PLIR 8630 Statecraft and International Security Prof. Todd S. Sechser Fall 2014 Office Hours: Mondays, 1:30-3:00pm Office: Gibson #282 Email: todd.sechser@virginia.edu Website: faculty.virginia.edu/tsechser Class Meetings: Wednesdays, 1:00–3:30pm Seminar Room: Gibson #241 Summary This is a seminar devoted to examining prominent research in political science about tools of international statecraft. The course is designed specifically for graduate students intending to write a dissertation or thesis in the field of international security; all others should see the instructor before enrolling. Objectives 1. Evaluate recent social science research about the use and effectiveness of instruments of diplomacy, statecraft, and foreign policy. 2. Build a cache of potential research proposals upon which to draw when selecting a dissertation or thesis topic. 3. Prepare for the comprehensive examination in international relations by gaining familiarity with a broad class of international security literature. General Requirements 1. Complete the Readings. The course will succeed only if students read all assigned readings prior to class meetings. Required books will be available at the University of Virginia Bookstore; all other readings can be accessed via Collab. For those who wish to follow up on specific interests later, supplementary books and articles (denoted by +) are listed below the required readings. 2. Contribute to Class Discussion. Discussion constitutes the entirety of each seminar meeting; students must come prepared to offer critical thoughts on each of the readings. –1– 3. Write Six Research Proposals. Six times during the semester, students must prepare a one-page research proposal related to the week’s topic. (Each student may choose four off-weeks.) Proposals should describe one puzzle raised by the readings or during class discussions and propose a brief research plan for resolving it. Proposals must be uploaded to Collab in pdf format not later than 24 hours before each class meeting. 4. Present A Research Proposal. In the last class session, students will briefly present one of their six research proposals, and answer questions from the class. 5. Writing Assignment. Students must complete one of the following writing assignments: (a) Final Exam. Students who have not taken comprehensive examinations may choose this option. The final examination mimics the format of the department’s exams: students will choose one essay question to answer in a two-hour period. The use of books and notes will be prohibited. (b) Write a Review Essay. Students who have already taken comprehensive examinations will prepare a review essay evaluating one week’s readings. Essays must be no longer than 3,500 words and must be uploaded to Collab in pdf format not later than 24 hours before the class in which the readings are to be discussed. A good review essay will contain the following elements: • Critique the theoretical argument. Essays should not just summarize the material. What are the independent, independent, and intervening variables? Is the causal logic plausible? Are there reasons the argument might be problematic? • Assess the empirical evidence. Are the cases chosen appropriately? Are the variables operationalized well? Might alternative tests be equally valid? If the author’s data are available, can you replicate the results? How robust (or fragile) are they? • Discuss related literature. How does this literature compare and contrast with other work on the subject? What are the origins of this research agenda? How far has the literature come? Has it made progress? • Add value. This is the most important and difficult element of the paper. Can you suggest new hypotheses, data sources, or research strategies? Are there alternative explanations that need to be considered? Can the research design be improved? Suggest how we might move forward. For a model of a nice review essay, see Jack S. Levy, “Misperception and the Causes of War: Theoretical Linkages and Analytical Problems,” World Politics 36:1 (October 1983), pp. 76–99 (available on Collab). Assignments and Evaluation There are three main components to the final semester grade. –2– • Participation 30% • Research Proposals and Presentation 40% • Writing Assignment 30% Professionalism, Ethics, and Other Policies 1. In-Class Distractions. Please remember to turn off your phones before class. Texting during class is distracting for the instructor, those around you, and most importantly, you. 2. Late Arrivals. Please be prompt so that class may begin and end on time. 3. Academic Integrity. Cheating and plagiarism are taken very seriously in this course. All assignments must be solely the original work of the student. Quoting or paraphrasing another author without attribution on any written assignment is considered plagiarism. Avoid plagiarism by using footnotes (with page numbers) whenever you quote, paraphrase, or otherwise borrow someone else’s ideas. Citing others’ work is a standard scholarly practice, and there is no punishment for having too many citations. If you are unsure whether you are committing plagiarism, do not hesitate to ask the instructor for guidance (before you submit your work). Violators risk failing the course and being reported to the Honor Committee. 4. Group Collaboration. Colleagues are essential to one’s intellectual growth, and I urge students to collaborate with classmates. Sharing written summaries, reading draft papers, and commenting on others’ work are all acceptable forms of collaboration. On the other hand, writing portions of a classmate’s paper or copying a paragraph from a book or website without attribution are very serious violations. 5. Late Assignments. Late assignments will not be accepted for any reason. To ensure that illness, computer failures, or other unanticipated events do not cause you to miss an assignment deadline, it is recommended that you begin the assignments well in advance of the deadline. Further, you should back up your work off-site using the University’s Home Directory or Box services, Google Drive, Dropbox, or another free cloud backup service. Books and Readings The following books are required and available at the University of Virginia Bookstore. All other readings can be accessed on Collab. • Reiter, D. and Stam, A. C. (2002). Democracies at War. Princeton University Press, Princeton. • Fortna, V. P. (2004b). Peace Time: Cease-Fire Agreements and the Durability of Peace. Princeton University Press, Princeton. –3– • Pape, R. A. (1996). Bombing to Win: Air Power and Coercion in War. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y. • Press, D. G. (2005). Calculating Credibility: How Leaders Assess Military Threats. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y. • Schelling, T. C. (1966). Arms and Influence. Yale University Press, New Haven. Students should also become familiar with the following book if they are not already: • King, G., Keohane, R. O., and Verba, S. (1994). Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton University Press, Princeton. Schedule Readings denoted by “•” are required; those denoted by “+” are supplementary. 1. August 27: Organizational Meeting 2. September 3: When Does Deterrence Work? A Debate • Huth, P. K. and Russett, B. (1988). Deterrence failure and crisis escalation. International Studies Quarterly, 32(1):29–45. • Lebow, R. N. and Stein, J. G. (1990). Deterrence: The elusive dependent variable. World Politics, 42(3):336–369. • Huth, P. K. and Russett, B. (1990). Testing deterrence theory: Rigor makes a difference. World Politics, 42(4):466–501. • Fearon, J. D. (1994b). Signaling versus the balance of power and interests: An empirical test of a crisis bargaining model. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 38(2):236– 269. • Fearon, J. D. (2002). Selection effects and deterrence. International Interactions, 28(1):5–29. + Huth, P. K. (1988). Extended Deterrence and the Prevention of War. Yale University Press, New Haven. + Achen, C. H. and Snidal, D. (1989). Rational deterrence theory and comparative case studies. World Politics, 41(2):143–169. + Jervis, R. (1989b). Rational deterrence: Theory and evidence. World Politics, 41(2):183–207. + George, A. L. and Smoke, R. (1989). Deterrence and foreign policy. World Politics, 41(2):170–182. + Huth, P. K. (1990). The extended deterrent value of nuclear weapons. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 34(2):270–290. –4– + Huth, P. K. (1999). Deterrence and international conflict: Empirical findings and theoretical debates. Annual Review of Political Science, 2:25–48. + Signorino, C. S. and Tarar, A. (2006). A unified theory and test of extended immediate deterrence. American Journal of Political Science, 50(3):586–605. 3. September 10: Democracies, Signals, and Credibility • Fearon, J. D. (1994a). Domestic political audiences and the escalation of international disputes. American Political Science Review, 88(3):577–592. • Schultz, K. A. (1999). Do democratic institutions constrain or inform? Contrasting two institutional perspectives on democracy and war. International Organization, 53(2):233–266. • Tomz, M. (2007). Domestic audience costs in international relations: An experimental approach. International Organization, 61(4):821–840. • Weeks, J. L. (2008). Autocratic audience costs: Regime type and signaling resolve. International Organization, 62(1):35–64. • Snyder, J. and Borghard, E. (2011). The cost of empty threats: A penny, not a pound. American Political Science Review, 105(3):437–456. • Downes, A. B. and Sechser, T. S. (2012). The illusion of democratic credibility. International Organization, 66(3):457–89. • Potter, P. B. and Baum, M. A. (2014). Looking for audience costs in all the wrong places: Electoral institutions, media access, and democratic constraint. Journal of Politics, 76(1):167–81. • Moon, C. and Souva, M. (2014). Audience costs, information, and credible commitment problems. Journal of Conflict Resolution, (forthcoming). + Schultz, K. A. (2001). Democracy and Coercive Diplomacy. Cambridge University Press, New York. + Gelpi, C. and Griesdorf, M. (2001). Winners or losers? Democracies in international crisis, 1918–94. American Political Science Review, 95(3):633–47. + Guisinger, A. and Smith, A. (2002). Honest threats: The interaction of reputation and political institutions in international crises. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 46(2):175–200. + Slantchev, B. L. (2006). Politicians, the media, and domestic audience costs. International Studies Quarterly, 50(2):445–477. + Clare, J. (2007). Domestic audiences and strategic interests. Journal of Politics, 69(3):732–45. + Trager, R. F. and Vavreck, L. (2011). The political costs of crisis bargaining: Presidential rhetoric and the role of party. American Journal of Political Science, 55(3):526–45. + Haynes, K. (2012). Lame ducks and coercive diplomacy: Do executive term limits reduce the effectiveness of democratic threats? Journal of Conflict Resolution, (forthcoming). –5– + Trachtenberg, M. (2012). Audience costs: An historical analysis. Security Studies, 21(1):3–42. + Schultz, K. A. (2012). Why we needed audience costs and what we need now. Security Studies, 21(3):369–75. + Gartzke, E. and Lupu, Y. (2012). Still looking for audience costs. Security Studies, 21(3):391–397. + Slantchev, B. L. (2012). Audience cost theory and its audiences. Security Studies, 21(3):376–382. + Levy, J. S. (2012). Coercive threats, audience costs, and case studies. Security Studies, 21(3):383–90. + Weiss, J. C. (2013). Authoritarian signaling, mass audiences, and nationalist protest in China. International Organization, 67(1):1–35. 4. September 17: The Utility of Air Power • Pape, R. A. (1996). Bombing to Win: Air Power and Coercion in War. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y, chapters 1–3 and 9. • Reiter, D. and Horowitz, M. (2001). When does aerial bombing work? Quantitative empirical tests, 1917–1999. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 45(2):147–173. • Stigler, A. L. (2002). A clear victory for air power: nato’s empty threat to invade Kosovo. International Security, 24(4):5–38. • Lake, D. R. (2009). The limits of coercive airpower: nato’s “victory” in Kosovo revisited. International Security, 34(1):83–112. • Kocher, M. A., Pepinsky, T. B., and Kalyvas, S. (2011). Aerial bombing and counterinsurgency in the Vietnam War. American Journal of Political Science, 55(2):201–18. • Lyall, J. (2014). Bombing to lose? Airpower and the dynamics of violence in counterinsurgency wars. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the International Studies Association, Toronto, March 26–29. + Watts, B. D. (1997/1998). Ignoring reality: Problems of theory and evidence in security studies. Security Studies, 7(12):115–71. + Warden, J. A. (1997/1998). Success in modern war: A response to Robert Pape’s bombing to win. Security Studies, 7(12):172–90. + Pape, R. A. (1997/1998a). The Air Force strikes back: A reply to Barry Watts and John Warden. Security Studies, 7(12):191–214. + Byman, D. L. and Waxman, M. C. (2000). Kosovo and the great air power debate. International Security, 24(4):5–38. + Press, D. G. (2001). The myth of air power in the Persian Gulf War and the future of warfare. International Security, 26(2):5–44. 5. September 24: Nuclear Coercion –6– • Schelling, T. C. (1966). Arms and Influence. Yale University Press, New Haven, chapters 1–3. • Betts, R. K. (1987). Nuclear Blackmail and Nuclear Balance. Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C, chapters 1 and 4. • Jervis, R. (1989a). The Meaning of the Nuclear Revolution: Statecraft and the Prospect of Armageddon. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y, chapter 1. • Beardsley, K. and Asal, V. (2009). Winning with the bomb. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 53(2):278–301. • Sechser, T. S. and Fuhrmann, M. (2013). Crisis bargaining and nuclear blackmail. International Organization, 67(4):173–95. • Kroenig, M. (2013). Nuclear superiority and the balance of resolve: Explaining nuclear crisis outcomes. International Organization, 67(1):141–71. • Gavin, F. J. (2014). What we talk about when we talk about nuclear weapons: A review essay. H-Diplo/International Security Studies Forum, (2):11–36. • Fuhrmann, M., Kroenig, M., and Sechser, T. S. (2014). The case for using statistics to study nuclear security. H-Diplo/International Security Studies Forum, (2):37– 54. + Brodie, B., editor (1972). The Absolute Weapon: Atomic Power and World Order. Harcourt, Brace, New York. + Nitze, P. H. (1956). Atoms, strategy, and policy. Foreign Affairs, 34(2):187–198. + Kissinger, H. (1957). Nuclear Weapons and Foreign Policy. Council on Foreign Relations, New York. + Schelling, T. C. (1960). The Strategy of Conflict. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. + Jervis, R. (1979). Why nuclear superiority doesn’t matter. Political Science Quarterly, 94(4):617–33. + Powell, R. (1990). Nuclear Deterrence Theory: The Search for Credibility. Cambridge University Press, New York. + Trachtenberg, M. (1991). History and Strategy. Princeton University Press, Princeton. 6. October 1: Are Reputations Worth Building? • Mercer, J. (1996). Reputation and International Politics. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y, chapters 1–2. • Copeland, D. C. (1997). Do reputations matter? Security Studies, 7(1):33–71. • Press, D. G. (2005). Calculating Credibility: How Leaders Assess Military Threats. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, N.Y, chapters 1–2 and 5. • Sartori, A. E. (2002). The might of the pen: A reputational theory of communication in international disputes. International Organization, 56(1):121–149. –7– • Nalebuff, B. (1991). Rational deterrence in an imperfect world. World Politics, 43(3):313–335. • Weisiger, A. and Yarhi-Milo, K. (2014). Revisiting reputation: How past actions matter in international politics. International Organization, (forthcoming). + Walter, B. F. and Tingley, D. H. (2011). The effect of repeated play on reputation building: An experimental approach. International Organization, 65(2):343–65. + Hopf, T. (1991). Soviet inferences from their victories in the periphery: Visions of resistance or cumulating gains? In Jervis, R. and Snyder, J., editors, Dominoes and Bandwagons: Strategic Beliefs and Great Power Competition in the Eurasian Rimland, pages 145–189. Oxford University Press, New York. + Hopf, T. (1995). Peripheral Visons: Deterrence Theory and American Foreign Policy in the Third World, 1965-1990. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor. + Huth, P. K. (1997). Reputations and deterrence: A theoretical and empirical assessment. Security Studies, 7(1):72–99. + Walter, B. F. (2006). Building reputation: Why governments fight some separatists but not others. American Journal of Political Science, 50(2):313–330. + Gibler, D. M. (2008). The costs of reneging: Reputation and alliance formation. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(3):426–454. + Sechser, T. S. (2010). Goliath’s Curse: Coercive Threats and Asymmetric Power. International Organization, 64(4):627–60. + Crescenzi, M. J., Kathman, J. D., Kleinberg, K. B., and Wood, R. M. (2012). Reliability, reputation, and alliance formation. International Studies Quarterly, 56(2):259–74. 7. October 8: Democracies and Military Effectiveness • Reiter, D. and Stam, A. C. (2002). Democracies at War. Princeton University Press, Princeton, chapters 1–3 and 8. • Lake, D. A. (1992). Powerful pacifists: Democratic states and war. American Political Science Review, 86(1):24–37. • Desch, M. C. (2002). Democracy and victory: Why regime type hardly matters. International Security, 27(2):5–47. • Downes, A. B. (2009b). How smart and tough are democracies? Reassessing theories of democratic victory in war. International Security, 33(4):9–51. + Choi, A. (2003). The power of democratic cooperation. International Security, 28(1):142–153. + Lake, D. A. (2003). Fair fights? Evaluating theories of democracy and victory. International Security, 28(1):154–167. + Desch, M. C. (2003). Democracy and victory: Fair fights or food fights? International Security, 28(1):180–194. –8– + Schultz, K. A. and Weingast, B. R. (2003). The democratic advantage: Institutional foundations of financial power in international competition. International Organization, 57(1):3–42. + Choi, A. (2004). Democratic synergy and victory in war, 1816–1992. International Studies Quarterly, 48(3):663–682. + Reiter, D. and Stam, A. C. (2009). Correspondence: Another skirmish in the battle over democracies and war. International Security, 34(2):194–200. + Downes, A. B. (2009a). Correspondence: Another skirmish in the battle over democracies and war. International Security, 34(2):200–204. + Henderson, E. A. and Bayer, R. (2013). Wallets, ballots, or bullets: Does wealth, democracy, or military capabilities determine war outcomes? International Studies Quarterly, 57(2):303–17. 8. October 15: Keeping the Peace • Fortna, V. P. (2004b). Peace Time: Cease-Fire Agreements and the Durability of Peace. Princeton University Press, Princeton, entire. • Werner, S. and Yuen, A. (2005). Making and keeping peace. International Organization, 59(2):261–92. • Walter, B. F. (1997). The critical barrier to civil war settlement. International Organization, 51(3):335–364. • Sambanis, N. (2000). Partition as a solution to ethnic war: An empirical critique of the theoretical literature. World Politics, 52(4):437–483. • Fortna, V. P. (2004a). Does peacekeeping keep peace? International intervention and the duration of peace after civil war. International Studies Quarterly, 48(2):269–92. + Kecskemeti, P. (1958). Strategic Surrender: The Politics of Victory and Defeat. Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif. + Pillar, P. R. (1983). Negotiating Peace: War Termination as a Bargaining Process. Princeton University Press, Princeton. + Goemans, H. E. (2000). War and Punishment: The Causes of War Termination and the First World War. Princeton University Press, Princeton. + Ramsay, K. W. (2008). Settling it on the field: Battlefield events and war termination. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 52(6):850–79. + Stanley, E. A. (2009). Paths to Peace: Domestic Coalition Shifts, War Termination and the Korean War. Stanford University Press, Stanford, Calif. + Reiter, D. (2009). How Wars End. Princeton University Press, Princeton. 9. October 22: Economic Sanctions • Pape, R. A. (1997). Why economic sanctions do not work. International Security, 22(2):90–136. –9– • Elliott, K. A. (1998). The sanctions glass: Half full or completely empty? International Security, 23(1):50–65. • Drezner, D. W. (2000). Bargaining, enforcement, and multilateral sanctions: when is cooperation counterproductive? International Organization, 54(1):73–102. • Hovi, J., Huseby, R., and Sprinz, D. F. (2005). When do (imposed) economic sanctions work? World Politics, 57(4):479–99. • Marinov, N. (2005). Do economic sanctions destabilize country leaders? American Journal of Political Science, 49(3):564–576. • Wood, R. M. (2008). “A hand upon the throat of the nation”: Economic sanctions and state repression, 1976–2001. International Studies Quarterly, 52(3):489–513. • Escribà-Folch, A. and Wright, J. (2010). Dealing with tyranny: International sanctions and the survival of authoritarian rulers. International Studies Quarterly, 54(2):335–359. + Pape, R. A. (1998b). Why economic sanctions still do not work. International Security, 23(1):66–77. + Drezner, D. W. (1999). The Sanctions Paradox: Economic Statecraft and International Relations. Cambridge University Press, New York. + Kirshner, J. (2002). Economic sanctions: The state of the art. Security Studies, 11(4):160–79. + Lektzian, D. and Souva, M. (2007). An institutional theory of sanctions onset and success. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 51(6):848–871. + Morgan, T. C., Bapat, N., and Krustev, V. (2009). The threat and imposition of economic sanctions, 1971–2000. Conflict Management and Peace Science, 26(1):92–110. 10. October 29: Fighting Against Non-State Actors • Edelstein, D. (2004). Occupational hazards: Why military occupations succeed or fail. International Security, 29(1):49–91. • Kalyvas, S. N. (2006). The Logic of Violence in Civil War. Cambridge University Press, New York, pp. 146–72. • Lyall, J. (2009). Does indiscriminate violence incite insurgent attacks? Evidence from a natural experiment. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 53(3):331–62. • Lyall, J. (2010b). Do democracies make inferior counterinsurgents? Reassessing democracy’s impact on war outcomes and duration. International Organization, 64(1):167–92. • Downes, A. B. and Cochran, K. M. (2010). It’s a crime, but is it a blunder? The efficacy of targeting civilians in war. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C., September 2–5. • Toft, M. D. and Zhukov, Y. M. (2012). Denial and punishment in the North Caucasus: Evaluating the effectiveness of coercive counter-insurgency. Journal of Peace Research, 49(6):785–800. – 10 – + Downes, A. B. (2007). Draining the sea by filling the graves: Investigating the effectiveness of indiscriminate violence as a counterinsurgency strategy. Civil Wars, 9(4):420–44. + Lyall, J. and Wilson, I. (2009). Rage against the machines: Explaining outcomes in counterinsurgency wars. International Organization, 63(1):67–106. + Lyall, J. (2010a). Are coethnics more effective counterinsurgents? Evidence from the second Chechen War. American Political Science Review, 104(1):1–20. + Friedman, J. A. (2011). Manpower and counterinsurgency: Empirical foundations for theory and doctrine. Journal of Strategic Studies, 20(4):556–91. + MacDonald, P. K. (2013). “Retribution must succeed rebellion”: The colonial origins of counterinsurgency failure. International Organization, 67(2):253–286. + Getmansky, A. (2013). You can’t win if you don’t fight: The role of regime type in counterinsurgency outbreaks and outcomes. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 57(4):709–34. ? November 5: No Class 11. November 12: Terrorism and Counterterrorism • Kydd, A. H. and Walter, B. F. (2006). The strategies of terrorism. International Security, 31(1):49–80. • Pape, R. A. (2003). The strategic logic of suicide terrorism. American Political Science Review, 97(3):343–361. • Cronin, A. K. (2006). How al-Qaida ends: The decline and demise of terrorist groups. International Security, 31(1):7–48. • Gould, E. D. and Klor, E. F. (2010). Does terrorism work? Quarterly Journal of Economics, 125(4):1459–1510. • Abrahms, M. (2012). The political effectiveness of terrorism revisited. Comparative Political Studies, 45(3):366–393. • Johnston, P. B. (2012). Does decapitation work? Assessing the effectiveness of leadership targeting in counterinsurgency campaigns. International Security, 36(4):47–79. • Jordan, J. (2014). Attacking the leader, missing the mark: Why terrorist groups survive decapitation strikes. International Security, 38(4):7–38. + Abrahms, M. (2006). Why terrorism does not work. International Security, 31(2):42–78. + Jordan, J. (2009). When heads roll: Assessing the effectiveness of leadership decapitation. Security Studies, 18(4):719–55. + Price, B. C. (2012). Targeting top terrorists: How leadership decapitation contributes to counterterrorism. International Security, 36(4):9–46. – 11 – + Carvin, S. (2012). The trouble with targeted killing. Security Studies, 21(3):529– 555. 12. November 19: War and the Public • Jentleson, B. W. (1992). The pretty prudent public: Post post-Vietnam American opinion on the use of military force. International Studies Quarterly, 36(1):49–73. • Gelpi, C., Feaver, P., and Reifler, J. (2005). Success matters: Casualty sensitivity and the war in Iraq. International Security, 30(3):7–46. • Boettcher, W. A. and Cobb, M. D. (2006). Echoes of Vietnam? Casualty framing and public perceptions of success and failure in Iraq. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 50(6):831–854. • Liberman, P. (2006). An eye for an eye: Public support for war against evildoers. International Organization, 60(3):687–722. • Berinsky, A. J. (2007). Assuming the costs of war: Events, elites, and American public support for military conflict. Journal of Politics, 69(4):975–997. • Gartner, S. S. (2008). The multiple effects of casualties on public support for war: An experimental approach. American Political Science Review, 102(1):95–106. • Groeling, T. and Baum, M. A. (2008). Crossing the water’s edge: Elite rhetoric, media coverage, and the rally-round-the-flag phenomenon. Journal of Politics, 70(4):1065–1085. + Eichenberg, R. C. (2005). Victory has many friends: US public opinion and the use of military force, 1981–2005. International Security, 30(1):140–177. + Berinsky, A. J. and Druckman, J. N. (2007). Public opinion research and support for the Iraq war. Public Opinion Quarterly, 71(1):126–141. + Gelpi, C., Feaver, P. D., and Reifler, J. (2009). Paying the Human Costs of War: American Public Opinion and Casualties in Military Conflicts. Princeton University Press, Princeton. + Berinsky, A. J. (2009). In time of war: Understanding American public opinion from World War II to Iraq. University of Chicago Press, Chicago. + Baum, M. A. and Groeling, T. (2010). Reality asserts itself: Public opinion on Iraq and the elasticity of reality. International Organization, 64(3):443–479. + Grieco, J. M., Gelpi, C., Reifler, J., and Feaver, P. D. (2011). LetâĂŹs get a second opinion: International institutions and american public support for war. International Studies Quarterly, 55(2):563–583. + Althaus, S. L. and Coe, K. (2011). Priming patriots: Social identity processes and the dynamics of public support for war. Public Opinion Quarterly, 75(1):65–88. + Althaus, S. L., Bramlett, B. H., and Gimpel, J. G. (2012). When war hits home: The geography of military losses and support for war in time and space. Journal of Conflict Resolution, 56(3):382–412. – 12 – ? November 26: No Class (Thanksgiving) 13. December 3: Research Presentations • Students this week will choose one of their research proposals to present. Audience members will play the role of a National Science Foundation grant committee evaluating grant proposals for funding. Presentations will last 10 minutes, with 10–15 minutes of questions from the audience. [Updated: November 13, 2014] – 13 –