 1349–1367, May 2004. Lerner, J.S., and D. Keltner, “Beyond valence: Toward a model of emotion-specificinfluences on judgment and choice,” Cognition & Emotion Vol. 14, no. 4, pp. 473-493, April 2000. Smith, C.A., and L.D. Kirby, “Putting appraisal in context: Toward a relational model of appraisal and emotion,” Cognition & Emotion Vol. 23, no. 7, pp. 1352–1372, July, 2009. L. Watson and M.T. Spence, “Causes and consequences of emotions on consumer behavior – a review and integrative cognitive appraisal theory” European Journal of Marketing, Vol. 41, no. 3, pp. 487–511, May-June 2007. Noussair, C., P. Wu, “Risk tolerance in the present and the future: Anexperimental study. Managerial Decision Econom, Vol. 27, no.6, pp. 401–412, June 2006.