A research and education initiative at the MIT Sloan School of Management JACKPOT OR FOOL’S GOLD: SERVICES AS A DYNAMIC CAPABILITY IN PRODUCT INNOVATION Paper 245 October 2008 Phillip C. Anderson For more information, please visit our website at http://digital.mit.edu or contact the Center directly at digital@mit.edu or 617-253-7054 JACKPOT OR FOOL’S GOLD: SERVICES AS A DYNAMIC CAPABILITY IN PRODUCT INNOVATION Phillip C. Anderson Ph.D. Student Massachusetts Institute of Technology Sloan School of Management 50 Memorial Drive, Room E52-557 Cambridge, MA 02142 phila@mit.edu October 3, 2008 P.C. Anderson Page 1 Abstract After-sales product support is considered a complementary asset and often viewed as a second class citizen within the high-tech product firm that must continually innovate in a fast-moving industry. During the Internet age, many product-oriented firms amplified the role of services in their business strategy through disruptive (e.g., multi-billion dollar acquisitions) and organic (e.g., hiring thousands of employees) measures that resulted in a growing proportion of total revenues coming from services. While some experts saw this phenomenon as the next economic boom others saw this as a trap for the product firm. This paper explores the evolution of this services phenomenon during a period of revolutionary and incremental change to show that services are no longer peripheral “second class citizens” but are in fact a central and growing dynamic capability within product-oriented firms. Using a longitudinal study of a sample of product firms in the intensely-competitive computer industry between 1994 and 2006, this paper begins to explore how services evolved during a period of significant technological change, how services affect firm performance, and how this phenomenon differs by technological focus (hardware systems vs. software). This paper emphasizes the heterogeneity of service functions beyond basic customer service – maintenance and product support – by proposing a taxonomy of service categories and a product-service coupling continuum – tightly coupled, loosely coupled, and uncoupled. P.C. Anderson Page 2 JACKPOT OR FOOL’S GOLD: SERVICES AS A DYNAMIC CAPABILITY IN PRODUCT INNOVATION The Jackpot Scenario: Professional-services companies have always been the unglamorous part of the computer business… But suddenly, services are in vogue… All this activity is catching the eye of Wall Street, which once ignored these businesses in favor of flashier high-tech companies… Professional services are hot now because they’re a way for hardware and software companies to add value to their products. The next boom in computers: services Business Week magazine July 7, 1986 The Fool’s Gold Scenario: [Bill] Gates and I discussed the service trap. It is his proposition that if software is good enough, all those services in which people install products and hook them together are not necessary… The more screwed up the product is, the more service is required and the more money the company makes. Not good. Gates holds that service income is a death trap slyly presenting itself as a safe haven from bloodletting product wars… What’s more, as producers retreat from the front lines, exhausted from battling the latest Silicon Valley startup and its kamikaze products, shareholders will cheer. Stock prices may spike on the expectation of predictable cash flow. The road to ruin—services Forbes magazine Oct 12, 1998 I. Introduction During the Internet age, many product-oriented firms began to amplify the role of services in their business strategy. This paper explores the evolution of this services phenomenon during a period of revolutionary and incremental change to show that services are no longer peripheral but are in fact a central and growing dynamic capability within product-oriented firms. As evidenced by the opening quotes, computer industry experts have been divided over the role of services within product firms. Are services the next economic boom or a trap to be avoided? This paper begins to explore how services might also affect firm performance. P.C. Anderson Page 3 The Phenomenon In April 1993, version 1.0 of the Mosaic web browser was released and Lou Gerstner began his tenure as IBM CEO. The Mosaic web browser was the spark that ignited the Internet revolution which was marked by radical technological change, an information explosion, and a new era in commerce. Gerstner was the spark that ignited a historic turnaround of an ailing computer industry legend. The System/360 mainframe business was in decline, a lingering 13-year antitrust suit had extinguished their competitive fire, a series of miscalculations relative to the PC squandered competitive advantages away to Microsoft and Intel, and the overall industry structure was shifting away from vertically integrated firms like IBM to a disaggregated mix of specialized firms. IBM's services business was a quiet multi-billion dollar revenue source in the early 1990's. However, the services business was viewed as a complementary asset (Teece, 1986, Tripsas, 1997, Rothaermel, 2001) and “a second-class citizen next to IBM's hardware [product] business” (Gerstner, 2002). Gerstner and his team made a big gamble based on a conjecture that the industry would become less interested in processor speeds, storage capacities, and proprietary systems and more interested in solutions that combine products and services to solve specific customer problems. At the time, IBM made a conscious decision to expand their services footprint from IBM product specific services to multi-vendor service offerings that would often recommend competitor’s products. But this would require a dramatic shift in skills, organizational routines, and culture. Gerstner (2002: 133) recalls the situation: P.C. Anderson Page 4 We were expert at managing factories and developing technologies. We understood cost of goods and inventory turns and manufacturing. But a human-intensive services business is entirely different. In services you don't make a product and then sell it. You sell a capability. You sell knowledge. You create it at the same time you deliver it. The business model is different. The economics are entirely different. Between 1996 and 2001, IBM added 98,000 employees to the new IBM Global Services division. In 2002, IBM gained another 30,000 services employees as the result of their $3.5 billion acquisition of PricewaterhouseCoopers Consulting (PwCC). By 2003, service revenues were beginning to exceed product-related revenues. While IBM began to talk internally about a major shift towards multi-vendor services in 1993, DEC was already publicly articulating its strategic focus on multi-vendor service opportunities in its 1993 annual report. In fact, Dell in its 1993 annual report acknowledged DEC as a provider of next-day onsite service for Dell machines. During the Internet age, more and more product-oriented firms in the computer industry began to amplify the role of services in their business strategy. Prior to Carly Fiorina’s arrival as HP CEO in 1999, HP had fallen behind in many of its product markets and was woefully unprepared (as many other incumbents at the time) for the Internet revolution. Fiorina recalls her view of HP's competitive position as follows (Fiorina 2006: 186-188): P.C. Anderson Page 5 We had great capability and deep resources, but we were spreading them too thin. We were organized around products, and although this had worked in the past, we now competed internally, duplicated effort, and were difficult to do business with. We were viewed as a product company, while IBM was viewed as a systems company; our services business couldn't compete against IBM's. … in the Internet age the pure product era had come to an end. We were building stand-alone products, but our customers demanded systems and solutions. While Fiorina and team made internal structural changes as an attempt to leverage synergies across various product business units, the need for a stronger position in services was clearly on their radar. In 2000, HP was secretly in negotiations to acquire PwCC in a bid that dropped from $16 billion to $3 billion (Fiorina, 2006). Although interested in a stronger services position to compete against IBM, Fiorina recalls that she walked away from the deal due to concerns over integrating a vastly different culture and concerns over structural changes occurring in the technology market. HP would later make a bold and controversial acquisition of Compaq in 2002 which provided better competitive positioning in some product markets and a larger services footprint thanks in part to Compaq's 1998 acquisition of DEC. Several years later under the leadership of CEO Mark Hurd, HP would make a $13.9 billion acquisition of EDS, the largest P.C. Anderson Page 6 independent IT professional services firm with 2007 annual revenues of $22 billion and over 130,000 employees. Not only have the large established firms like IBM, DEC, and HP been amplifying services within their strategy, some of the younger and smaller product-oriented firms have been doing likewise. Red Hat, an open source software product firm, had almost 500 employees by the end of 1999. Not long after a successful IPO in August 1999, Red Hat acquired Cygnus Solutions for $674 million in January 2000 to expand the scope of their service offerings and professional services staff. The firm views services as a mechanism for increasing the diffusion rate of their product (Red Hat 1999 annual report): We believe that providing these services and establishing ourselves as our customers' technology development partner will allow us to facilitate the widespread adoption of Red Hat Linux and other open source solutions as full scale enterprise solutions. BEA, a fast-growing software firm founded in 1995, reported services as a key element of their strategy (BEA 1999 annual report): [We continue to] develop new services offerings that focus on accelerating delivery of end-to-end e-commerce solutions based on robust transaction and application platforms. BEA continues to enhance its services offerings through acquisitions and aggressive hiring. P.C. Anderson Page 7 The examples highlighted above begin to hint at four characteristics of a services phenomenon within the computer industry. First, firms often established a separate and distinct services organization which had internal links to R&D and sales divisions and external links to customers. Second, firms often pursued an aggressive incremental expansion via the addition of human capital to the dedicated services organization. Third, firms often pursued a radical approach to services through acquisitions of independent service firms and acquisitions of product firms with a strong services footprint. Acquiring firms were willing to face the daunting task of integrating large numbers of employees and vastly different cultures. Fourth, as a product firm amplified its services focus, the firm's services revenues grew as a percentage of total revenues. This paper explores the evolution of this services phenomenon during a period of revolutionary change to show that services are no longer peripheral second-class citizen but are in fact a central and growing dynamic capability within product-oriented firms. Using a longitudinal study of product firms in the intensely-competitive computer industry between 1994 and 2006, this paper begins to explore the following questions. 1) How have services evolved during a period of technological change? 2) How have services affected firm performance? 3) How has this evolution differed by technological focus (hardware systems vs. software)? Differences by firm size, firm age, and firm structure (vertically integrated vs. specialized) are potential subjects of future research. This paper emphasizes the heterogeneity of service functions beyond basic customer service (i.e., maintenance and product support) by proposing a standardized set of service P.C. Anderson Page 8 categories through which comparisons can be made across different groupings of firm types. The paper is divided into the following sections. Section II searches for an appropriate theoretical perspective to help frame the discussion about services within a product innovation setting. Section III describes the empirical setting for the paper and highlights some of the key environmental forces shaping IT product firms between 1994 and 2006. Section IV discusses the data collection methodology used to explore the evolution of services from a qualitative and quantitative perspective. A taxonomy of service capabilities is defined so that a comparison across firms can be conducted. Section V presents the empirical results. Section VI discusses the empirical results and explores why services have been on the rise among the product firms in our sample. Section VII concludes with implications for practitioners and ideas for future research. II. Theoretical Perspective on Services While the services phenomenon has involved the flow of thousands of employees and billions of dollars in acquisitions and revenues, the phenomenon has not yet found a firm theoretical home in the academic literature. The following discussion will examine services through a few theoretical lenses – product/process innovation, resource-based view, and dynamic capabilities – and determine which lens will be most productive at helping us frame the emergence of this services phenomenon during a period of technological change. P.C. Anderson Page 9 Services and Product/Process Innovation Most of the research on product-oriented firms in the computer industry has focused on product innovation and product development. On one hand, the product development literature focuses on micro level process-related issues such as development process flexibility (Eisenhardt and Tabrizi, 1995, MacCormack, Verganti and Iansiti, 2001), product design (Baldwin and Clark, 2000, Utterback, 2006), communication flows among individuals and teams (Allen, 1977, Ancona and Caldwell, 1992a), team structure (Ancona and Caldwell, 1992b), and decision-making (von Hippel, 1994). On the other hand, the product innovation literature explores macro level issues such as the patterns of technological change, lifecycles, industry dynamics, firm adaptation, and firm failure. Our discussion begins with an attempt to situate services within the product innovation literature. One of the prevailing frameworks used by innovation scholars to explain the patterns of technological change has been the Abernathy/Utterback ((Utterback and Abernathy, 1975, Abernathy and Utterback, 1978, Utterback, 1994)) product lifecycle model. The hallmark of the framework is a diagram that qualitatively graphs the rate of product innovation and process innovation over time. The nature of innovation, competition, and rivalry pivots on the emergence of a dominant (product) design. Prior to the dominant design in the era of ferment, the focus of innovation is product centric as new firms enter and incumbents reorganize around the competence-destroying technologies or face a possible demise. Following the establishment of a dominant design in the era of incremental change, we expect the remaining firms to leverage their competenceenhancing know-how and to subsequently produce incremental product innovations while P.C. Anderson Page 10 simultaneously competing on the basis of lower costs driven down by process innovations from the manufacturing division (Tushman and Anderson, 1986). The cycle repeats when the next technological disruption occurs (Anderson and Tushman, 1990). Perhaps services fit into the Abernathy/Utterback framework in one of three ways. First, a service is often assumed to be just another product. Services that contain a high degree of explicit knowledge can be codified within a technological system and offered in a standardized manner. For example, a bank that offers a web-based mutual fund for its customers is certainly providing a product. However, many other types of services involve deep tacit knowledge and idiosyncratic know-how that is more human intensive and less technological in nature. Cusumano et al. argue that services exist on a continuum from standardized to customized, and hence they begin to highlight a heterogeneity in service offerings (Cusumano, Kahl and Suarez, Forthcoming). A standalone standardized service offering may perhaps follow a product lifecycle model, but customized services may follow a completely different innovation model which could be orthogonal to the product models. Another dimension for possible heterogeneity to consider is how services are coupled with “traditional” products. ______________________________ Figure 1. Product – Service coupling continuum. ______________________________ Figure 1 demonstrates how a product-service coupling is not a homogeneous across all product-service combinations. Services such as maintenance and product support are usually bundled and tightly coupled to the product. Systems integration and installation are examples of services typically offered as optional and loosely coupled to the product. P.C. Anderson Page 11 Project management and consulting are types of general services that can be independent and uncoupled from the product. An example of a loose product-service coupling is mentioned in EMC’s 2005 annual report: “Installation and professional services are not considered essential to the functionality of our products as these services do not alter the product capabilities, do not require specialized skills and may be performed by our customers or other vendors.” Given the variation in services along a standardized-customized continuum and along a product-service coupling continuum, the product innovation graph in the Abernathy/Utterback framework is not well suited to capture the dynamics of the services phenomenon. Second, services may follow the process innovation graph in the Abernathy/Utterback framework. If a product is in the mature phase of its lifecycle when the market has been saturated and new sales are difficult, maintenance services become an important source of revenue as the product firm refocuses its attention on the installed base of customers (Cusumano, 2004). While this is certainly a plausible explanation, it lacks explanatory power at addressing the heterogeneity in service functions beyond maintenance and product support. A firm whose product sales have drastically declined is not likely to be a legitimate source for cutting edge consulting advice. Therefore, a consulting service may follow a different innovation rate curve than maintenance. P.C. Anderson Page 12 To limit services to a post-product innovation view of the world is to miss an additional role that services may play relative to product innovation. Earlier in the paper, I mentioned how Red Hat uses services as a mechanism to help establish the legitimacy of their Red Hat Linux product and related open source technologies during the era of ferment. In other words, services can positively influence the diffusion of a new technology which is a crucial function for a young firm that faces a liability of newness (Stinchcombe, 1965). Another example is how the diffusion of the mechanized reaper in the 19th century was greatly influenced by service-oriented business models such as renting and cooperative sharing arrangements early in its product lifecycle when the average farmer could not afford to outright own the product (Olmstead, 1975). With services playing a role during early and mature product stages, we should not try to squeeze the services phenomenon into the process innovation graph. Third, the services phenomenon could be a third innovation graph in the Abernathy/Utterback framework or perhaps follow a reverse product cycle as proposed by Barras (Barras, 1986). Given the heterogeneity of service functions, a third innovation curve would be neither plausible nor generalizable across other industrial settings. The product-service coupling would not fit within the Barras reverse product cycle framework. The setting for Barras’ framework is the financial services sector and he equates services to products whereas this paper treats products and services separate yet with varying degrees of coupling. After examining three possible scenarios, the Abernathy/Utterback framework provides a very limited fit for services. P.C. Anderson Page 13 A second highly influential work within product innovation research has been Christensen’s study on the rigid disk drive industry (Clayton M. Christensen, 1993, Christensen, 1997). His findings posit that “good, well managed” incumbent firms fail in the face of radical and disruptive innovations which tend to be best exploited by new startup firms with “good enough” technologies. Although incumbents often have access to the new technologies, they are paralyzed because they listen too attentively to their customers and remain fatally bound to the existing technologies. Christensen’s work follows a component technology within a fast-moving industry undergoing a structural change from vertically integrated to disaggregated specialized firms. The firms in this paper face a similar turbulent and fast-moving industrial setting as the ones in Christensen’s study, but the level of analysis here is more of a systems view (of services) rather than the analysis of one specific component technology (or service). A systems level approach is at a higher level of abstraction and subsequently is able to explore the insights gained from the interdependency of individual components (Henderson and Clark, 1990). In the typesetter industry (Tripsas, 1997), incumbents who possessed the font libraries and sales/service network complementary assets were able to increase their survival chances during technological disruptions since the new entrants did not possess such complementary assets (Teece, 1986). While Christensen argues that firms who pay too much attention to their customers risk a possible demise, firms in this exploratory study appear to view services as a mechanism for gaining deeper insight into customer needs and product usage patterns. Hence, services as a complementary asset – “a second class citizen” at IBM –are not likely to be the sole cause of a product firm collapse given that substitutes are available from thirdP.C. Anderson Page 14 party service providers. Although the industrial setting of this paper is very similar to the rigid disk drive industry in Christensen’s work, the exclusive focus on a component technology is not likely to help explain the evolution of services as a complementary asset during a period of technological change. Services and the Resource Based View of the Firm In the previous section, I showed how services fit very nicely into the complementary asset perspective. In Teece’s paper about profiting from technological innovation, the examples of complementary assets provided were “marketing, competitive manufacturing, and after-sales support” (Teece, 1986). As I explained earlier, services are more heterogeneous than maintenance and product support, but the overall fit as a complementary asset is quite appropriate. A complementary asset may also be a complementary product or technology that is owned by another firm. Rothaermel showed how complementary assets are accessed beyond firm boundaries through strategic alliances and how the number of alliances an incumbent formed with new entrants had a positive effect on firm performance in the biopharmarceutical industry (Rothaermel, 2001). A service in this study is a complementary asset that is managed by the product firm although the asset could be owned or implemented by an external service provider. Although not originally articulated as such, a complementary asset is a resource. More specifically, a complementary asset is a type of resource that is peripheral to the core resources of the firm. Within a product firm in this study, the technological know-how embodied within the R&D organization is typically the core resource of the firm. The P.C. Anderson Page 15 resource-based view of the firm is based on the idea that a firm’s idiosyncratic resource endowment will provide it with a competitive advantage over firms who do not possess a similar resource endowment (Wernerfelt, 1984). Earlier in the paper, we saw how Fiorina was concerned about HP’s ability to compete with limited service resources against IBM. At the time, her team acknowledged that IBM had a competitive advantage over them based on a stronger services resource endowment. The resource-based view of the firm shows promise as a lens through which to consider services. However, I see two shortcomings. First, the firms who create a separate and distinct services organization are actually creating an idiosyncratic mix of resources, know-how, and organizational routines. (Nelson and Winter, 1982). This sounds much broader than a resource and perhaps more like a capability. Second, the resource-based view of the firm is often criticized for being a static framework (Teece, 2007). Since this paper examines the evolution of services over time, perhaps the dynamic capabilities literature is the most salient theoretical lens through which to explore the services phenomenon. Services as a Dynamic Capability In general terms, the strategic management literature views a firm’s organizational skills, know-how, and routines as a capability (Nelson and Winter, 1982, Leonard-Barton, 1992, Kogut and Zander, 1992, Teece, Pisano and Shuen, 1997, Zollo and Winter, 2002). Polaroid had a competitive edge based on its strong technical capabilities in instant photography and strong manufacturing capabilities in precision camera assembly and thin film coating (Tripsas and Gavetti, 2000). HP developed a strong capability in measurement equipment technology (Leonard-Barton, 1992). As market conditions changed over time, the capabilities that made Polaroid and HP leaders became liabilities P.C. Anderson Page 16 and ceased to provide a competitive advantage. Conceptually, a dynamic capability speaks to how a firm is able to adjust its resource endowments and how those adjustments affect firm performance during changing market conditions. Eisenhardt and Martin view dynamic capabilities as the strategic and organizational processes (e.g., product development, strategic alliances, and decision making) that create value for firms in changing markets (Eisenhardt and Martin, 2000). Helfat et al. (Helfat, et al., 2007) define a dynamic capability as “the capacity of an organization to purposefully create, extend, or modify its resource base.” The evolution of services within the computer industry fits the definition of a dynamic capability. First, managers made intentional and purposeful decisions related to their services position. Second, many product firms set out to expand their services resource base through disruptive (e.g., acquisitions) and organic (e.g., hiring new employees) means. Using a longitudinal study of product firms in the intensely-competitive computer industry, this paper begins to explore how a services dynamic capability evolved during a period of technological change, how a services dynamic capability affects firm performance, and how has this evolution has differed by technological focus (hardware systems vs. software)?1 This paper emphasizes the heterogeneity of service functions beyond basic customer service (i.e., maintenance and product support) by proposing a standardized set of service categories through which comparisons can be made across different groupings of firm types. 1 Future research can explore differences by firm size (small, medium, and large), firm age (young, middleaged, and mature), and firm structure (vertically integrated vs. specialized). P.C. Anderson Page 17 III. Empirical Setting: The Computer Industry Background of the Computer Industry Due to space constraints, this paper will briefly summarize the broad themes that have shaped the computer industry structure leading up to 1994 (Flamm, 1988, CampbellKelly and Aspray, 2004, Campbell-Kelly, 2003). The computer industry has gone through four major eras: mainframe computers, minicomputers, personal computers, and networked computers. The big players in the mainframe era were IBM and the Seven Dwarfs (Burrows, Univac, NCR, Control Data, Honeywell, GE, and RCA). The pinnacle of this era was the introduction of the IBM System/360 family of mainframe computers. The minicomputer era was primarily dominated by DEC with its PDP and VAX systems followed by Data General, Wang Laboratories, and Prime Computer. The leading firms during the mainframe and minicomputer eras competed as vertically integrated with a proprietary bundle of integrated circuits, the computer system, operating system (software), and software applications along with product-specific services. The PC era marked a significant sea change in the industry structure as the dominant players were no longer the vertically integrated firms from the previous eras but rather specialized firms who focused on one particular technological area – e.g., Intel for microprocessors, Apple and Compaq for personal computers, Microsoft for the operating system, and many small software product firms. The PC era also marked a shift from proprietary systems to open systems based on industry standard interfaces. As new specialized players entered with narrowly focused strategies, the basis of competition became very product centric. The next major era began as users wanted to share resources among the many personal systems. The networking era started with local area P.C. Anderson Page 18 networks (LANs) based on client-server architectures but eventually exploded with the creation of the web browser that sparked the beginning of the Internet revolution in 1993. The computer industry is known for being fast-paced and intensely competitive (Eisenhardt and Tabrizi, 1995, Bourgeois III and Eisenhardt, 1988, Eisenhardt, 1989, Cusumano and Yoffie, 1998). Although product development processes for hardware and software products came to rely increasingly more on modular architectures and open standards, the products have become increasingly complex to develop (Iansiti, 1995) and also complex to integrate into diverse customer environments (Goodstadt, B. and Kessler, S., 1999, Graham-Hackett, 1999). While each era was marked by a punctuated change with new entrants and product categories, customers were more likely to add capacity with the new products than to rip and replace the older legacy systems that dated back to the mainframe era. By 1994, the industry was structured into three main sets of players: hardware systems firms, software product firms, and independent services firms.2 [NOTE: need an analyst report from 1993. Until then, I’m using 1998 S&P industry reports.] By 1998, hardware revenues were approximately $250 billion with nearly 70% coming from PCs and the remaining from workstations, servers, and the high-performance market. The market share leaders were Compaq, IBM, Dell, HP, and Packard Bell-NEC (Graham-Hackett, 1999). By 1998, packaged software was a $135 billion market where the top five vendors were Microsoft ($16.8 billion), IBM ($13.5 billion), Oracle ($8.0 billion), and 2 The semiconductor (primarily Intel), storage, peripherals, and telecommunications sectors have also shaped the general computer industry. P.C. Anderson Page 19 Computer Associates ($5.1 billion), and SAP ($5.1 billion) (Goodstadt, B. and Kessler, S., 1999). By 1998, worldwide computer services was a $296.4 billion market with IBM as the leading vendor with revenue of $23.4 billion. Two of the leading independent services firms were EDS3 ($16.9 billion), Andersen Consulting4 ($XXX billion), and Computer Sciences Corporation $7.4 billion (Goodstadt, 1999). Technological change between 1994 and 2006 The computer industry underwent disruptive and incremental technological change between 1994 and 2006 that subsequently shaped the environment and product firm strategies. The most notable source of incremental technological change is characterized as Moore’s Law, a popular rule-of-thumb for predicting the increased speed of computers over the last four decades (Campbell-Kelly and Aspray, 2004). While some view Moore’s Law as less of a predictive mechanism and more of a self-fulfilling prophecy (Mollick, 2006), raw performance and price/performance continued to improve between 1994 and 2006 for memory, storage, communication, and processing technologies. This period was marked by major transitions in microprocessor technology from 16-bit to 32bit, 32-bit to 64-bit, and single-core to multi-core on a single chip. As component technologies advance, the corresponding ripple effects occur throughout the industry as witnessed by new hardware systems, devices, and peripherals; new software applications, middleware, and tools; and the accompanying services that help users integrate these products into their IT environment. Users have up to three options for services: their own 3 4 EDS was a spin off from General Motors Corporation in June 1996. Andersen Consulting is now known as Accenture. P.C. Anderson Page 20 internal IT staff, product suppliers, and third-party IT services providers (e.g., EDS or Accenture). While Moore’s Law describes the high-velocity incremental march towards greater performance in this industry, the Internet is the primary disruptive technological change during this period. Although engineers, scientific researchers, and university students were using the Internet by the late 1980’s, it wasn’t until the Mosaic/Netscape browser was made generally available in 1993 that the extraordinary growth of the Internet began to unfold (Campbell-Kelly and Aspray, 2004). The Internet and the subsequent technologies built on it have been a catalyst for new organizational forms (e.g., Internet firms and open innovation projects), new business models, new collaboration tools, and unprecedented access to an abundance of information. The Internet became as much a commercial revolution as an information revolution. Between 1994 and 2006, several open source software projects emerged as credible alternatives to traditional “closed source” proprietary software products. For example, the Linux operating system – started as a hobby by Linus Torvalds in 1991 – evolved into a legitimate business-critical product that is actually favored for some enterprise workloads. At a minimum, open source is a non-technological disruptive change that represents a different development model and forces firms to rethink software product business models. While the product firms in this sample who offer open source software products utilize a services-oriented business model, the long-term competitive and economic implications of the open source model on the existing closed source software model remains uncertain. P.C. Anderson Page 21 IV. Research Methodology Data and Measures Twenty-two large, publicly-traded computer industry product firms were selected as an exploratory sample for this study. These firms have a significant presence in the intensely competitive and financially lucrative enterprise computing market. While many of the firms have a presence in the consumer market, the focus on service capabilities was very evident in the enterprise space. Eleven of the firms generate a majority of their product revenues from software product sales across various categories such as operating systems, middleware, applications, systems management, and tools. The remaining 11 firms generate at least half of their product revenues from hardware systems product sales across categories such as computer systems, networking equipment, storage, and peripherals. Many of the hardware firms also have strong capabilities in software development which results in standalone software products, systems software bundled with the hardware, or as complementary tools. Firms in the sample represent diverse product markets (consumer, enterprise, and technical), innovation models (proprietary and open source), and distribution channels (direct and indirect). See Table 1 for a listing of the firms by SIC code. Although the sample of firms is biased towards large product firms, a shift towards more of a services orientation may possibly become an institutionalized norm throughout the industry. In that case, the findings from this study may indicate a larger industry-wide phenomenon. ______________________________ Table 1. IT product firms in this study. ______________________________ P.C. Anderson Page 22 Qualitative Measures of Service Capabilities Data was analyzed and coded from annual 10-K reports that were filed with the U.S. Security and Exchange Commission (SEC). The 10-K reports were downloaded from the SEC’s Electronic Data Gathering, Analysis, and Reporting (EDGAR) database. I started a content analysis of the business (i.e., Item 1) and management discussion (i.e., Item 7) sections within 257 10-K reports to specifically capture the dialogue relative to a firm’s service capabilities. Electronic copies of the 10-K reports are not available across all 286 firm-years (i.e., 22 firms x 13 years) because two firms were founded after 1994, three firms were acquired prior to 2006, and a few reports were not available in electronic form in the EDGAR database. As I began the content analysis of the 10-K reports, I noticed very little year-to-year fluctuation in categories within a firm. Once a service capability is mentioned in the 10K, it tends to persist across multiple years. Therefore, I coded service capabilities in three-year intervals – 1994, 1997, 2000, 2003, and 2006. Services Taxonomy Although often identified by different names, the coding of service capabilities began to reveal a similarity across firms during the initial phase of the content analysis. For that reason, I sought to utilize a standardized taxonomy that facilitates the ability to compare and contrast service capabilities across firms. In Figure 2, I propose a taxonomy of service categories that highlights the heterogeneity in service capabilities. Lah et al. (Lah, O'Connor and Peterson, 2002, Lah, 2005) present a services taxonomy of computer industry firms that emphasizes the professional services categories. Whereas Lah et al. P.C. Anderson Page 23 distinguish between technical and business consulting, Figure 2 only contains a consulting category. The goal was to create categories only when unique skills, knowhow, and routines were identified. The taxonomy also includes services-oriented business model categories. The hope is that the taxonomy will be a robust lens through which other product industries can be evaluated in future research. ______________________________ Figure 2. Services taxonomy for product firms. ______________________________ The eight categories in Figure 2 are organized into three broad themes consistent across the IT product firms in our sample. Customer service is the baseline level of product support that comes bundled with the product. Professional services tend to be optional services that are typically knowledge worker intensive. Business model driven services are service capabilities that provide customers with new ways to use and access the suppliers’ products. Many of these types of business models began to emerge between 1994 and 2006 (Cusumano, 2008). Customer Service Maintenance and product support services are the baseline level of services usually bundled with the product. Firms often offer extended levels of support beyond the baseline for additional fees. Professional Services P.C. Anderson Page 24 Deployment services include any optional for fee work activities that help customers deploy the product within their data center. Examples are installation, implementation, configuration, systems integration, and migration services. Custom development services involve customization work above and beyond the mass market product offering. Education and training services include product training and certification programs. Consulting services involve a range of technology to business advice which typical. These services may also overlap with implementation services which are included under deployment in this taxonomy. Business Model Driven Services Outsourcing services provide customers with an opportunity to transfer installation and day-to-day operations to the product firm or a third-party. For this study, we will focus only on outsourcing provided through the product firm. Utility computing services provide customers with metered usage of a high-tech product similar to a public utility such as gas or electric service. The product may or may not be installed and maintained on the customer premises. This category has some overlap with outsourcing and exists under various names such as “on demand” computing, pay per use, and software as a service (SaaS). I also lump “pay for access” subscription services under this category. P.C. Anderson Page 25 Financial services provide creative options for customers to purchase products. Examples include leasing and financing. Figures 2 and 3 provide one way to explore the heterogeneity of service capabilities in a longitudinal study of IT product firms. Although Figure 2 shows all service capabilities with a uniform connection to products, Figure 1 earlier highlighted a variation in the product-service coupling with tightly coupled (e.g., bundled services such as maintenance and product support), loosely coupled (e.g., deployment), and uncoupled (e.g., project management or business consulting) services. The maintenance and product support capability is so tightly coupled with the core product that a product-service distinction is often blurred. A few firms changed their categorization of maintenance revenues from services to products between 1994 and 2006. As a qualitative measure in this study, I preserve the original categorization of maintenance as a service capability. This causes no degradation in the qualitative breadth measures because there is no variation in maintenance across firms and years (i.e., maintenance always exists and is always coded as “1”). Breadth and Depth of Services In a given year, a firm’s aggregate service capability index ranges from one (e.g., maintenance is a default service available across all product firms) to eight. A variable is maintained for each of the eight categories and each is coded at three-year intervals (0 = no capability, 1 = service capability). The firm’s aggregated service capability index is a sum of the eight indicator variables. The aggregated index measure provides a rough P.C. Anderson Page 26 breadth indicator of a firm’s strategic intent towards its service capabilities and how the mix changes over time. A firm may subsequently deepen its presence in a service category over a number of years, but that is not captured by the breadth index. Figure 3 presents a two-dimensional framework for analyzing the evolution of services within product firms. ______________________________ Figure 3. Qualitative measures of breadth and depth. ______________________________ While firms are more than willing to publicize (e.g., in 10-K reports and press releases) their range of capabilities, firms are very reluctant to disclose the accompanying depth of resources and investment levels behind those capabilities. Hence, a corresponding service capabilities depth index cannot be measured from 10-K report data. However, depth is being thought of at multiple levels as shown in Figure 3. The baseline begins where a firm provides one or more tightly-coupled product specific services for its own products. As the firm adds service capabilities for products beyond the boundary of the firm such as for partners’ products and competitors’ products, the firm’s service capabilities are considered to be deepening. As a means to expand their sphere of influence, firms often position themselves as a “one-stop shop” and offer comprehensive services that also provide coverage of their competitors’ products. Finally, a product firm may offer services that are entirely product independent such as business consulting or project management. Preliminary evidence of this deepening effect is discussed later in the paper. Quantitative Measures of Service Capabilities and Firm Performance P.C. Anderson Page 27 Since the qualitative measures provide an indication of the strategic intent of firms during a period of technological change, the paper further explores the effect of services on firm performance. Financial data was gathered from 10-K reports, COMPUSTAT, and Mergent Online for the sample of 22 firms between 1994 and 2006. In general, all revenue figures were based on original SEC filings and not restated filings. Exceptions were made in a few cases when original services revenue data included product revenue. For example, in 1994 and 1995 HP’s service revenue included sales of consumable supplies and product parts. In 1996, the service revenues were restated for 1994 and 1995 without the parts and supplies revenues. When revenue data from the public databases (i.e., COMPUSTAT and Mergent Online) did not distinguish between product and service segment revenues, I consulted the 10-K reports and often found the segmented data located in the business or management discussion section. In 1997, a new accounting standard (SFAS 131) was passed stating that firms must report segment financial data by business segments, geographic segments, or both. By 1999, all firms in the sample were reporting segmented services revenue figures. For firms that were not reporting services revenues prior to SFAS 131, the services financial data could often be captured for the two years prior to the first SFAS 131-compliant annual report. Using a cross-sectional time series model, I set out to explore the effect of services on firm performance. Since firms do not consistently break out service revenues across the service categories, I was constrained to explore only the aggregated effect of services contribution on firm performance. With the firm as the unit of analysis, a fixed effects P.C. Anderson Page 28 model is used to explore within firm variation. The results of this model have been moved into the Appendix. Dependent variable Operating income. Operating income is a measure of a firm’s earnings before deduction of interest payments and income taxes. Independent variables Service revenue contribution. This variable is the percentage of total revenues attributed to services. When not accessible in the COMPUSTAT and Mergent Online databases, service revenue data were gathered from the 10-K reports. In order to consider a possible nonlinear relationship between services and firm performance, I include a service revenue contribution squared term. Firm control variables US sales. This variable measures the percentage of sales coming from the United States. In cases where US sales were not available, I operationalized US sales using an estimated percentage of North America sales (e.g., 98%) or Americas sales (e.g., 95%). The 98% and 95% estimates were chosen because historically these firms reported large sums of revenue from US operations. When new geographic segments (e.g., North America or The Americas) were created, most of the sales are still believed to be coming from the US. R&D expenses. This variable measures R&D expenses as a percentage of annual sales. P.C. Anderson Page 29 Firm size. Firm size is operationalized as the log of the total number of employees in a given year. Lagged product sales. The log of one-year lagged product sales is included in order to see how strong or weak product sales from a prior year affect financial outcomes in the following year. Hardware product sales. Although each firm is categorized broadly as either a hardware or software firm during the entire longitudinal study, a fixed effects model drops variables that have no variation across the time period. Therefore, the hardware product sales variable measures the proportion of actual hardware product sales in a given firmyear. Industry control variables Y2K. This variable is included as an indicator of sales that are perhaps driven by the concern for the Year 2000 problem (Y2K) facing firms on January 1, 2000. Y2K contains a value of one across all firms for calendar years 1998 and 1999 and zero otherwise. Dot com bust. This dummy variable controls for the downturn in 2001 caused by the bursting of the dot com bubble. The variable holds a value of one across all firms in calendar year 2001 and is zero for all other years. P.C. Anderson Page 30 V. Empirical Results Qualitative Results Exploring Breadth The graphs in Figure 4 measure the average service capability breadth across the firms as coded at the three-year intervals of 1994, 1997, 2000, 2003, and 2006. Figure 4a suggests that on average all product firms increased their total services footprint between 1994 and 2006 by two capabilities while the net increase for software product firms was approximately one greater than for hardware product firms. Most of the breadth increases occurred by 2000 and remained relatively flat up through 2006. A net increase of three capabilities by software firms slightly exceeded a net increase of two by hardware firms. However, by 2006, hardware and software firms were active with an equivalent number of service capabilities. Figure 4b captures the change in the professional services grouping and suggests that on average all product firms increased their professional services footprint between 1994 and 2006. The net increase for software product firms was nearly two while the net increase for hardware product firms was approximately one capability. Although most of the professional service breadth increases occurred by 2000, software firms experienced a slight increase while hardware firms experienced a slight decrease in professional services between 2000 and 2006. Some hardware firms either withdrew from custom development services altogether or they began to deemphasize custom development as a strategic capability to highlight. P.C. Anderson Page 31 Figure 4c captures the change in the service-oriented business model grouping and suggests that on average all product firms increased their business model services footprint between 1994 and 2006. The net increase for hardware product firms was one while the net increase for software product firms was less than one whole capability. Although most of the business model service breadth increases occurred by 2000 for software firms, hardware firms experienced a continued increase between 2000 and 2006. Intuitively, the business model service capabilities are likely underrepresented in these results due to insufficient data directly available about these capabilities in the 10-K reports. ______________________________ Figure 4. Evolution of Service Capabilities Breadth. ______________________________ Exploring Depth A rigorous operationalization of service capability depth is near impossible to gather from only 10-K reports. However, excerpts from several 10-K reports are suggestive of a deepening effect in services relative to products (i.e., firm, partner and competitor) and services driven independent of any specific products. Intuitively, product suppliers are more likely to provide expanded services for products at or above the level of products in their portfolio relative to a technology solutions stack. More specifically, I expect to see hardware systems firms provide services for products equivalent to their own hardware systems and also for software products further up the stack. However, I do not expect software firms to move down the stack and offer services for a partner’s or competitor’s hardware products. P.C. Anderson Page 32 Services Depth for Firm Products Oracle announced an outsourcing service for its enterprise applications in 1999 where the equipment was hosted on Oracle’s premises: By 2002 Oracle introduced a broader outsourcing service with more flexible options where the equipment could be located on Oracle’s premises, at the customer’s data center, or at a third-party location: Services Depth for Partner Products HP demonstrated an increasing level of services for ERP software products from its partners between 1998 and 2000 in 10-K reports: P.C. Anderson Page 33 Services Depth for Competitor Products Several product firms have sought to position themselves as not only competent in their own product portfolios, but also with respect to products from their partners and even their competitors. For example, DEC in 1994, IBM in 1999, EMC in 2001, and HP in 2002 mention their ability to offer multi-vendor services to position themselves as onestop shops of IT expertise for their customers. P.C. Anderson Page 34 Similar to DEC, IBM, and HP, EMC positioned itself more as an expert general contractor as it continued to articulate its growing support agreement portfolio ties most likely with partners and competitors. P.C. Anderson Page 35 Services Depth Independent of Products As firms started to understand the opportunities available through internet technologies, they began to expand their support delivery mechanisms. While BEA offered basic and comprehensive 7x24 product support via a telephone hot line in 1998, by 2006 they had expanded the support delivery mechanisms to include telephone, web, email, and fax. In 1997, Symantec began to offer a fee-based technical support service called Chat Now! ™. In 1998, Dell “introduced an interactive web-based tool to provide additional customer support.” The ability to have a web-based real-time interactive chat is likely one of the bigger leaps in delivery mechanisms compared to long hold times that often accompany telephone support calls. However, Dell and other firms were offering product support through paid online services such as CompuServe, America Online, and Prodigy and on electronic bulletin boards in the early 1990’s. By 2006, all firms were leveraging online communication mechanisms for product support. Quantitative Results While Cusumano showed the rise in service revenue contribution within software firms (Cusumano, 2004, Cusumano, 2008), Figure 5 shows the product-service contribution proportions between 1994 and 2006 across the collective sample of firms in this study and also split by hardware and software firms. While all IT product firms in this sample experienced a greater contribution from their aggregated services business, software firms became service oriented at a much faster rate than hardware firms. Although the increase in service revenue contribution is quite apparent in Figure 5, that graph only tells a part of the story. If product sales are dropping, a corresponding service contribution P.C. Anderson Page 36 increase may signal a greater reliance on maintenance revenues whereas a simultaneous increase in product sales and service contribution signal product momentum and perhaps an intentional effort to expand the firm’s service capabilities. Figure 6 shows that service contribution has been growing during both product downturns and growth periods. ______________________________ Figure 5. Product and service revenue contribution. ______________________________ ______________________________ Figure 6. Product $ vs. service revenue %. ______________________________ Table 2 displays the firm-year means and correlations for the key variables used in the models. The mean operating income across all firms between 1994 and 2006 is 1.7 billion US dollars and the median value (not shown in Table 2) is 323 million US dollars. IBM and Microsoft are the primary outliers with respect to high levels of operating income during this period. Across all product firm years, the services business generates 35.77% of total sales revenue. The mean number of employees is 38,636 (not shown in Table 2). The mean age is 28.26 years. This sample of firms relies on over half of its sales from customers in the United States. Therefore, in the fast-moving IT industry, our sample represents firms that are relatively large and mature. Due to the wide variation in firm size (i.e., 103 to 355,766 employees) and product revenues (i.e., $0 to $74.2 billion) across firms, the logarithm of those respective variables is used in the models. Although a wide variation in operating income exists across firms, one-fourth of the values are negative and so I did not use logarithms. ______________________________ Table 2. Means and correlation coefficients. P.C. Anderson Page 37 ______________________________ While Table 2 provides the means across all firm years, Table 3 shows that there is a significant difference between the hardware and software firms in the sample by firm age, firm size, R&D spending, and revenue contribution from services. The difference in firm age is likely skewed by the inclusion of IBM and NCR, founded in 1924 and 1884 respectively. Of the firms in this sample, two software firms and one hardware firm were founded while one software firm and two hardware firms were acquired between 1994 and 2006. Consistent with the graphs shown earlier in Figure 5, software product firms are experiencing a growth in services revenue contribution at a faster rate than hardware product firms. Hardware firms require a greater level of capital investment to develop and reproduce their products than software firms. The capital constraints within hardware firms appear to have a moderating effect on the transition to services by hardware firms. ______________________________ Table 3. t tests on mean firm value. ______________________________ VI. Discussion This paper set out to research the evolution of services within an exploratory sample of product-oriented firms and to subsequently see how this phenomenon differs by technology focus (i.e., hardware vs. software firms). The empirical results suggest that product firms in this sample have amplified their services position beyond basic customer service into professional services and into service-oriented business models. While the P.C. Anderson Page 38 professional services functions have similar characteristics to tacit knowledge, the business model services are often new ways of delivering products to market. Technologies such as open source software and virtualization software have forced firms to explore service models such as subscriptions and utility computing, respectively. A further content analysis of 10-K reports suggests preliminary evidence for an increased depth of services from firms in this sample. On one hand, an expansion of existing capabilities relative to the firm’s products is to be expected as a firm continues to grow and mature. On the other hand, an expansion of the role of services that is inclusive of partner products and competitor products is a somewhat surprising and risky tactic. The firm must grow or acquire the expertise as well as exceed a legitimacy threshold in the eyes of customers who may normally obtain such services from the competitor or a third party service provider. During periods of technological change, we know that new firms often drive disruptive change which subsequently causes incumbents to fail (Christensen, 1997). According to Christensen’s framework, we should have seen more incumbents fail and new startups dominate the industry. The empirical setting for Christensen’s work is the rigid disk drive industry which is one device within a larger complex system. Incumbents in complex product categories have opportunities to use standard components in novel ways that provide distinguishable advantages (Henderson and Clark, 1990). Since a component supplier is easier to replace than a vendor of a complex computer system or enterprise software product, I would expect greater turnover in a component industry. As with the typesetter industry (Tripsas, 1997), incumbents that possess a key P.C. Anderson Page 39 complementary asset are more likely to buy more time during an era of technological change or are more able to fight off technological disruptions caused by new firms that do not possess the complementary asset. For firms whose core technological know-how is tied to its products, services appear to be a complementary asset. Through the use of an exploratory longitudinal study, this paper has shown the heterogeneity of service capabilities and also how the evolution in services fits the characteristics of a dynamic capability within the computer industry between 1994 and 2006 (Teece, Pisano and Shuen, 1997). The paradox is that in some firms a complementary asset has become the core revenue generating engine. In other words, some product firms who are traditionally rewarded by analysts and Wall Street for innovative products (i.e., the core resource) are generating their core economic value from services (i.e., the peripheral resource). This paper provides new insight into how a “second class” complementary asset evolves into a central strategic asset. This paradox is more pronounced among the software firms in this sample. Although Figure 5 shows how software firms are moving faster towards services, the preliminary results from the models in Table 5 suggest that the hardware firms may have a better approach. Somewhere between 25% and 40% is the point at which service contribution has a positive effect on firm performance. However, future research ought to explore the effect of the service mix on product revenues. In other words, which mix of service capabilities – maintenance, consulting, outsourcing, etc. – is likely to have the greatest effect on product revenues? P.C. Anderson Page 40 IT customers have three options for services: in-house IT staff, third-party service providers (e.g., EDS and Accenture), and product vendors. The causal mechanisms behind the march towards more services by product vendors are beyond the scope of this data set. However, I speculate that five reasons may contribute to this shift by product firms. First, many IT customers began to look to external partners for help with their IT tasks. While the pace of change increased and the competitive environment intensified between 1994 and 2006, IT customers faced a double-edged sword of implementing new strategic initiatives while simultaneously maintaining their basic infrastructure needs (Hoffman, 1997, Hoffman, 2003). Consequently, CIOs were more willing to outsource some basic infrastructure services to external vendors while facing greater scrutiny of IT budgets from senior executives (Hoffman, 1997, Hoffman, 2003). Following the burst of the dot come bubble, CIOs continued to look for ways to reduce costs through IT enablement but under conditions of greater scrutiny from senior executives (Rosen, 2001). Second, many product categories have shifted away from proprietary products to products based on industry standards. As product margins erode, incumbent product firms are likely to search for new sources of revenue that can be built up in a competence enhancing manner (Tushman and Anderson, 1986). Starting from a base of services coupled to its own products, firms have expanded into services covering partner products and competitor products. However, whether services are the next economic boom for this industry or simply a trap for incumbents no longer able to compete with “the latest Silicon Valley startup and its kamikaze products” (Karlgaard, 1998) remains unclear in the short term. P.C. Anderson Page 41 Third, IT product usage and integration with existing data centers remains complex. Complexity has increased as customers seek to avoid lock-in with one IT product firm which consequently has led to heterogeneous IT environments. This complexity drives the need for more professional services and more flexible support options. With product categories becoming less proprietary and more based on open industry standards, product firms are well-positioned to leverage their product know-how to become legitimate service providers for products beyond their own by either organically growing or acquiring these service capabilities (Zollo and Winter, 2002). Fourth, as customers have reduced their IT budgets, they have become very reluctant to purchase new products when their current IT resources are underutilized. IT customers are searching for ways to increase the efficiency within their existing IT environments. This climate has spurred talk of on-demand and pay-per-use business models as an attempt to solve the underutilization problem (Hamm, 2005). As customers become more dependent on the benefits of IT, customers need increased levels of support service guarantees. The need for increased system uptimes and better resource utilization highlights the need for increased efficiency within business operations. Fifth, professional services and customer support provide additional opportunities for the product firm to strengthen ties with customers and increase learning about future customer needs. While Christensen argued that firms paid too much attention to their customers in the rigid disk drive industry, firms with diverse product portfolios appear to be convinced of the value of customer ties and of the role of services in helping to harvest P.C. Anderson Page 42 that knowledge. Even Microsoft’s support group is intent on creating strong ties with customers as articulated below from their 1994-1999 annual reports. VII. Conclusion Although the results are limited to a small sample of primarily large, diversified technology firms, the empirical findings shed more light on how the services phenomenon is playing out within a very dynamic and rapidly changing industrial setting. This paper contributes to the strategic management and the product innovation literatures. The dynamic capabilities literature has stirred up some great theoretical discussions over the last decade, but the empirical studies have been few and far between. This paper contributes to this literature by empirically showing how a dynamic capability developed around a complementary asset (resource) during a period where firms faced radical and incremental technological change. Within this exploratory sample of firms, we begin to see how services are no longer peripheral but a central and growing resource base within product-oriented firms. In a setting where product innovation is greatly rewarded, this paper shows how a complementary asset evolved into an increasing source of strategic and economic value. Further research is needed to test these concepts across a more systematic sample of firms. P.C. Anderson Page 43 A second contribution of this paper is that it shows the heterogeneity of services beyond the classic “maintenance and product support” function. The paper puts forth a taxonomy by which service endowments across different types of product firms can be compared and contrasted. In this setting, the paper argues that services should not be viewed in a silo but rather as an architectural mix of service capabilities that exist along a productservice coupling continuum – tightly coupled, loosely coupled, and uncoupled. Preliminary evidence suggests that services have a role to play as early as the initial diffusion of a new technology to as late as a technology’s end of life when maintaining an installed customer base becomes the top priority. Future product innovation research would do well to further explore how services affect product innovation. This paper puts forth evidence that uncovers a possible industry-wide variation in service evolution between hardware product firms and software product firms. While the increasing contribution from services in software product firms has been highlighted in other work (Cusumano, 2004, Cusumano, 2008), this paper shows that service contribution is also increasing among some hardware product firms. In addition, this paper shows how service capabilities evolved at different rates among a sample of hardware and software firms that were seeking to adapt to a rapidly changing business environment. Future research should explore how this services phenomenon varies across firm size (e.g., small, medium, and large), firm age (e.g., young, middle-aged, and mature), and firm structure (i.e., vertically integrated vs. specialized firms). The software product firms in this sample experienced a greater net increase in service capabilities and a much more aggressive increase in service revenue contribution than P.C. Anderson Page 44 their hardware product firm counterparts. The hardware firms have a greater exposure to the capital requirements that accompany manufacturing activities such as fixed assets and inventories that perhaps moderated their evolutionary rate towards and reliance on services-generated revenues. However, the models suggest that the hardware firms are better positioned relative to overall firm performance due to more balance between product and service revenues. Hardware firms may be forced to apply greater discipline in product pricing and discounting unlike software firms who may feel more compelled to offer deeper product discounts given that software products can be perfectly replicated at near zero marginal costs (Davis, 2001). Perhaps the software firms are over extended into services and this may highlight a weakness in firm product strategies or larger issues unique to software industry dynamics. A firm deep in service capabilities without a healthy product innovation strategy is likely to struggle. Service capabilities alone are not a silver bullet for product firms lacking a healthy product innovation strategy as we saw large incumbents such as DEC (up to 47%), Compaq (up to 20%), and Seibel (up to 64%) stumble and become acquisition bait between 1994 and 2006. Yet, firms such as IBM (services contribution up to 56%) and HP (services contribution up to 20% and likely to grow much higher as it acquires EDS) continue to increase their dependence on services in the face of technological change. This suggests that a product firm cannot afford to fall asleep at the wheel of product innovation. While a services business can generate value during downturns in product sales, a greater dependence on services within product firms is likely to create a nervous tension within the firm. If a firm’s culture, identity, and path dependency are deeply ingrained with respect to product innovation, the rise of services is likely to not only P.C. Anderson Page 45 negatively affect margins, but also affect product development and product commercialization decisions. The long-term implications of this phenomenon are not clear as to whether this is the source of another boom within the industry or as Bill Gates believed in 1998 a trap for firms who have grown weary from competing in an intenselycompetitive product-oriented environment. To further enhance our understanding of services within a product innovation context, future research is needed at a lower level of analysis than provided in this study. Exploring how the changing mix of service capabilities affects customer retention and financial outcomes may better inform the product strategies of firms. Research that explores the organizational linkages between service and product organizations within firms is likely to reveal greater insights on how knowledge flows between these symbiotic entities affect product development, commercialization, and maintenance activities. Perhaps the rise in service revenue contribution and in service capabilities among this sample of firms is a small indicator of a larger shift in IT product firms. While hardware and software product categories are becoming increasingly more commoditized, this alone is not sufficient to explain an increased emphasis on services by product firms. On one hand, perhaps this is a sign of a mature albeit fast-moving industry characterized by rapid incremental innovations. Much depends on the level of analysis by which one searches for a dominant design. On the other hand, perhaps the rise of services signals a new technological era – one in which customers familiar with digital goods are drowning in a sea of complexity. While commoditization will produce lower prices, the complex P.C. Anderson Page 46 integration of multiple devices, access points, and massive data is likely to continue to attract a larger role for services from product firms. P.C. Anderson Page 47 Appendix 1 – Figures and Tables Figure 1. Product - Service coupling continuum. Services Products Tightly Coupled Loosely Coupled Uncoupled Figure 2. Services taxonomy in product firms. P.C. Anderson Page 48 Figure 3. Qualitative measures of service capabilities breadth and depth. P.C. Anderson Page 49 Figure 4. Evolution of service capabilities breadth. (4a) Average number of service capabilities in a given year (4b) Average number of professional services P.C. Anderson (4c) Average number of business model services Page 50 Figure 5. Product and service revenue contribution between 1994 and 2006. (5a) Averaged across all firms in the sample (5b) Hardware firms only P.C. Anderson (5c) Software firms only Page 51 Figure 6. Service contribution relative to product sales. (6a) Averaged across all firms in the sample (6b) Hardware firms only P.C. Anderson (6c) Software firms only Page 52 Table 1. IT product firms. Hardware firms Software firms Firm SIC code Compaq DEC Dell HP IBM SGI Sun Microsystems EMC NCR Avaya Cisco 3571 3571 3571 3571 3571 3571 3571 3572 3578 3661 3669 Firm BEA BMC CA Intuit Microsoft Novell Oracle Red Hat SAP Siebel Symantec SIC code 7372 7372 7372 7372 7372 7372 7372 7370 7372 7372 7372 Table 3. t tests of means by firm type Variable Firm age (years) Firm size (log employees) R&D spending (%) Revenue from US sales (%) Revenue from product sales (%) Revenue from sales of services (%) P.C. Anderson H/w Firm Mean S/w Firm Mean 38.58 10.38 8.06 52.60 74.69 25.31 19.07 8.81 16.40 61.57 54.21 45.71 Alternative Hypothesis Phw != Phw != Phw != Phw != Phw != Phw != Psw Psw Psw Psw Psw Psw t test Significance 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 Page 53 MOVED FROM TEXT INTO THE APPENDIX DUE TO SMALL SAMPLE SIZE Table 4 contains six firm fixed-effects models that explore the relationship between services contribution and operating income. In models 1 and 2, the services contribution variables provide no significant effect on operating income (R-squared = 0.00). Once the controls for firm size and age are added, the model improves (R-squared = 0.19) and the services contribution variables are significant at the 0.001 and 0.05 levels. Most of the within firm variation is likely explained by the addition of the age variable which is positive and significant at the 0.001 level. Including all firm and industry controls in models 5 and 6 provide similar results as in model 4 with only a marginal increase in within firm variation (R-squared = 0.22). Models 4-6 suggest that services contribution has a negative and significant effect on operating income up until 66% of total sales and then it subsequently has a positive effect on operating income. Although a firm is likely to prefer high-margin maintenance revenues, a services contribution beyond 20% is likely to come from a considerable investment in professional services and business model services. Since professional services are typically more customized (Cusumano, Kahl and Suarez, Forthcoming)and related to know-how (von Hippel, 1994) which accumulates over time, the initial negative magnitude of services contribution followed by a positive effect seems plausible due to the ramp up in personnel. However, the transition point of 66% seems rather high given that many of the hardware product firms have survived with lower levels of service revenue contributions. ______________________________ Table 4. Firm fixed-effects models. ______________________________ P.C. Anderson Page 54 Table 5 runs the same models but separately for hardware and software firms. Although Figure 4 shows how software product firms are increasing their services revenue contribution faster than hardware product firms, Table 5 suggests that services contribution has a significant effect on the operating income of hardware firms but is not significant for software firms. Models 1-4 suggest that services have a negative effect on operating income up until approximately 30%, and then services have a positive effect. Although the sample size is very small, the results seem more plausible than those from the combined sample of Table 4. ______________________________ Table 5. Firm fixed-effects models by technology focus. ______________________________ P.C. Anderson Page 55 P.C. Anderson Page 56 P.C. Anderson Page 57 References Abernathy WJ, Utterback JM. 1978. Patterns of Industrial Innovation. Technology review 80: 40-47. Allen TJ. 1977. Managing the flow of technology : technology transfer and the dissemination of technological information within the R&D organization. MIT Press: Cambridge, Mass. Ancona DG, Caldwell DF. 1992a. Bridging the Boundary: External Activity and Performance in Organizational Teams. Administrative Science Quarterly 37: 634-665. Ancona DG, Caldwell DF. 1992b. Demography and Design: Predictors of New Product Team Performance. Organization Science 3: 321-341. Anderson P, Tushman ML. 1990. Technological Discontinuities and Dominant Designs: A Cyclical Model of Technological Change. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 604633. Baldwin CY, Clark KB. 2000. Design rules. MIT Press: Cambridge, Mass. Barras R. 1986. Towards a theory of innovation in services. Research Policy, 15: 161173. Bourgeois III LJ, Eisenhardt KM. 1988. Strategic Decision Process in High Velocity Environments: Four Cases in the Microcomputer Industry. Management Science 34: 816835. Campbell-Kelly M. 2003. From airline reservations to Sonic the Hedgehog : a history of the software industry. MIT Press: Cambridge, Mass. Campbell-Kelly M, Aspray W. 2004. Computer : a history of the information machine. Westview Press: Boulder, Colo. Christensen CM. 1997. The innovator's dilemma : when new technologies cause great firms to fail. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, Mass. Clayton M. Christensen. 1993. The Rigid Disk Drive Industry: A History of Commercial and Technological Turbulence. The Business History Review 67: 531-588. Cusumano MA. 2004. The business of software : what every manager, programmer, and entrepreneur must know to thrive and survive in good times and bad. New York: Free Press. P.C. Anderson Page 58 Cusumano MA, Kahl S, Suarez F. Forthcoming. A Theory of Services in Product Industries. Cusumano MA. 2008. The Changing Software Business: Moving from Products to Services. IEEE Computer 41: 20-27. Cusumano MA, Yoffie DB. 1998. Competing on Internet time : lessons from Netscape and its battle with Microsoft. Free Press: New York, NY. Davis R. 2001. The Digital Dilemma. Communications of the ACM 44: 77-83. Eisenhardt KM. 1989. Making Fast Strategic Decisions in High-Velocity Environments. Academy of Management Journal 32: 543-576. Eisenhardt KM, Martin JA. 2000. Dynamic Capabilities: what are They? Strategic Management Journal 21: 1105. Eisenhardt KM, Tabrizi BN. 1995. Accelerating Adaptive Processes: Product Innovation in the Global Computer Industry. Administrative Science Quarterly 40: 84-110. Fiorina C. 2006. Tough choices : a memoir. Portfolio: New York. Flamm K. 1988. Creating the computer : government, industry, and high technology. Brookings Institution: Washington, D.C. Gerstner LV. 2002. Who says elephants can't dance? : inside IBM's historic turnaround. HarperCollins Publishers: New York, NY. Goodstadt B. 1999. Computers: Commercial Services, Industry Report. Standard & Poor's: New York, NY. Goodstadt, B. and Kessler, S. 1999. Computer: Software, Industry Report. Standard & Poor's: New York, NY. Graham-Hackett M. 1999. Computers: Hardware, Industry Report. Standard & Poor's: New York, NY. Hamm S. 2005. A Virtual Revolution. Business week 98. Helfat CE, Finkelstein S, Mitchell W, Peteraf MA, Singh H, Teece DJ, Winter SG. 2007. Dynamic capabilities : understanding strategic change in organizations. Blackwell Pub: Malden, MA. Henderson RM, Clark KB. 1990. Architectural Innovation: The Reconfiguration of Existing Product Technologies and the Failure of Established Firms. Administrative Science Quarterly 35: 9-30. Hoffman T. 2003. Gartner survey finds continued CIO focus on cutting costs. Computerworld 37: 13. P.C. Anderson Page 59 Hoffman T. 1997. Pressure is on to cut costs. Computerworld 31: 8. Iansiti M. 1995. Technology integration: Managing technological evolution in a complex environment. Research Policy, 24: 521-542. Karlgaard R. 1998. The road to ruin -- services. Forbes: New York. Kogut B, Zander U. 1992. Knowledge of the Firm, Combinative Capabilities, and the Replication of Technology. Organization Science 3: 383-397. Lah TE. 2005. Mastering professional services. Press Services Professional: Westerville, OH. Lah TE, O'Connor S, Peterson M. 2002. Building professional services the sirens' song. Prentice Hall PTR.: Upper Saddle River, NJ. Leonard-Barton D. 1992. Core Capabilities and Core Rigidities: A Paradox in Managing New Product Development. Strategic Management Journal 13: 111-125. MacCormack A, Verganti R, Iansiti M. 2001. Developing Products on "Internet Time": The Anatomy of a Flexible Development Process. Management Science 47: 133-150. Mollick E. 2006. Establishing Moore's Law. Annals of the History of Computing, IEEE 28: 62-75. Nelson RR, Winter SG. 1982. An evolutionary theory of economic change. Belknap Press of Harvard University Press: Cambridge, Mass. Olmstead AL. 1975. The Mechanization of Reaping and Mowing in American Agriculture, 1833-1870. The Journal of Economic History 35: 327-352. Rosen C. 2001. The shrinking IT budget. InformationWeek 22. Rothaermel FT. 2001. Incumbent's advantage through exploiting complementary assets via interfirm cooperation. Strategic Management Journal 22: 687-699. Stinchcombe AL. 1965. Social Structure and Organizations. Rand McNally: Chicago, IL. Teece DJ, Pisano G, Shuen A. 1997. Dynamic capabilities and strategic management. Strategic Management Journal 18: 509-533. Teece DJ. 2007. Explicating dynamic capabilities: the nature and microfoundations of (sustainable) enterprise performance. Strategic Management Journal 28: 1319-1350. Teece DJ. 1986. Profiting from technological innovation: Implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy. Research Policy, 15: 285-305. P.C. Anderson Page 60 Tripsas M. 1997. Unraveling the process of creative destruction: Complementary assets and incumbent survival in the typesetter industry. Strategic Management Journal 18: 119-142. Tripsas M, Gavetti G. 2000. Capabilities, cognition, and inertia: Evidence from digital imaging. Strategic Management Journal 21: 1147-1161. Tushman ML, Anderson P. 1986. Technological Discontinuities and Organizational Environments. Administrative Science Quarterly 31: 439-465. Utterback JM, Abernathy WJ. 1975. Dynamic Model of Process and Product Innovation. Omega-International Journal of Management Science 3: 639-656. Utterback JM. 2006. Design-inspired innovation. World Scientiific Pub.: Hackensack, NJ. Utterback JM. 1994. Mastering the dynamics of innovation : how companies can seize opportunities in the face of technological change. Harvard Business School Press: Boston, Mass. von Hippel E. 1994. "Sticky Information" and the Locus of Problem Solving: Implications for Innovation. Management Science 40: 429-439. Wernerfelt B. 1984. A Resource-based View of the Firm. Strategic Management Journal 5: 171-180. Zollo M, Winter SG. 2002. Deliberate Learning and the Evolution of Dynamic Capabilities. Organization Science 13: 339-351. P.C. Anderson Page 61