National Poverty Center Gerald R. Ford School of Public Policy, University of Michigan www.npc.umich.edu “Consumption, Income, and the Well‐Being of Families and Children” This paper was delivered at a National Poverty Center conference. Any opinions, findings, conclusions, or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the view of the National Poverty Center or any sponsoring agency. Poverty in the U.S. Based on NAS Recommendations: Income and Expenditures by Thesia I. Garner1 and Kathleen S. Short2 April 28, 2006 Discussant: Gary Burtless, Brookings Institution Conference on Consumption, Income, and the Well‐Being of Families and Children Sponsored by the National Poverty Center with Funding from the Office of the Assistant Secretary for Planning and Evaluation, U.S. Department of Health and Human Services Thursday and Friday, May 4‐5, 2006 Hyatt Regency Washington on Capitol Hill, Washington, D.C. JEL Classification: I320 Measurement and Analysis of Poverty _____________________________________________________________________________________________ 1 Thesia I. Garner, Senior Research Economist, Division of Price and Index Number Research, Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), U.S. Department of Labor, Washington, D.C., garner.thesia@bls.gov, (202) 691 – 6576. 2 Kathleen S. Short, Senior Research Economist, Housing and Household Economic Statistics Division, U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, D.C. 20233, kshort@census.gov, (301) 763 – 8921. Part of this paper draws on results presented by Garner and Short during the 2005 Joint Statistical Meetings (JSM), Minneapolis, Minnesota. The comments of Timothy Smeeding, discussant at the JSM session, are appreciated, as are those of other participants in the session. The comments of colleagues in the BLS Division of Price and Index Number Research, particularly Ralph Bradley, Rob McClelland, and Uri Kogan, greatly improved this research. Appreciation is extended to Rob Cage who provided invaluable assistance with regard to the U.S. Consumer Price Index (CPI), and Laura Paszkiewicz with regard to the U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey. Census Bureau disclaimer: This paper is released to inform interested parties of ongoing research and to encourage discussion of work in progress. The views expressed on statistical, methodological, technical, or operational issues are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the U.S. Census Bureau. Bureau of Labor Statistics disclaimer: The views expressed in this research are solely those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official positions or policies of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics or the views of other staff members. The author accepts responsibility for all errors. Abstract -- This paper presents an alternative to the current official measure, now more than 40 years old. It describes a new approach to measure basic needs and a consistent measure of family resources that are available to people and families to meet those needs. Poverty thresholds are based on out-of-pocket spending by families on basic goods and services. Resources are defined in terms of income and expenditures. A new measure of resources, out-of-pocket expenditures that include allocations to savings with adjustments for necessary expenses, is compared to the spending-based threshold. This measure represents the money spent or obligated by the household, its “outflows,” that reflect a certain level of living. These “outflows” could be supported from current income, savings, or dis-savings. In contrast to the expenditure-based measure used in this study, a consumption measure would reflect the implicit value of the goods and services that the household consumes. Consumption too could be financed out of the same sources as expenditures; however, implicit valuations must be made to determine levels of material wellbeing. A resource measure based on an “inflows” concept reflects money coming into the household that is available to meet one’s basis needs. Using data for 2001-2003, results from income- and expenditure-based analyses are compared. An important finding is that increases in expenditures for medical care, utilities, and shelter, captured in the experimental poverty threshold, suggest a greater increase in the number of families not able to meet basic needs than is reflected by the official poverty statistics. Income as opposed to expenditure-based resources results in lower poverty rates. Not surprisingly, subtracting necessary work related expenses and other financial obligations increases the probability that someone is below the spending-based threshold. Keywords: Consumer Expenditures, Income Measures, Poverty Thresholds, Poverty Measurement 2 I. Introduction In 1995, the National Academy Sciences (NAS) Panel on Poverty and Family Assistance, under the auspices of the Committee on National Statistics (CNSTAT), published a report, Measuring Poverty, A New Approach (Citro and Michael, 1995). In their report, recommendations were made that the current official measure of poverty should be revised. The Panel argued that the official poverty measure is outdated given the changes in U.S. society and in government policies (Citro and Michael, 1995; also see Ruggles, 1990). They noted that the current measure does not account for the increased labor force participation of mothers and working families in general. It does not account for differences in health care costs and needs. Family size adjustments in the thresholds are anomalous in many respects. As living standards and notions of minimum needs change, thresholds too should change. Resources should reflect changes in government policies that make it possible for families to meet their basic needs. Regarding the threshold, the Panel stated that the current poverty threshold “no longer represents the concept on which it was originally based—namely, food times a food share multiplier [the percentage of after-tax money income spent on food]—because that share will change (and has changed) with rising living standards. Rather, the poverty threshold reflects in today’s dollars the line that was set some 30 [now 40] years ago” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 25). The Panel noted that total expenditures of families have increased in real terms, and spending on nonfood items has risen more rapidly than spending on food. While expenditures on food accounted for one-third of the after-tax money income in the 1950s, they account for less than one-sixth of the total today. The Panel stated, “If the original approach were used to develop the poverty thresholds today, their value would be significantly higher” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 30). 1 1 The authors conducted an exercise to determine what the threshold would be if the same procedure were used today as was used to derive the official threshold 40 years ago. U.S. Consumer Expenditure Survey quarterly income and expenditure data from 2003Q1 through 2004Q1 were used along with the U.S. average value of the USDA Thirty Food Plan in June 2003 (USDA, 2003). The Food Plan assumes that all meals and snacks are purchased at stores and prepared at home. Since the Food Plan is based on the ages of older children and adults and the gender of family members, the value of the Plan for a specific four-person family was used to determine the value of the food adequacy standard for this exercise. The family was composed of a husband and wife who are both in the 20-50 year age range, one child who is 2 years old, and another who is in the 3-5 year age range. After-tax money income data with imputations for missing values are not available in the CE, so food shares are derived using total before-tax money income (with imputations for missing data), total expenditures and consumption expenditures. Total expenditures are defined by the Bureau of Labor Statistics for publication of CE data (USDL, 1997; BLS 2004). Consumption expenditures are a subset of total expenditures but do not include cash contributions, insurance premiums for life or other personal insurance, or contributions to retirement accounts or Social Security. The food share of before tax money income for a four-person consumer unit was 10 percent, the food share of published CE total expenditures was 14 percent and the share of consumption expenditures was 16 percent. These shares translate 3 The Panel noted that the current measure of resources, compared to the official poverty thresholds is outdated and not consistent with the threshold measure. The measure of resources used for official poverty measurement is defined as current before-tax money income. The official measure is based on before-tax income because when the measure was first developed for poverty measurement, few families at the lower end of the distribution paid taxes. Now many of these families qualify for the earned income tax credit that did not exist when the measure was first developed. Since the Panel’s report, research has been conducted on the experimental measures that they recommended. Much of this work has been conducted at the Bureau of the Census and Bureau of Labor Statistics (e.g., Garner, 2005; Garner et al., 1998; Johnson et al., 1997; Short, 2001, 2005; Short and Garner, 2004; Short et al., 1999). The current research represents a culmination of this previous work, taking into account the concerns of the research and policy communities regarding the desirable properties of a poverty measure (Iceland, 2005). Properties deemed desirable by the panel include: consistency in construction, statistical defensibility, understandability, broad acceptance by the public and operational feasibility (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 4). The primary aim of this research is to present a poverty measure that is based on the NAS recommendations with these desirable properties. Although the Panel produced thresholds and resource measures, they emphasized that their purpose was to propose a procedure that could be used to produce a poverty measure that is more appropriate for current society. The procedure calculates a poverty threshold that is, by design, updated on a continuous basis and reflects changes in levels of basic needs over time. The official measure, in contrast, is updated using changes in overall prices for an average consumer (using the Consumer Price Index). The NAS proposed measure of family resources reflects the effect of taxes and transfers and takes account of necessary work expenses such as child care and commuting to work. The official measure does not take these into account. The poverty measures presented in this study are based on the recommendations of the Panel, with one deviation, the introduction of a resource measure based on expenditures, in this case, out-of-pocket spending. The NAS Panel discussed resources as consumption or expenditures but their focus was a consumption resource measure (Citro and Michael, 1995, pp. 210-214). Yet, the Panel described a poverty threshold based on spending needs -- into multipliers of about nine, seven, and six. Applying these multipliers to the annual value of the Food Plan ($4893.20) resulted in thresholds of $44,039 using before tax money income, $34,252 using total expenditures, and $29,359 using consumption expenditures. The official poverty threshold for a two-adult two-child family ($18,660) in 2003 is about 60 percent of the least generous of these thresholds. 4 median expenditures on food, clothing, and shelter increased by a modest additional amount to allow for other necessities, without regard to when these items are actually "consumed." For the thresholds, spending needs are defined in terms of out-of-pocket expenditures 2 using U.S. Consumer Expenditures Interview Survey (CE) data. The values of most in-kind transfers (e.g., housing subsidies, energy assistance) are not included in this measure. The one exception is food stamps. Food expenditures made with food stamps cannot be separated from other food spending in the CE. Out-of-pocket spending underlies the official thresholds as well; the multiplier used to create the official thresholds is based on food spending out after-tax money income. Out-of-pocket expenditures used to derive the thresholds for this study differ from the expenditures regularly published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) in that additional expenditures are counted, such as payments to reduce one’s mortgage principal (for details, see Rogers and Gray, 1994). Earlier studies conducted by the current authors used the BLS publication definition of expenditures, following the lead of the Panel. More recent studies (Garner, 2005; Short, 2005) have compared income-based resources to expenditure outlays-based thresholds. The first resource measure presented is after-tax money income plus near-cash benefits that are available to meet spending needs. Resources are defined as income net of necessary expenses (e.g., taxes and work-related expenses) and compared to the spending-based thresholds. The resource measure is based on an “inflows” concept and reflects money coming into the household that is available to meet one’s basis needs. The second resource measure is out-of-pocket expenditures for consumption with adjustments for other spending including allocations to savings and subtractions for necessary expenses and other legal obligations. Both resource measures are consistent with the spending-based threshold presented in this study in that both represent resources that people have available to meet basic spending needs. Other researchers have used various definitions of expenditures to define resources for poverty measurement for the U.S. For example, Federman et al. (1996) first used BLS publication-defined expenditures, Garner and Short (2004) used BLS defined out-of-pocket spending (as well as a consumption-based measure), and Bavier (2005) used BLS defined out-of-pocket spending but subtracted necessary expenses. In other studies of 5 poverty measurement (e.g., Charles et al., 2006; Cutler and Katz, 1991; Fisher et al., 2006; Meyer and Sullivan, 2003; and Slesnick, 1993) consumption (based on consumption expenditures) was the preferred resource measure. The expenditure-based measure used in this study differs from these other measures in the concept used to guide its construction. This measure is spending-based and thereby represents resources available or obligated by the household. This spending could be or is being used to support basic needs. Spending "outflows" can be supported from current income, savings, or borrowing. An expenditure measure reflects, as does an income measure, one's ability to garner resources to actualize consumption for a given period of time, regardless of when the goods are actually used up. A challenge in producing an expenditures-based resource measure is to include all of the expenditures made by the household for consumption and for other purposes. For poverty measurement, an expenditures-based measure can provide useful information to policy makers as they try to understand the spending patterns and needs of consumers relative to their incomes. The expenditure-based measure used in this study is new, and has not been used, to our knowledge, in studies of U.S. poverty. The paper begins with a review of the current official measure of poverty followed by a description of the thresholds and the elements that make up the resource side of the experimental poverty measure. Thresholds and resources are consistent in concept and in measurement method. The technical and conceptual issues that underlie the NAS-based approach to poverty measure construction are highlighted. The NAS-based thresholds are compared to the current official thresholds and examined with regard to underlying concepts and movements. Poverty rates are produced that compare the measure presented here with the current official measure. Poverty rates for 2001-2003 are presented using the official poverty and experimental poverty measures. Poverty rates over time are presented for the total population and for specific subgroups of the population that have been most susceptible to hardship historically. The paper shows that resulting poverty rates are higher with a spending-based resource measure as compared to an income resource measure. II. The Current Official Poverty Measure The current official measure was developed in the early 1960s as an indicator of the number of people with inadequate income to cover the costs of a minimum food diet and to allow for other needed expenses (see Orshansky 2 Throughout the remainder of this study, spending and expenditures are used interchangeably. 6 1965; Citro and Michael 1995). The official thresholds are based on the share of food spending in after-tax money income (one-third for families of three or more; other shares were used for smaller families) using data from the 1955 Household Food Consumption Survey, and a food adequacy standard based on the same survey, The food adequacy standard selected was the USDA economy food plan, issued by the Department for “temporary or emergency use when funds are low” (Orshansky 1965, p. 20). The food plan did not allow for meals eaten out or other food eaten away from home. Thus, if family members ate at school or on the job, those meals were to be prepared at home. Also for this standard it was assumed that “the homemaker is a good manager and has the time and skill to shop wisely, she must prepare nutritious, palatable meals on a budget” for herself and her family (Orshansky 1965, p. 24). Since the first official thresholds were released, thresholds have been updated by changes in prices, holding the multiplier constant at three and the food adequacy standard constant as the economy food plan, both based on the 1955 Food Survey data. In 1969, the Bureau of the Budget gave “official” status to the following change in the poverty thresholds: to use the overall Consumer Price Index (CPI) to update the thresholds for price changes instead of the Economy Food Plan that had been used earlier. Office of Management and Budget Policy Directive No. 14 (OMB, 1978) specifically states that, “The official poverty thresholds do not vary geographically, but they are updated for inflation using [the] Consumer Price Index (CPI-U).” The CPI-U represents the change in prices of a fixed market basket of goods and services, with relative prices changing while utility remains constant.3 The updating mechanism for the official poverty measure is based on the relative change in prices of goods and services purchased by an average consumer unit (using plutocratic, not democratic, weights 4 ). The income measure for official poverty measurement is before-tax money income. This measure includes the following sources of income: earnings, unemployment compensation, workers’ compensation, Social Security, Supplemental Security Income, public assistance, veterans’ payments, survivor benefits, pension or retirement income, interest, dividends, rents, royalties, income from estates, trusts, educational assistance, alimony, child 3 The CPI market basket changes on a periodic basis. In addition to this regular change in the market basket, other changes have been made in the production of the index over the years (see the BLS web site for references). 4 Plutocratic weights are based on the value of goods and services across all consumer units for each commodity represented in the index. For example, the weight for food is total spending on food for all consumer units divided by the value of all goods and services for all consumer units. These weights are then combined with prices to produce the index. Democratic weights reflect the distribution of consumer units in the population. For example, consumer unit specific price indexes would be created based on the value of goods and services of each consumer unit and the prices that the consumer unit faces. To obtain an overall index for the population, the consumer unit 7 support, assistance from outside the household, and other miscellaneous sources. Non-cash benefits (such as food stamps and housing subsidies) do not count, nor do capital gains or losses. If a person lives with family members, their incomes are added together and compared to thresholds that reflect their family size and composition. III. Concepts, Methods, and Data A. Poverty Thresholds Poverty is most often defined in terms of one’s ability to meet his/her basic or minimum needs for survival or participation in society. In the U.S., we have most often been concerned with the costs, at least officially, of some minimum or basic bundle of goods and services that can be used to meet one’s needs, and the income or resources available to meet those needs. A poverty threshold based on “costs,” such as the current official measure, is expressed in terms of the dollar spending necessary to pay for a basic bundle of goods and services. For a spendingbased threshold, expenditures would most appropriately be used to derive the thresholds. For this study, expenditures for a selected set of goods and services are used to construct a spending-based poverty threshold. Others have constructed spending-based thresholds or standards using alternative approaches. As noted previously, the official measure is based on food adequacy and the expenditures necessary to pay for adequate food and to meet other spending needs. Other researchers have constructed spending-based thresholds by building basic needs budgets, specifying adequacy standards for each of the major groups of goods and services that families consume and adding an appropriate amount for direct taxes (for example, see Renwick and Bergman 1993; Renwick, 1998). Spending-based self-sufficiency standards have been constructed by building basic family budgets using local prices and expenditures, and expert judgment (for example, see Bernstein et al., 2000; Pearce, 2005a and 2005b). Personal assessments of what is needed financially to provide for one’s minimum level of living too have been used to produce thresholds based on minimum spending needs. Minimum spending questions are used for the assessments and thus the thresholds are often referred to as minimum spending question (MSQ) thresholds. (see Garner and Short, 2003 and 2004; Morissette and Poulin , 1991). One of the advantages of defining the poverty thresholds in the way proposed in this study, following the NAS panel’s basic recommendations, is that we know exactly how the thresholds are constructed and how each of the elements in the thresholds are measured. While we can surmise what is contained in the current official specific price indexes would be averaged using demographic population weights to reflect the value of goods and 8 thresholds, there remains controversy about the exact measurement process used by Orshansky in the construction of those thresholds (for example, Betson, 2000 and Bavier, 2001). Another important advantage of this procedure is that the thresholds are automatically updated over time by actual spending on these basic selected items. Setting the threshold has several steps. These include selecting a reference family, choosing an appropriate equivalence scale, and identifying the goods and services included in the thresholds. The reference family used here has two adults and two children. According to the Panel, the criteria used to select the reference family type was that family would “fall near the center of the family size distribution rather than at one of the extremes…also, it is preferable for the reference family to be one that accounts for a relatively large proportion of the population because its spending patterns observed in a sample survey will be the basis for the poverty threshold…” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 101). Short and Garner (2002) found that about 9 percent of all families were two-adult/two-child families. Of families with children, those with two adults and two children were the largest group. Since children make up a large portion of the poverty population it is reasonable that the reference family represent spending patterns for that group. Once the reference family is chosen, median expenditures for a select group of goods and services are calculated. This group of commodities includes food, clothing, shelter (including utilities), and a small additional amount to allow for other needs (e.g., household supplies, personal care, and non-work-related transportation). Also, medical needs are accounted for by including medical out-of-pocket expenses in the poverty thresholds. Thus, medical care is treated as a basic need, along with food, clothing, shelter, and utilities.5 For this study, the threshold based on an out-of-pocket definition of expenditures includes food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care, and is referred to as the “experimental” threshold. The experimental threshold includes the following: • Out-of-pocket spending on: Food Clothing Utilities (includes telephone) Medical care services and price experience of all consumer units. 9 For renters, shelter expenditures For homeowners, non-vacation shelter expenditures that include: Mortgage interest payments Repayments of mortgage principal Prepayment penalties Property taxes Maintenance, repairs, insurance and other related expenditures. Percentile values for expenditures, based on percentages of the median, drive the poverty thresholds. The use of the percentage links updates in the threshold to changes in expenditures at the median. The percentages selected correspond to the reference family’s expenditures between the 30th and 35th percentiles of the distribution of the sum of food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care expenditures. Our applications have used the midpoint of the recommended range to set the value of the thresholds. Once the percentage of median expenditures on a basic bundle had been estimated, multipliers are applied to the basic bundle to add a small additional amount to allow for other needs. A range of multipliers represents the basic bundle plus personal care, one-half transportation, education, and reading materials costs. 6 Finally, an equivalence scale is applied to the reference family threshold to obtain thresholds for families of other sizes and composition. We use a three-parameter scale that allowed for a different adjustment for single parents (Betson, 1996). The three-parameter scale had been used in several BLS and Census Bureau studies (Johnson et al., 1995; Short et al., 1999; Short 2001). The three-parameter scale is shown below. One and two adults: scale = ( adults )0.7 (1a) 5 This represents a deviation from the original recommendations of the NAS panel that medical out-of-pocket expenses be subtracted from income as a necessary expense. For earlier research with medical care included in the thresholds, see: Banthin, et al. (2001), Bavier (2001), Short (2001), Short and Garner (2002). 6 Transportation expenditures were defined by the Panel to include vehicle finance charges, expenses for gasoline and motor oil, maintenance and repairs, vehicle insurance, public transportation (including air fares), and vehicle rentals, licenses and other charges. In addition, transportation included the total purchase price (minus the trade-in value) on new and used vehicles. Personal care includes products for hair, oral hygiene, and shaving, cosmetics and bath products, electric personal care appliances, other personal care products, and personal care services. Education includes tuition, fees, textbooks, supplies and equipment for public and private nursery schools, elementary, and high schools, colleges, and universities, and others schools. 10 Single parents: scale = ( adults + 0.8* firstchild + 0.5* otherchildren ) All other families: scale = ( adults + 0.5* children ) 0.7 0.7 . (1b) (1c) The economy of scales factor was set at 0.70; the Panel recommended a range of 0.65 to 0.75. The general formula for deriving the reference family threshold, using food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care is shown in the equation below. (1 − smedical ) (1.15* PL * M ) + (1.25* PH * M ) )+ 2 ( smedical ) (2) ( PL * M ) + ( PH * M ) ) 2 where s medical = medical share of threshold value PL = lower percentage of median costs PH = higher percentage of median costs M = median expenditures for reference family. The multipliers of 1.15 and 1.25 are applied to the non-medical part of the threshold, (1-smedical), since they are based on the relationship between the sum of food, clothing, shelter, and utilities expenditures and expenditure for smaller and larger other bundles of needed goods and services as noted in the 1995 report. The three-parameter equivalence scale is also only applied to the non-medical part of the threshold. This is because the medical care needs of children are not expected to be less than those of adults and because there are few inherent scale economies in medical care consumption with increasing family size. Medical care expenditure risk indexes were created that account for variations in family expenditures as related to family size, and the age, health status, and health insurance coverage of family members. 7 The medical Reading materials includes subscriptions for newspapers, magazines, and books through book clubs, purchase of single copy newspapers, and magazines, newsletters, books, encyclopedias, and other reference books. 7 One of the goals of the current research was to use the CE Interview Survey for the production of the thresholds without auxiliary data from another survey. Since the CE does not include information on the health status of members, only the remaining factors were used in the production of the CE-based medical risk indexes. An additional challenge in using the CE to produce the medical indexes is that the CE does not collect health insurance information for each member; data are collected on whether the consumer unit as a whole has various private health 11 risk indexes are calculated as the ratio of median medical out-of-pocket expenditures for different groups, varied by the factors just noted, compared to the median expenditures of the reference family. Only the medical part of the threshold is adjusted by the medical risk index. This procedure to calculate thresholds repeated each year employs a quasi-relative approach for annually updating the thresholds. This approach allows for “…changes in real consumption but in a conservative manner” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 154). Such thresholds are more reflective of current needs than the official threshold. B. Income-Based Resources The next step in constructing a poverty measure is to calculate the resources that families have to meet the needs specified in the thresholds. The resource measure presented here represents an attempt to construct a poverty measure that is internally consistent. Cash and near-cash income, adjusted for required spending (e.g., income taxes paid) that reduces a family’s income to meet its basic spending needs, is compared to a spending-based threshold. The main theme in this section is that, while the selection of a poverty threshold is a policy choice, once that selection is made, the measure of resources employed for comparison must be consistent. “It is important that family resources are defined consistently with the threshold concept in any poverty measure. The current [official] measure violates this principle, as has some recent work to investigate alternatives.” (Citro and Michael, 1995, p. 9). The current official definition of poverty finds a family to be poor if total family pre-tax money income is below that family’s poverty threshold, defined to be a particular dollar amount depending upon family size and composition. This measure was based on the availability of data in the 1960s, so that, while the thresholds were conceptually based on after tax income, for example, no estimates of after tax income were available at that time. Income-based resources in this paper are the sum of money income from all sources plus the value of nearmoney benefits that help the family meet spending needs, less necessary expenses that must be paid. This alternative concept of family income is referred to as “discretionary income” -- income that can be used to meet a family’s basic needs (food, clothing, shelter, utilities, medical care plus a little bit more) after subtracting necessary expenses such as taxes and work-related expenses. Constructing an experimental measure of poverty starts with gross money income and adds values for nearcash transfers from federal programs aimed at helping poor families meet their basic spending needs. Experimental insurance policies. However, data are collected concerning the total number of people who are covered by Medicaid 12 poverty thresholds as noted above include all expenditures for food, including purchases with food stamps. Since the thresholds include all food spending, it is appropriate to include food stamps in a measure of resources. Food stamps are the only near-cash benefit that is added to income to meet spending needs in this measure because no other near-cash benefits are included in the spending threshold. Other important benefits are often included as near cash income such as housing subsidies and school lunch subsidies. 8 As mentioned earlier, spending on food in the thresholds only includes the out-of-pocket spending for school lunch or breakfast, not the value of food consumed. The CE thresholds do not include subsidies for school lunch by children at school. For this reason we do not add the value of subsidies to school lunches here. The CE thresholds also do not include subsidies for housing 9 and thus are not included in resources. Federal housing assistance consists of a number of programs administered primarily by the Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD). The programs generally reduce tenants’ rent payments to a fixed percentage of their income after certain deductions, currently 30 percent. If the threshold is based on reported out-of-pocket spending then the housing subsidy is not added to income since it does not help the family meet their spending requirement. After calculating the income component of the resource measure, the next step is to subtract expenses that must be paid before determining how much money is available to purchase basic necessities. Families must first pay taxes and expenses required to work. 10 Taxes are subtracted from income since taxes must be paid and are not available to meet basic needs. Federal and state income taxes and all payroll taxes paid are accounted for in this resource definition (O’Hara, 2004). Further, earning a wage may entail incurring expenses, such as travel to work and purchase of uniforms or tools as well as care provided for children while parents are at work. These expenses are viewed as necessary and are paid by families before expenditures are made on goods and services (see Short 2004 for a detailed examination). The remaining monies represent the ability of the family to purchase, on an annual basis, what they need. While borrowing and dis-saving are options that may be used to meet spending needs in the short run, this and Medicare. See, for example, the Census Bureau’s alternative income definitions (Census 2006). 9 Earlier studies included imputed values for housing subsidies in the thresholds (Garner and Rozaklis, 1999 and 2001). 10 Child support monies that are paid out should be deducted from income since they are included as income by the receiving family. In Census Bureau income statistics using the CPS this is not done because data regarding the amount of child support paid by one household to another is not collected, while the amount received by another household is collected and added into income. The consequence of this is that child support transfers are doubly 8 13 measure suggests an amount that is required over the year to get along. Shortfalls in available resources on an annual basis suggest circumstances that are untenable in the longer term. The income measure used in this study includes realized capital gains. This is done as part of the tax model calculations. The inclusion of realized capital gains in income is inconsistent with the basic income concept recommended by the Canberra Group (2001) and International Labour Organization (ILO). However, the ILO reports that the inclusion of realized capital gains is consistent with the Haig-Simons approach. For the Haig-Simons approach, income is defined as the sum of consumption expenditure and change in net worth in a period (see Simons, 1938, in Atkinson and Stiglitz, 1980). 11 The ILO recommended that income not include reductions in net worth, “as a rule”, in income (p. 11) but noted that when “receipts from the sale of assets, withdrawals from savings and loans obtained … are important for the analysis of the financing of consumption expenditure, they should, as much as possible, be collected along with the income receipts” (pp. 11, 22). 12 Finally, the value of the flow of services of owned homes is not included in income resources. Garner (2005) explains that for a spending-based threshold, a consistent treatment of homeownership in the resource measure would not include values for net implicit rents from owner-occupied housing. Net worth, considered by some in poverty measurement (Wolfe, 1990; Short and Ruggles, forthcoming), is also not included in the incomebased resource measure. It is important to note that expenditure-based resources may include spending from both income and assets. C. Expenditure-Based Resources The expenditure measure used to define resources represents what is spent and what could be spent to meet basic needs as defined by the threshold. The expenditure measure of resources reflects spending for consumption goods and services financed out of current income, assets, or borrowing; interest associated with non-secured counted in household income and official poverty statistics. These expenses and reported receipts were about $22 billion in 2001. 11 As noted in the ILO report, “This [Haig-Simons] approach does not impose any requirement of regular recurrence nor requires the notion of not reducing net worth. No restriction to only those receipts available for current consumption expenditure is made. The implication is that income should include all receipts, recurrent or otherwise, regular or irregular and even those resulting in a reduction of net worth” (ILO, 2003, p. 9). 12 See Citro and Michael (1995, pp. 214-215) and Short and Ruggles (forthcoming) regarding the use of net worth and poverty measure. 14 borrowing and other necessary expenses are subtracted. Allocations to savings and financial accounts and expenditures for capital improvements to property that could be used instead for consumption are also added to expenditures. Compulsory transfers (e.g., child support and alimony) are subtracted from expenditures as spending for these cannot be used to meet the threshold spending needs of the household. Also, as is done for the income resource measure, work-related expenses, including those for child care, are subtracted. Additional subtractions include interest paid on credit cards and related debt used to support the purchase of consumption goods and services, child support and alimony payments, and other legal obligations. Three measures of expenditures are presented in order that the impact of each set of subtractions and additions can be assessed. The first measure is out-of-pocket expenditures as defined by the BLS plus allocations to financial accounts, the second subtracts from this amount the same necessary expenses as is done for the income resource measure, the third subtracts from this second measure interest on home equity loans and lines of credit, vehicle finance charges, interest on other consumer credit, child support and alimony. D. Data This paper uses several surveys to construct alternative poverty measures. First, the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CE) quarterly interview data, for 1998 quarter two through 2003 quarter one, are used to construct alternative poverty thresholds following the procedure recommended by the NAS panel. 13 CE Interview data are made available on a quarterly cycle. Data collected in an interview refer to expenditures made during the three months prior to the interview month. It is assumed that data from each reference quarter is independent of the data from other quarters, just as it is assumed for CE publications. Thus, although annual thresholds are produced, these are based on quarterly reports of expenditures. Three years of quarterly data are used to produce each threshold. For example, for the 2003 threshold, 36 months of data from 2000 second quarter through 2003 first quarter are used. Data from earlier years in the three-year cycle are updated to the threshold year using the annual All Items 13 When research began to produce the thresholds used in this study, it was expected that the Census Bureau would be publishing the thresholds. Given the CE data release dates and Census Bureau publication dates, the data chosen to produce the thresholds are from the three most recent years minus one. However, shortly before the thresholds were completed, it was determined that the NAS-based thresholds would not be published; thus the three most recent years of data could have been used as in the earlier BLS and Census Bureau studies previous cited. If the earlier approach has been used, the 2003 threshold would have been based on data from 2001quarter 2 through 2004 quarter 1 and the thresholds would have been more reflective of more recent spending patterns. The experimental 15 Consumer Price Index, U.S. City Average (CPI-U). 14 Thresholds are produced for the reference family. The reference family includes two related adults and two children, also related to the adults. To measure family income or, as more broadly defined, family income-based resources, the analysis uses the Current Population Survey Annual Social and Economic Supplement (CPS ASEC) for the income years 2001 to 2003. Payroll taxes, federal and state income taxes, and earned income tax credits (EIC) are based on a model developed for the CPS ASEC. All but the EIC are also subtracted from income; EIC amounts are added. Information from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP) 2001 panel is used to value work and child care expenses, both are subtracted from income, in the experimental measure. Income-based resource measures are produced for families and unrelated individuals. The calculation of the income-based resources starts with current money income as defined and measured in the CPS ASEC. Current money income is used to calculate official poverty statistics and includes cash income received on a regular basis, such as income from earnings, any cash transfers, and property income. It includes money income received in the previous calendar year by the family residing together as of February, March, or April (the interview date) of the current year. Before-tax income, regularly received, does not include net realized capital gains, gifts, lump sum inheritances, or insurance payments. The CPS collects no information on taxes paid, so a tax model is required. As part of the tax calculator, net realized capital gains are simulated and added to income in the computation of adjusted gross income (AGI). It should be noted, this is done only for tax filers because non-filers have no such income by definition. Also, net simulated realized capital gains are added to income even though they are not regularly received. For work-related expenses (other than child care) a fixed amount per week is used for all workers. The weekly amount is estimated to be 85 percent of median work expenses reported in the SIPP. Reported mileage commuted to work is used with the IRS mileage allowance for taxes to compute these work expenses. Total expenses were obtained by multiplying this fixed amount by the number of weeks respondents reported working in the year. Accounting for child care expenses while parents worked in the CPS also uses estimated weekly median expenses as reported in the SIPP. Only those families who indicated that someone paid for child care while they threshold using the most recent three years of data is $21,635. This is somewhat lower than the threshold for 2003 used in this study ($23,170). 14 In another exercise, medians were produced based on an updating of the expenditures of threshold components using their corresponding CPI-Us; there was essentially no difference in the medians in threshold year dollars with this approach or when the overall CPI-U was used for the sum of expenditures. 16 worked were assigned these amounts. For these families weekly amounts were multiplied by number of weeks worked by the “secondary” worker, or the worker with the lowest earnings. For the expenditure-based resource measures, the analysis uses quarterly CE Interview data collected in 2001quarter two through 2004 quarter one. Expenditures for consumer units, as opposed to families, are collected and thus are used for the analysis. However, experimental poverty rates are produced for people rather than consumer units. Expenditures for the resource measure are quarterly; thus expenditure-based resources are compared to the expenditure thresholds divided by four. For the CE Interview, collected expenditures refer to those made in the three months prior to the interview month. This means, for example, that quarterly expenditures collected during the 2001 quarter two through 2002 quarter one time period are compared to the 2001 threshold divided by four. 15,16 The study time period begins with 2001 quarter two since several variables of interest (e.g., cash contributions and occupational expenses) are asked in each quarter of the Interview beginning with this quarter. Before this time, questions regarding these variables were asked only once, in the fifth interview. The last year of data, 2003, corresponds to the most recently produced experimental thresholds. Poverty rates using three different expenditure-resource measures are compared to the experimental thresholds. The first is used to provide a baseline for comparison to the other two that result from additions and subtractions to expenditures. The base line measure is similar to that used by Garner and Short (2004) in their comparison of expenditure outlays to official poverty and minimum spending and income thresholds, although expenditures collected only in the fifth interview were not included in their measure of outlays. 17 The second and third expenditure-resource measures are attempts to produce measures that are more consistent with the threshold. For these two measures, necessary expenditures that cannot be used to meet the threshold spending needs are subtracted. For the second expenditure-based resource measure, payroll taxes, and work-related and child care expenses are deducted from expenditure outlays. These are the same subtractions as those made for the income-resource measure with the exception of income taxes. Income taxes are not included in 15 The expenditure months in scope for each threshold year could have been used. However, since the thresholds are estimated using data collected in the first quarter of the following year, the same time reference period is used for calculating poverty rates. 16 In contrast, Bavier (2005) used expenditure outlays adjusted for NAS necessary expenses with data for consumer units for which four quarters of data were available and thereby produced annual poverty rates. 17 Garner and Short (2004) restricted expenditure outlays to those collected in Interview quarters from October 1995 through January1996. Expenditures not included were those for finance charges (excluding those on mortgages and financed vehicles), occupational expenses, and cash contributions to organizations and non-CU members. This was 17 the CE definition of outlays and thus did not need to be deducted. The third measure additionally subtracts child support and alimony payments, vehicle finance charges, other finance charges (excluding those for mortgages and vehicles), and interest on home equity loans and lines of credit. All of these represent legal obligations of the consumer unit and therefore expenditures for these cannot be diverted to meet the basic threshold needs of the consumer unit. Added to expenditure resources are changes in financial accounts (i.e., positive changes to savings accounts, checking accounts, and U.S. savings bonds), and expenditures for capital improvements to property (i.e., owned home, vacation home, and other property). For this study, it is assumed that increases in saving accounts, checking accounts, and the purchase of U.S. savings bonds represent allocations that the consumer unit made rather than returns to investments and thus could have been used for the purchase of goods and services instead. Given the time period, interest rates for these financial accounts were low so we think that the assumption is reasonable. All the additions and subtractions from expenditure outlays are based on reports from the CE Interview except for work related expenses. Work-related expenses are subtracted for each working adult in the consumer unit. 18 Work-related expenses are determined by multiplying the number of weeks worked, as reported in the CE, by the same fixed amount as was done for the income-based resource measure. 19 Not all CE child care expenditures are subtracted from outlays to obtain the third expenditure-resource measure. Child care expenditures are only subtracted for a consumer unit with a dependent child who is less than 13 years of age (based on the U.S. tax code of child dependency for child care) and in which there are two or more working adults or a single parent consumer unit in which the parent is working. These values were capped at the level allowed for dependent care credit in the federal tax code. IV. Results The thresholds for the three years are presented along with poverty rates using income- and expenditure outlays-based measures. The thresholds are first examined in relationship to the movement of other economic statistical series. This is followed by a detailed examination of how the experimental threshold differs from the official threshold with particular reference to the CPI that is used to adjust the official poverty thresholds. Poverty done in order that all consumer units would have the opportunity to have the same expenditures as every other consumer unit each quarter. 18 Bavier (2005), when using expenditure outlays to compare to NAS-based thresholds, subtracted work related expenses for the reference person or spouse only, not all working adults. 19 The amount deducted per week per working adult in 2001 was $17.94 and $18.96 for 2002 and 2003. 18 rates are presented for the total population and selected population subgroups using the income-based resource measure and the three expenditure-based measures. A. Thresholds The experimental thresholds and the official poverty line for a family with two adults and two children are presented in Table 1 and Chart 1. The experimental thresholds increase over the 2001 to 2003 period, just as the official threshold increases. However, the rate of increase for the experimental thresholds is greater. The official threshold in 2001 is $17,960 and in 2003 it is $18,660, a 3.9 percent increase. In contrast, the experimental threshold for 2001 is $21,177 and $23,170 by 2003, a 9.4 percent increase. The experimental poverty threshold increased almost three times as fast as the official poverty threshold. The official poverty line is about 85 percent of the experimental threshold in 2001 but only 81 percent in 2003. 20 Table 2 compares the official and experimental poverty thresholds to published CPS average household before-tax money income and published CE average consumer unit total expenditures 21 (available from the BLS, 2006 and Census, 2006, web sites) to determine if movements in the poverty thresholds reflect general movements in the economy. Before-tax money income for all households increased by only 1.5 percent from 2001 to 2003; total expenditures increased by 3.3 percent for all consumer units. These results indicate that income and expenditures were not increasing as fast as the poverty thresholds but total expenditures were moving at about the same rate as the official measure. When comparing the experimental with the official thresholds, it is important to understand the differences in the two thresholds. The official threshold is based on the assumption that one-third of all spending is for food. As noted in the introduction, the official threshold is based on the cost of a minimum diet (defined in 1955) multiplied by the food share as a percentage of after-tax money using 1955 Household Food Consumption Survey data. The food share was based on the spending and income of all families with three or more people. With the experimental threshold there is no explicit assumption regarding shares of spending, only that the threshold accounts 20 To compare the relative differences in spending needs determined by the experimental threshold and other spending-based thresholds, thresholds for 1995 from Garner (2005) are considered. The 1995 experimental threshold is about 97 percent of the minimum spending threshold (MSQ) threshold presented by Garner and Short (2004) for that same year. It is 95 percent of the value of the budget-based threshold constructed by Renwick (1998) for a husband-wife family with two children and one working parent, and 78 percent of the Renwick threshold for this family but with both parents working. 19 for food, clothing, 22 shelter, utilities, medical care, and other basic goods and services. The experimental thresholds are produced each year using the most recent three years (minus one year) of spending of families composed of two adults and two children. The official poverty threshold is updated each year to current dollars using the CPI. 23 Changes in the official poverty threshold each year are based on movements in the CPI, while changes in the experimental threshold are based on movements in consumer spending. The consumer price index is based on price changes and expenditure weights for aggregation. To better understand how the official and experimental thresholds compare, expenditure shares underlying the CPI and expenditure thresholds are presented for 2001-2003. Indexes for all items and for food, clothing, shelter, utilities and medical care are presented to show how the overall CPI moves relative to the CPI of selected subcomponents. Implicit shares in the experimental threshold are also presented to highlight differences between the official poverty measure and the experimental threshold, and to provide insight regarding why the official and experimental thresholds move differently. Shares of expenditures implicit in the experimental thresholds for the reference family are presented in Table 3, and are based on the underlying distribution of expenditures used to derive the thresholds. The thresholds are based on percentages of the median, 78 and 83 percent, corresponding to the 30-35th percentiles of the distribution based on the sum of expenditures for the threshold bundle. The expenditure shares implicit in the thresholds are based on shares in this lower part of the expenditure distribution. Tables 4a and 4b include shares based on aggregated annual expenditure estimates for the CPI. The shares in Table 4a are based on the 1998 CPI market basket structure (see Greenlees and Mason, 1996) while Table 4b is based on the definition of expenditures used for the experimental threshold. The shares in both Table 4a and 4b are derived from the same underlying 21 Published CE expenditure data are based on integrations of expenditures collected using the Diary and Interview instruments. 22 The NAS Panel referred to Apparel as Clothing in the 1995 report. In this study, we do this as well. Thus, Apparel in the CPI-U is referred to as Clothing. 23 Over the 1993-2003 period of this study, the Consumer Price Index for All Urban Consumers (CPI-U) was used to adjust the official poverty thresholds from year to year. The CPI-U is based on the spending and prices faced by consumers living in metropolitan statistical areas (MSA’s) and urban places of 2,500 inhabitants or more. Non-farm consumers living in rural areas within MSA’s are also included. In contrast, the experimental thresholds are based on the spending and prices faced by consumers living in both urban and rural areas. The CPI-U measures the average change in the prices paid by urban consumer for a fixed market basket of goods and services. As noted in the BLS Handbook of Methods (USDL, 1997, p. 170), “The CPI uses a fixed market basket to hold the base-period living standard constant. The CPI equals the ratio of the cost of the base-period basket at this month’s prices to the actual cost of the base-period basket in the base period. It is an index of price change only and does not reflect changes in buying patterns that consumers probably would make to adjust to relative price changes.” The weight of an item in the CPI is derived from expenditures from the CE. These are known as quantity weights. These weights are used along with the prices for goods and services to calculate the index. 20 data. 24 There are some differences between the CPI categories of expenditures and the category definitions used for the experimental poverty thresholds. For example, the CPI includes the value of owner-occupied shelter services (rental equivalence) while the experimental threshold shelter is based on out-of-pocket expenditures. The experimental threshold definition structure includes telephone services with other utilities (Table 4b); these are not included in utilities in the CPI structure and therefore are not included in Table 4a. Medical care in the CPI structure includes adult day care while this is not included in medical care in the experimental threshold definition structure. 25 The results presented in Table 3 reveal that food accounted for less than a third (28.0 percent) of the experimental threshold in 2001 followed by shelter at 30.1 percent. By 2003 this relationship had reversed with shelter accounting for 30.5 percent of the experimental threshold and food for 26.7 percent of the total. Utilities come in third (not counting “other”) with between 13 and 14 percent of the total, followed by medical care and clothing. Expenditures for other basic goods and services account for about 15.6 percent of the experimental threshold from 2001 to 2003. 24 Only the 1999-2003 data are official production data used for the CPI-U. Data for the earlier years were not specifically used for the production of the official CPI-U but are used in this study to show the shares for the commodity groups defined using the CPI-U market structure and the experimental threshold structure. The shares are based on aggregated CE data and are presented for each elementary item using the 1998 CPI market basket structure (there are 211 elementary items). The data file used to create the shares contained aggregate annual expenditure estimates for the CPI-U population for each year 1993-2004 (the last year of data are not used in this study). The 1999 to 2004 data are official production data. That is, the composite estimated and raked annual expenditure data are those that were used to construct the biennial aggregation weights for the CPI-U periods 19992000, 2001-2002, and 2003-2004. Prior to 1999, the BLS did not composite estimate and rake expenditure data annually. According to Cage (2006), “only the 1993-1995 data were used as an official CPI-U expenditure reference period, and back then the data were aggregated together (over the three years) prior to composite estimation.” Hence, the 1993 to 1998 data are not composite estimated and raked. Cage notes that this probably does not have significant effect. He did state however that “the 1993 to 1998 data may have slightly higher variance than the 1999 [and] forward data. But then again, the sample size of the CE was increased in 1999 so the difference in variance would be expected.” 25 Details regarding the differences between the CPI-U groupings, using the 1998 market structure, and the experimental threshold groupings are available from the authors. However, some of these differences follow. (1) CPI food includes the value of meals as pay; the experimental threshold measure for food does not. (2) CPI clothing (apparel) includes clothing for men, boys, girls, women, and infants and toddlers, footwear, jewelry and watches while the experimental threshold clothing includes these plus material for making clothes, sewing notions and patterns, shoe repair and other shoe service, coin-operated apparel laundry and dry cleaning, alteration and repair of apparel and accessories, clothing rental, watch and jewelry repair, apparel laundry and dry cleaning not coinoperated, and clothing storage. (3) CPI shelter includes the rent of primary residence including rent as pay, lodging away from home, owners’ equivalent rent of primary residence, and tenants’ and household insurance. The experimental threshold shelter includes mortgage principal and interest of primary residence, prepayment penalties, property taxes of primary residence, shelter rent (not on vacation, away at school, or rent as pay), tenants’ and household insurance, property management for primary residence, maintenance and repairs, and some materials for remodeling. (4) CPI utilities are those for primary and vacation rental and owned properties and include natural gas, electricity, fuel oil, other fuels, and water and other public services (not including septic tank cleaning). The experimental threshold utilities include only the utilities for primary residences and rentals and include those in the 21 In Tables 4a and 4b, shelter accounts for approximately the same share of total CPI expenditures as it does in the experimental thresholds, approximately 30 percent. In contrast, food accounts for about 14.5 percent of total CPI expenditures (Table 4a), almost half the share implicit in the experimental thresholds. The expenditure share for utilities in the CPI is also about a third of the experimental threshold share for utilities. In the CPI expenditures, clothing accounts for about 4.7 percent while medical care accounts for a slightly higher percent of the total at about 5.5 percent (Table 4a). The largest share of expenditures in the CPI (about 40 percent 26 ) is represented by goods and services not represented by the basic needs in the thresholds; food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care. The shares in Table 4b, based on the definitions used for the experimental thresholds, reveal higher shares of expenditures for clothing and utilities than when using the CPI aggregation structure. The results presented in Tables 3, 4a, and 4b reveal how the underlying structure of the CPI, which is used to adjust the official poverty threshold each year, and the experimental thresholds differ. The official poverty threshold is influenced more by goods and services “other” than food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care than is the experimental threshold. Food and shelter account for about 40 percent of CPI expenditures while they account for about 60 percent of expenditures in the experimental threshold. Rates of increase in the CPI and underlying threshold expenditures are presented in Tables 5 and 6. Table 5 includes the CPI for all items and for the items included in the experimental threshold. 27 Table 6 includes the implicit average annual expenditures in the experimental threshold for the reference family. Expenditures are presented in threshold year dollars. The experimental threshold rose faster than the all items CPI from 2001 to 2003 (3.9 percent versus 9.4 percent), and thus rose faster than the official poverty threshold, as noted earlier. Food expenditures increased at about the same rate in the thresholds (4.2 percent) as did the CPI for food (4.0 percent). Implicit clothing expenditures in the thresholds rose by 7.5 percent in the thresholds but the CPI for clothing fell 5.0 percent. Shelter expenditures in the thresholds increased by 11 percent compared to an increase in the shelter CPI of 6.2 percent. Implicit expenditures for utilities also increased at a faster rate in the thresholds than the CPI for CPI with the addition of septic tank cleaning and telephone services. (5) Medical care is defined the same in both with one exception: adult day care is only included in the CPI medical care category. 26 Approximately 17.9 percent of the CPI-U aggregate is for transportation, 6.3 percent for recreation, 5.9 percent for education and communications, 5.0 percent for household operations, and 4.2 percent for other goods and services (authors’ own calculations using aggregates provided by Cage (2006). 27 A CPI for “other” is not presented as there is no CPI for “other” and the authors did not calculate a composite index to represent the other commodity groups. 22 utilities (11.8 percent compared to 2.9 percent). The greatest increase in threshold expenditures from 2001 to 2003 was for medical care, increasing 23.3 percent. The increase for the CPI was only 8.9 percent. The experimental threshold changes each year based on the buying habits and spending of families with two adults and two children whose expenditures are at the lower end of the expenditure distribution (between the 30th and 35th percentiles of the distribution for the sum of food, clothing, shelter, utilities and medical care expenditures). The official poverty threshold changes each year based on the average change in prices paid by urban consumers for a specific market basket of goods and services. The results in Tables 4 through 6 have been used to highlight differences in the two thresholds. The official poverty threshold is adjusted by the CPI each year so movements in the CPI were used to explore differences in the official and experimental thresholds. The experimental threshold increased more rapidly during the 2001-2003 time period than did the official poverty threshold. Even though shelter accounts for about the same share of the CPI-U expenditures and the experimental threshold, shelter expenditures increased at a faster rate in the experimental thresholds. Utilities increased at a much faster rate in the experimental thresholds and represent about three times the expenditures in the CPI. To summarize, these results reveal that the spending for basic needs as represented by the experimental threshold is increasing at a faster rather than the CPI. This is reflected by differences in commodity composition and movements in spending over time. B. Resources Change in poverty thresholds would be expected to change trends in poverty statistics over time. However, these statistics, when measured using income are also affected by changes in income and other tax and transfer policies. Expenditure-based resource measures can also be affected by changes in policies. These changes too may change trends in expenditure-based poverty rates over time. An examination of the elements in the resource measures sheds light on changes in overall resources. Table 7a and Chart 2 include the necessary expenses that are subtracted from both cash income and out-ofpocket expenditures to derive at the resource measures used for experimental poverty measurement for 2001 to 2003. These include payroll taxes, work expenses, and child care expenses. Additional expenses are subtracted from before-tax money income to derive the experimental poverty measure. These include federal and state income taxes. Additions to income include the cash value of food stamps, net realized capital gains, and the earned income tax 23 credit (see Short 2005). The value of food stamps is implicitly included in expenditures since these are used for spending. Payroll taxes increase in the CPS and CE samples from 2001 to 2003. Since, over time we are subtracting larger and larger amounts for payroll taxes, the experimental measures are expected to result in higher poverty rates over time. Other expenses do not change as much and are thus not expected to affect trends in poverty. Average annual payroll taxes are slightly higher in the CPS than in the CE, both around $3,000 by 2003. Work expenses are marginally lower in the CPS than CE (both about $1,000). This might be expected since a consumer unit is defined to be more inclusive than a family in that it may include unrelated individuals. By 2003, average child care expenses are almost indistinguishable for the CPS and CE. The averages presented are computed over all families and consumer units in the study samples and therefore do not represent the averages for only those families and consumer who incurred the expenses. Additions to out-of-pocket expenditures are shown in Table 7b and Chart 3 along with additional subtractions. Positive changes in financial accounts vary from about $700 in 2001 to almost $900 in 2003. Consumers spent an annual average of $765 in 2001 on capital improvements to property; they increased this spending to $1,048 by 2003. The NAS Panel recommended that child support payments be subtracted from an experimental resource measure. Since the CPS does not include data on child support payments, they were not subtracted to derive the income-based resource measure. However, these payments are collected in the CE and thus can be subtracted for the expenditure-based measure. Annualized average child support payments decreased over the 2001 to 2003 period from $195 to $165. Alimony payments are also subtracted as legal obligations; expenditures for payments of alimony cannot be used to meet the basic needs of the consumer unit making those payments. These payments were on average quite low, less than $50. The other subtractions from out-of-pocket expenditures are those associated with the use of credit, other than that for owned real estate property. Since the interest on mortgages for owned home that are financed is included in the spending-based threshold, this interest is included in expenditures, not subtracted from expenditures. Subtractions of expenditures associated with the use of consumer unit include those for vehicle finance charges, finance charges other than those for mortgages and vehicles, and interest on home equity loans and lines of credit. The average total of these charges ranges from $672 in 2003 to $827 in 2002. Clearly credit is important to consumers in financing their levels of living. 24 The result of the additions and subtractions on average annual resources are shown in Table 7c and Chart 4, along with other statistics previously presented including before-tax money income, CE published total expenditures, and the poverty thresholds. The income-based resource measure is $14,926 less than the before-tax money income measure used for official poverty measurement in 2001; this difference increases to $16,430 by 2003. There are only marginal differences between published CE total expenditures and the base expenditures, defined as outlays plus some additions, used for this study. However, once necessary expenses are subtracted from the base expenditures, differences in expenditure resource measures arise. The base expenditure resource measure for 2001 is $39,215 and by 2003 it rises to $41,130. The NAS necessary expense subtractions result in the second expenditure resource measure; the second expenditure-based resource measure is from $3,700 to $4,000 lower than the first measure in 2001 as compared to 2003. The average annual expenditure for the last measure, the one that is most consistent with the spending-based threshold concept, is even lower than the others. In all, subtractions from the base expenditure measure result in reductions in spending available to meet basic needs by about $4,900 in 2003. The income-based resources are leveling out between 2002 and 2003 resulting in less of a difference between that measure and the third and last expenditure-based measure. The difference is about $8,800 in 2001 but $6,400 by 2003. These averages suggest that the income-based measure will result in lower poverty rates than will the expenditure-based measure. C. Experimental Poverty Rates To determine poverty status, total family or consumer unit resources are compared to the spending needs thresholds. If resources are below the amount needed, then all individuals in the family or consumer unit are classified as poor. The official poverty measure shows the percent of people in families with before tax cash income below official poverty thresholds. The experimental measure uses poverty thresholds that provide a more current estimate of the cost of an explicitly defined set of basic goods and reflects out-of-pocket spending needs. Taking account of spending on basic goods, and the additions and subtractions to base resources, provides information about individuals who, while not poor using the official measure, may have difficulty meeting basic needs. Table 8 and Chart 5 show poverty rates for the period of time from 2001 to 2003. The rates shown using income measures are based on annual data while those based on expenditures are based on quarterly data. The figures show that the official poverty rate rose across the period from 2001 to 2000 from 11.7 to 12.5 percent. The 25 experimental poverty measure using income-based resources displays a similar though more pronounced pattern with a rate of increase around 14 percent as compared to 6.8 percent for the official measure. Poverty rates based on expenditure resources also exhibit greater increases than the official measure but not as great as the income-based measure. Differences in trends, between the official and experimental measures, are due to increases in the experimental thresholds as well as increased payroll taxes and work expenses that families and consumer units face. Poverty rates based on income resources are slightly lower than those based on expenditures with no subtractions. Once necessary expenses and other obligations are subtracted from base expenditures, poverty rates are 8 to 9 percentage points higher than the rates based on income resources. Finally, Table 9 shows trends in poverty measures for two basic demographic subgroups, age and race categories. These groups are of interest because children and Blacks have historically high poverty rates. While levels vary in expected ways, there are also some differences in trends for these groups. Trends in poverty rates for children and for Blacks roughly parallel the official measure. For these groups, poverty rates in 2003 are higher than in 2001. For the elderly and persons of other races, poverty rates in 2002 are lower than those in 2001 when the expenditure-based resource measure is used. All of the figures shown indicate differences between the two resource measures. This is an important area for further investigation. Large differences in poverty rates from using the income- and expenditure-based measures suggest that income and expenditures do not reflect the same ability of families and consumers to meet their basic needs. More likely, this could be an indication that our measures need refinement. For example, is too much income being assigned to families based on the addition of net realized capital gains based on the computation of the current CPS tax model? Are all expenditures being captured in our measure? Should the value of goods and services drawn from one’s business for personal use be counted in expenditures? Should they be counted in income? Is the time period for expenditures, quarterly, too short to adequately reflect expenditures for poverty measurement? When quarterly reports of expenditures are used for the analysis, negative medical care expenditure are more likely to result than when twelve months of expenditures are used. Negative medical expenditures result when reimbursements are made for expenditures made in an earlier period. Should these reimbursements be considered income and thereby not be counted in an expenditure-based resource measure? Setting negative medical expenditure expenditures to zero results in poverty rates that are about three percentage points than the ones presented in this study (results not shown). Bavier (2005) used out-of-pocket expenditures, as defined by the BLS, 26 with subtractions for necessary expenses but limited his sample to consumer units with four complete quarters of data. By restricting his sample in this way (and not subtracting as much for work expenses), he produced poverty rates of 16 percent for consumer units. The poverty rate for consumer units in this study using a similar measure (the second expenditure-based resource measure), results in consumer unit poverty rates of 21.5 percent for approximately the same time period. In additional work by Bavier (2006), consumption expenditure-based poverty rates resulted in annual poverty rates 1.5 percentage points lower than rates based on quarterly consumption expenditures. Evidence from the SIPP also suggests that higher poverty rates, based on income measures, result when the reference period is shorter as well (Short, 1990). V. Conclusions The thresholds presented in this study, unlike the official thresholds, reflect recent spending needs in levels and patterns. Unlike the official measure, they account for changes in living standards over time. A focus on meeting spending needs versus consumption needs dictated the construction of the poverty measure presented here. The thresholds produced follow the same procedure over the 2001-2003 period. These, along with the thresholds for 1993-2000 presented in Garner (2005), represent the most recent series of thresholds available that uses the same method over time. The results presented reveal thresholds that have been increasing at a faster rate than official poverty thresholds. The experimental threshold has been increasing at a faster rate than the official threshold since 2001. It was shown that changes in implicit expenditures in the experimental threshold highlight differences between the official poverty measure and the experimental threshold, and provide insight regarding why the official and experimental thresholds move differently. The largest share of expenditures in the CPI (about 40 percent) is represented by goods and services not represented by the basic needs in the thresholds: food, clothing, shelter, utilities, and medical care. This means that the official poverty threshold is influenced more by goods and services other than food, clothing, shelter, utilities, or medical care. It was demonstrated that implicit expenditures for shelter, utilities, and medical care in the thresholds increased much more than the CPI for these items over this period of time. Included in the discussion of a resource measure for poverty statistics was an emphasis on consistency with the selected threshold. It is useful to calculate a resource measure that represents the ability of the family or 27 consumer unit to meet the needs as measured in the particular threshold selected. In this paper experimental poverty thresholds were compared to two measures of resources that represented our best effort at conceptual consistency, one reflecting “inflows” into the household and the other “outflows.” These experimental poverty measures showed trends and levels of poverty that differed from the official measure for the overall population and for some specific subgroups. Many believe that one’s command over economic resources should be measured in terms of household income (Atkinson et al., 2002). However, research using expenditures, including that presented in this study, can “increase our understanding of how people actually choose, or are constrained, to allocate their economic resources.” 28 28 The quote is from Bavier (2006) who supports research using expenditure data for poverty measurement. We agree with his statement. 28 REFERENCES Atkinson, Tony, Bea Cantillon, Eric Marlier, Brian Nolan, Social Indicators: The EU and Social Inclusion, Oxford, Oxford University Press, 2002. Atkinson, A. B. and J.E. Stiglitz, Lectures in Public Economics, McGraw-Hill, Singapore, 1980. Banthin, Jessica, “Where Do We Stand in Measuring Medical Care Needs for Poverty Definitions?” Available at http://www7.nationalacademies.org/cnstat/Workshop_on_Experimental_Poverty_Measures.html, August 2004. Banthin, Jessica, Thesia I. Garner, and Kathleen Short, “Medical Care Needs in Poverty Thresholds: Problems Posed by the Uninsured.” Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality, Presented at the American Economic Association Meetings, January 2001. Bavier, Richard, “Do the Current Poverty Thresholds Include Any Amount for Health Care?” Poverty Measurement Working Paper, Census Bureau, March 2001. Bavier, Richard, “Income and Expenditure Data in Poverty Measurement,” unpublished manuscript from the Office of Management and Budget, April 7, 2006. Bavier, Richard, “Medical Out-of-Pocket Spending in Poverty Thresholds,” Poverty Measurement Working Paper, Census Bureau, October 2000. Bavier, Richard, “Misclassification in An Experimental Poverty Measure,” unpublished manuscript, Office of Management and Budget, April 21, 2005. Bernstein, Jared, Chauna Brocht and Maggie Spade-Aguilar, 2000. How Much Is Enough? Basic Family Budgets for Working Families. Economic Policy Institute, Washington, D.C. Betson, David M., “Is Everything Relative? The Role of Equivalence Scales in Poverty Measurement,” Working Paper, Census Bureau, December 1996. Betson, David M., “Response to Bavier’s Critique of the NRC Panel’s Recommendations”, Poverty Measurements Working Paper, Census Bureau, November 2000. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), 2003 Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey Public Use Microdata Documentation, Washington, D.C., available at: www.bls.gov/cex/2003/cex/cexintvw.pdf, February 24, 2004. Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey Internal Data for 2001Q2-2004Q1, Washington, D.C., 2005 Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), data from 2001, 2002, 2003 available at http://stats.bls.gov/cex/home.htm, 2006. Cage, Rob, Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, personal communications regarding the CPI and expenditure weights, 2006. Canberra Group, Expert Group on Household Income Statistics, Final Report and Recommendations, Ottawa, 2001. Census Bureau (Census), data for 2001, 2002, 2003 available at http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/income/income.html, 2006. Charles, Kerwin Kofi, Sheldon Danziger, Laurie Pounder, and Robert F. Schoeni, “Consumption, Income, and WellBeing Among the Mature Population,” National Poverty Center paper, available at 29 http://www.npc.umich.edu/news/events/consumption06_agenda/pounder-charles-schoeni-danziger.pdf, April 2006. Citro, Constance F., National Academy of Sciences, personal communication regarding the use of shelter consumption as opposed to shelter expenditures in deriving the thresholds, 1999. Citro, Constance F., and Robert T. Michael (eds.), Measuring Poverty: A New Approach, Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 1995. Cutler, David and Lawrence Katz, “Macroeconomic Performance and the Disadvantaged,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Vol. 1991, No. 2, 1991. Fisher, Jonathan, David S. Johnson, Joseph Marchand, Timothy Smeeding, and Barbara B. Torrey, “The Retirement Consumption Puzzle: Evidence from a Consumption Survey,” presentation at the National Poverty Center's "Consumption, Income, and the Well-Being of Families and Children" Conference, May 2006. Garner, Thesia I., “Developing Poverty Thresholds 1993-2003,” 2005 Proceedings of the American Statistical Association, Social Statistics Section [CD-ROM], Alexandria, VA: American Statistical Association, 2005. Garner, Thesia I. and Patricia Rozaklis, “Accounting for Owner Occupied Housing in Poverty: Focus on Thresholds,” American Statistical Association (ASA) Proceedings of the Section on Government Statistics and Section on Social Statistic, 1999. Garner, Thesia I. and Patricia Rozaklis, “Owner-Occupied Housing: An Input for Experimental Poverty Thresholds,” paper presented at session organized by the Society of Government Economists at the annual meeting of the Allied Social Sciences Associations, January 6, 2001. Garner, Thesia I., Stephanie Shipp, Geoffrey Paulin, Kathleen S. Short, and Charles Nelson, “Poverty Measurement in the 1990s,” Monthly Labor Review, March 1998, pp. 39-61. Garner, Thesia I. and Kathleen S. Short, “Owner-Occupied Shelter in Experimental Poverty Measures,” paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the Southern Economic Association, Tampa, Florida, November 1, 2001. Garner, Thesia I. and Kathleen S. Short, “Economic Well-Being Based on Income, Consumer Expenditures and Personal Assessments of Minimum Needs” in John A. Bishop and Yoram Amiel, eds., Studies on Economic Well-being: Essays in the Honor of John P. Formby , Vol. 12 of the Series Research on Economic Inequality, Oxford, UK: Elsevier Science, February 2004, pp. 319-361. Garner, Thesia I. and Kathleen S. Short, “Personal Assessments of Minimum Income and Expenses: What Do They Tell Us about ‘Minimum Living’ Thresholds and Equivalence Scales?” in John A. Bishop and Yoram Amiel, eds., Inequality, Welfare and Poverty: Theory and Measurement, Vol. 9 of the Series Research on Economic Inequality, Oxford, UK: Elsevier Science, 2003, pp.191-243. Greenlees, John S. and Charles C. Mason, “Overview of the 1998 Revision of the Consumer Price Index,” Monthly Labor Review, December 1996, pp. 3-9. Iceland, John. "The CNSTAT Workshop on Experimental Poverty Measures, June 2004." Focus 23(3), 2005, pp. 26-30. International Labour Organization (ILO), Report II: Household Income and Expenditure Statistics, Seventeenth International Conference of Labour Statisticians, Geneva, 24 November-3 December 2003. Johnson, David, Stephanie Shipp, and Thesia I. Garner, “Developing Poverty Thresholds Using Expenditure Data,” in Proceedings of the Government and Social Statistics Section. Alexandria, VA: American Statistical Association, August 1997, pp. 28-37. 30 Meyer, Bruce D. and James X. Sullivan, “Measuring the Well-Being of the Poor Using Income and Consumption,” Journal of Human Resources, 38:S, pp. 1180-1220, 2003. Morissette, R. and Susan Poulin, Income Satisfaction Supplement: Summary of Four Survey Years, Staff Reports, Labour and Household Surveys Analysis Division, Statistics Canada, Ottawa, Canada, 1991. National Research Council. Workshop on Experimental Poverty Measures: Summary of a Workshop. Washington, D.C.: National Academy Press, 2005. Office of Management and Budget (OMB), Statistical Policy Directive No. 14, Definition of Poverty for Statistical Purposes, May 1978, http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/povmeas/ombdir14.html. O'Hara, Amy, “New Methods for Simulating Taxes,” Census Bureau Working Paper, available at http://www.census.gov/hhes/income/papers.html, 2004. Orshansky, Mollie, “Counting the Poor: Another Look at the Poverty Profile,” Reprint from the Social Security Bulletin, U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, Social Security Administration, January 1965. Pearce, Diana , The Real Cost of Living in 2005: The Self-Sufficiency Standard for Connecticut, prepared for the Wider Opportunities for Women, and Office of Workforce Competitiveness, State of Connecticut, available at http://www.sixstrategies.org/states/states.cfm, 2005a. Pearce, Diana, The Self-Sufficiency Standard for the Washington, D.C. Metropolitan Area 2005, prepared for the Wider Opportunities for Women, in conjunction with Wider Opportunities for Women’s Family Economic Self-Sufficiency Project, available at http://www.sixstrategies.org/states/states.cfm, 2005b. Renwick, T. J., 1998. Basic Needs Budgets Revisited: Does the U.S. Consumer Price Index Overestimate the Changes in the Cost of Living for Low-Income Families? Feminist Economics 4(3), pp. 129-142. Renwick, T. J. and Bergmann, B.R., 1993. A Budget-Based Definition of Poverty with an Application to SingleParent Families, Journal of Human Resources 28(1), pp. 1-24. Rogers, John M. And Maureen B. Gray, “CE Data: Quintiles of Income vs. Quintiles of Outlays,” Monthly Labor Review, December 1994, pp. 32-37. Ruggles, Patricia, Drawing the Line: Alternative Poverty Measures and Their Implications for Public Policy, Washington, D.C.: The Urban Institute Press, 1990. Short, Kathleen, “Estimating Resources for Poverty Measurement: 1993-2003,” 2005 Proceedings of the American Statistical Association, Social Statistics Section [CD-ROM], Alexandria, VA: American Statistical Association, 2005. Short, Kathleen, Experimental Poverty Measures: 1999, U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, Consumer Income, P60-216, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, 2001. Short, Kathleen, “The Relationship Between Monthly and Annual Income: SIPP,” paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Statistical Association, 1990. Short, Kathleen, “Work-Related Expenditures in a Measure of Poverty,” available at http://www7.nationalacadmeies.org/cnstat/Workshop_on_Experimental_Poverty_Measures.html, August 2004. Short, Kathleen, and Thesia I. Garner, “A Decade of Experimental Poverty Thresholds: 1990 to 2000,” The ICFAI Journal of Public Finance, II (2), May 2004, pp. 65-89. 31 Short, Kathleen and Thesia I. Garner, “Experimental Poverty Measures Under Alternate Treatments of Medical Outof-Pocket Expenditures,” Monthly Labor Review, August 2002, pp. 3-13. Short, Kathleen, Thesia Garner, David Johnson, and Patricia Doyle, Experimental Poverty Measures: 1990 to 1997, U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, Consumer Income, P60-205, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC, 1999. Short, Kathleen and Patricia Ruggles, “Experimental Measures of Poverty and Net Worth: 1996,” Journal of Income Distribution, forthcoming. Slesnick, Daniel T., “Gaining Ground: Poverty in the Postwar United States,” Journal of Political Economy, 1901(1), pp.1-38, 1993. U.S. Department of Labor (USDL), Bureau of Labor Statistics, BLS Handbook of Methods, Bulletin 2490, April 1997. U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA), Official USDA Food Plans: Cost of Food at Home at Four Levels, U.S. Average, June 2003, available at www.cnpp.usda.gov, issued July 2003. Wolff, Edward, “Wealth, Holdings, and Poor Status in the U.S.,” Review of Income and Wealth, 36(2), pp. 143-165, 1990. (Many of the unpublished working papers listed here are available at: http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/povmeas/papers.html 32 Table 1: Official and Experimental Poverty Thresholds for the Reference Family: 2001-2003 Year Official Experimental $17,960 $21,177 2001 18,244 22,036 2002 18,660 23,170 2003 Source: Census Bureau and authors’ own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2000Q2 – 2003Q1. Table 2: Average Annual CPS Household Income, CE Total Expenditures, and Thresholds Year 2001 2002 2003 Published Before Tax Money Income $58,208 57,852 59,067 Published CE Total Expenditures $39,518 40,677 40,817 Reference Family Experimental Threshold $21,177 22,036 23,170 Source: Census Bureau and Bureau of Labor Statistics web sites, and authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2000Q2 – 2003Q1. Table 3: Shares of Aggregated Annual Expenditures Implicit in the Experimental Threshold for the Reference Family Year 2001 2002 2003 Food 0.280 0.276 0.267 Clothing 0.062 0.063 0.061 Shelter 0.301 0.297 0.305 Utilities 0.134 0.136 0.137 Medical 0.067 0.072 0.075 Other 0.157 0.156 0.155 Source: Authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2000Q2 – 2003Q1. 33 Table 4a: Shares of Aggregated Annual Expenditures Based on the 1998 CPI Market Basket Structure, U.S. City Average, CPI-U Population Year Food1 Clothing2 Shelter3 Utilities4 Medical Other 0.143 0.044 0.324 0.049 0.056 0.384 2001 0.145 0.047 0.305 0.043 0.055 0.403 2002 0.145 0.047 0.305 0.043 0.055 0.403 2003 Source: Basic calculations produced by Cage (2006), Bureau of Labor Statistics; upper level aggregations produced by authors. 1 Does not include alcoholic beverages. 2 Officially referred to as "Apparel". 3 Owners’ equivalent rent for owners shelter costs. 4 Does not include telephone services. Table 4b: Shares of Aggregated Annual Expenditures Based on Experimental Threshold Structure, Reference Family, All U.S. Clothing2 Shelter3 Utilities4 Medical Year Food1 0.143 0.047 0.292 0.073 0.056 2001 0.145 0.052 0.277 0.067 0.055 2002 0.145 0.052 0.277 0.067 0.055 2003 Source: Basic calculations produced by Cage (2006), Bureau of Labor Statistics; upper level aggregations produced by authors. 1 Does not include alcoholic beverages. 2 Officially referred to as "Apparel". 3 Owners’ out-of-pocket expenses for owners shelter costs. 4 Includes telephone services. Other 0.389 0.403 0.403 34 Table 5: Annual CPI-U, U.S. City Average for All Items and Selected Categories Year 2001 2002 2003 All Items 1.77 1.80 1.84 Food 1.73 1.76 1.80 Clothing 1.27 1.24 1.21 Shelter 2.01 2.08 2.13 Utilities 1.50 1.44 1.55 Medical Care 2.73 2.86 2.97 2001 to 2003 3.9 4.0 -5.0 6.2 2.9 percent change Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics web site and authors’ own calculations. 8.9 Table 6: Implicit Average Annual Expenditures Based on Experimental Threshold Structure, Reference Family, All U.S. (in threshold year dollars) Year 2001 2002 2003 Threshold 21,177 22,036 23,170 Food 5,928 6,080 6,176 Clothing 1,315 1,392 1,413 Shelter 6,371 6,535 7,074 Utilities 2,834 3,005 3,169 Medical Care 1,413 1,590 1,742 Other 3,317 3,433 3,596 9.4 4.2 7.5 11.0 11.8 23.3 8.4 2001 to 2003 percent change Source: Authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2000Q2 - 2003Q1. 35 Table 7a. Annual Average Family or Consumer Unit Subtractions Used to Calculate Poverty Rates Payroll Taxes Work Expenses Child Care Expenses Year CPS CE CPS CE CPS CE $2,856 $2,483 $993 $1,093 $163 $140 2001 2,990 2,608 1,038 1,146 155 152 2002 3,039 2,725 1,028 1,128 153 151 2003 Source: Authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2001Q2 - 2004Q1. Table 7b. Annual Average Consumer Unit Addition and Additional Subtractions Used to Calculate Poverty Rates Additions Subtractions Vehicle Change in Financial Property Capital Child Finance Other Finance Year Alimony Charges Accounts1 Improvements2 Support Charges3 $682 $765 $195 $27 $364 $223 2001 835 893 187 22 396 274 2002 874 1,048 165 43 369 183 2003 Source: Authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2001Q2 - 2004Q1. 1 Positive changes to savings accounts, checking accounts, and U.S. savings bonds. 2 Expenditures for capital improvements to owned home, vacation home, and other property 3 Finance charges excluding those for mortgages and vehicles Interest on Home Equity Loans and Lines of Credit $164 157 121 36 Table 7c. Reference Family Thresholds and Annual Average Household Income and Consumer Unit Expenditures Income Published Household BTM Income Income-NAS Expenditures Published CU Total Expenditures Expenditures (CE outlays + additions) Expenditures-NAS Expenditures-NAS-Other Legal Obligations Thresholds Experimental Threshold Official Threshold 2001 2002 2003 $58,208 43,282 $57,852 42,513 $59,067 42,637 39,518 39,215 35,499 34,526 40,677 40,623 36,716 35,680 40,817 41,130 37,126 36,246 21,177 17,960 22,036 18,244 23,170 18,660 Source: Published data from Census Bureau and Bureau of Labor Statistics web sites for years 2001-2003; other results based on authors' own calculations using U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey data from 2000Q2 - 2004Q1. 37 Table 8: Population Poverty Rates Using Income- or Expenditure-Based Resources: 2001-2003 Official Threshold Experimental Threshold Income-Based Resources Subtractions Experimental Threshold Expenditure-Based Resources Subtractions NAS + Other Legal Year None NAS1 None NAS1 Obligations2 11.7 15.5 17.4 22.7 23.9 2001 12.1 16.4 17.8 23.3 24.5 2002 12.5 17.7 19.7 25.6 26.7 2003 Source: Authors’ own calculations using 1994 - 2004 CPS ASEC and U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey 2001Q2 - 2004Q1 CE data. 1 Subtractions for payroll taxes, work related expenses, and child care expenses associated with working. 2 Child support payments, alimony, vehicle finance charges, interest on home equity loans and lines of credit. 38 Table 9: Population Poverty Rates Using Income- and Expenditure-Based Resources 2001 2002 2003 Children NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions 16.3 19.3 16.7 20.1 17.6 21.7 19.9 20.3 23.0 NAS Subtractions1 26.2 26.8 30.2 27.8 28.3 31.5 10.1 13.4 10.6 14.1 10.8 15.2 14.4 15.1 16.3 19.9 20.7 22.5 21.0 21.8 23.5 10.1 18.4 10.5 20.4 10.3 22.1 27.0 26.3 30.4 29.3 29.1 32.3 30.0 29.8 32.9 9.9 13.5 10.2 14.3 10.5 15.4 14.9 15.1 17.3 20.0 20.2 22.8 21.0 21.2 23.8 22.7 28.0 23.9 29.4 24.3 31.0 31.3 34.0 35.1 2 NAS + Other Non-elderly Adults NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions NAS Subtractions 1 NAS + Other2 Elderly NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions NAS Subtractions 1 2 NAS + Other White NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions NAS Subtractions 1 NAS + Other2 Blacks NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions 1 38.1 41.6 43.2 NAS + Other2 Other races NAS Income Official Experimental Expenditure Outlays No Subtractions 40.4 43.7 45.1 12.8 16.9 12.5 16.8 13.6 18.9 20.9 19.2 19.6 NAS Subtractions1 26.1 25.9 26.6 NAS Subtractions 2 26.7 26.5 27.3 NAS + Other Source: Authors’ own calculations using 1994 - 2004 CPS ASEC and U.S. Consumer Expenditure Interview Survey 2001Q2 - 2004Q1 CE data. 1 Subtractions for payroll taxes, work related expenses, and child care expenses associated with working. 2 Subtractions for child support payments, alimony, vehicle finance charges, interest on home equity loans and lines of credit. 39 Chart 1. Official and Experiment Poverty Thresholds for the Reference Family: 2001-2003 $25,000 $20,000 $15,000 $10,000 $5,000 $0 2001 2002 Official 2003 Experimental 40 Chart 2. Average Annual NAS Subtractions to Calculate Poverty Rates in Both CPS and CE $0 -$500 -$1,000 -$1,500 -$2,000 -$2,500 -$3,000 -$3,500 CPS-Payroll Tax CE-Payroll Tax CPS-Work Expenses 2001 CE-Work Expenses 2002 CPS-Child Care CE-Child Care 2003 41 Chart 3. Annualized Annual Mean Additions and Subtractions for Expenditure Resource Poverty Measure $1,200 $1,000 $800 $600 $400 $200 $0 -$200 -$400 -$600 Child Support Alimony Vehicle Finance Charges CC Finance Charges 2001 2002 Home Equity Change in Borrowing Interest Financial Accounts Property Capital Improvements 2003 42 Chart 4. Average Annual Income and Expenditures $60,000 $55,000 $50,000 Published Household BTM Income Income-NAS $45,000 Expenditures $40,000 Published CU Total Expenditures Expenditures-NAS $35,000 Expenditures-NAS-Other Legal Obligations Experimental Threshold $30,000 Official Threshold $25,000 $20,000 $15,000 2001 2002 2003 43 Chart 5. Poverty Rates Using Official and Experimental Measures 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Official Experi w/ NAS Income Experi w/ Expenditures 2001 2002 Experi w/Exp-NAS Experi w/Exp-NAS-other 2003 44