Country-Specific Idiosyncratic Risk and Global Equity Index Returns C. James Hueng and Ruey Yau Abstract: The “idiosyncratic volatility puzzle” arises from the empirical evidence that stocks with higher past idiosyncratic volatilities earn lower future returns. Studies have found that this puzzle can be explained by certain time-series properties of the firm-specific idiosyncratic shocks. In the country-level market index data, however, the puzzle does not exist, which implies that the time-series properties of the country-specific idiosyncratic shocks are different from those of the firm-specific idiosyncratic shocks within a country. We find that the differences are, first, that lagged idiosyncratic volatility is a better proxy for expected idiosyncratic risk in the country-level data than in the firm-level data. Second, unlike the firm-specific idiosyncratic skewness, the countryspecific idiosyncratic skewness is not significant enough to play a role in determining index returns. Finally, return reversals documented in the firm-level data are not present in the country-level index data. Instead, a momentum effect is found in the countryspecific index returns. JEL Classification: G11, G12, G15 Keywords: Idiosyncratic volatility puzzle; Idiosyncratic skewness; International asset pricing i 1. Introduction The single-factor capital asset pricing model (CAPM) demonstrates that investors are able to enjoy the benefit of reducing unsystematic risk from diversification while holding the market portfolio in equilibrium (Sharpe 1964 and Lintner 1965). However, Merton (1987) demonstrates that a sub-optimally diversified portfolio could be in equilibrium in a capital market with incomplete information. In reality, investors rarely hold well-diversified portfolios. Campbell et al. (2001) suggest that an investor needs to hold at least 50 randomly selected stocks to achieve complete portfolio diversification. Goetzmann and Kumar (2008), however, examine more than 60,000 equity investment accounts from 1991 to 1996 and find that less than ten percent of the investors hold more than ten stocks. The apparent lack of diversification among most investors indicates that idiosyncratic risk should be priced because under-diversified investors require compensation in the form of a higher return for bearing this risk (Levy 1978; Merton, 1987). Given the benchmark prediction of a positive relationship between idiosyncratic risk and excess returns, the related empirical evidence is far from being conclusive. In particular, the "idiosyncratic volatility puzzle" found by Ang et al. (2006) in the U.S. market has attracted much research. This puzzle arises from the empirical evidence of cross-sectional analyses showing that stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities in the previous month have abysmally low average monthly returns. Ang et al. (2009) point out that the puzzle found by Ang et al. (2006) may be dependent on the particular sample used. To explore the possibility of datasnooping, they check whether the puzzle exists in other markets. They find the same puzzling evidence that 1 stocks with high idiosyncratic volatility tend to have low average returns in each of the G7 equity markets and in a larger sample of 23 developed markets. Both studies (Ang et al., 2006, 2009) investigate the relationship between expected returns and the associated risk within a country using cross-sectional firm-level data. The discussion of the datasnooping problem of the puzzle has never been extended to another investment avenue - the market for international equity indices. Country-level cross-sectional analyses have used these global index data to discuss the international CAPM or international market integration/segmentation (e.g., Li et al., 2003; Driessen and Laeven, 2007; You and Daigler, 2010), but have never addressed the datasnooping issue of the puzzle in these data. Studies suggesting international market segmentation such as Bali and Cakici (2010) find evidence of a positive and significant relationship between country-specific idiosyncratic volatilities in the previous month and future index returns. This absence of the abnormal puzzle in the international equity index market simply confirms the normal positive risk-return relationship and may not deserve much attention from the literature on the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle. However, the evidence that the puzzle does not exist in the international equity index market provides a new path of research. Rather than discussing the datasnooping issue of the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle, we use this evidence to investigate the differences in the timeseries properties between the firm-level and country-level data. Specifically, some studies claim that the puzzle can be explained by certain time-series properties of the idiosyncratic shocks. If these explanations are legitimate, the time series properties of the country-level data must differ from those of the firm-level data since the puzzle does not exist in the international 2 index data. This would have important implications for different investment strategies in firmlevel stock portfolios and in international index portfolios. For example, Huang et al. (2010) argue that the puzzle is caused by the omission of lagged stock returns as a regressor in the cross-sectional regressions. They find that past returns have a negative effect on current returns (return reversal). In addition, there is a positive contemporaneous correlation between realized idiosyncratic volatility and stock returns. Therefore, if lagged returns are omitted from the regression, the effect of past idiosyncratic volatility on expected returns is negatively biased. Once return reversals are controlled for, they find a significantly positive relationship between the conditional idiosyncratic volatility and expected returns. Fu (2009), on the other hand, inspects the second moment of the idiosyncratic shocks. He argues that since idiosyncratic volatilities are time-varying with a small average first-order autocorrelation, lagged idiosyncratic volatility is not a good estimate of expected idiosyncratic volatility. Therefore, the negative relationship between lagged idiosyncratic risk and excess returns does not represent the expected risk-return relationship. Instead, Fu models the idiosyncratic volatility as an exponential GARCH (EGARCH) process, and uses the estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatility to proxy for the expected idiosyncratic volatility. He finds evidence of a positive relationship between the estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatilities and stock returns. Boyer et al. (2010) consider the investors’ preference for positive skewness in an attempt to explain the puzzle. They provide evidence supporting the theory that expected idiosyncratic skewness and expected returns are negatively correlated (Barberis and Huang, 3 2008; Mitton and Vorkink, 2007). In addition, they find that past idiosyncratic volatility is a strong predictor of future idiosyncratic skewness and that the relationship between past idiosyncratic volatility and expected idiosyncratic skewness is positive. Therefore, investors may accept lower expected returns on stocks that have experienced high idiosyncratic volatility because these stocks have higher expected idiosyncratic skewness. This provides a novel explanation of the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle. The empirical results from these studies suggest that the above time series properties of the firm-level idiosyncratic shocks must differ from those of the country-specific idiosyncratic shocks in Bali and Cakici (2010). Specifically, based on the arguments of Fu (2009), the idiosyncratic volatilities of a specific country index return relative to the world market must be highly autocorrelated, and therefore past idiosyncratic volatility is a good predictor of expected idiosyncratic volatility. If not, then Bali and Cakici's (2010) test would be invalid and a better measure of the expected idiosyncratic volatility needs to be used to test the risk-return relationship in the country-level cross-sectional regressions. Furthermore, the relationships among return, idiosyncratic volatility, and idiosyncratic skewness in the firm-level data found by Boyer et al. (2010) may not hold in the international index market. On the one hand, Bali and Cakici's (2010) results may simply imply that, unlike the preference for lottery-like stocks in domestic asset portfolios, international investors do not prefer positively skewed index securities in their under-diversified international portfolios. However, on the other hand, if they do prefer positive skewness, then past idiosyncratic volatility should not positively predict future idiosyncratic skewness in the international index market; otherwise, the positive relationship between lagged idiosyncratic volatility and future 4 returns found by Bali and Cakici (2010) would imply that portfolios with higher idiosyncratic skewness earn higher returns. Using international equity index data, we find that, first, lagged idiosyncratic volatility is not a bad predictor of future idiosyncratic volatility in the country-level index data, and performs better than that in the firm-level data. It provides useful information on expected idiosyncratic volatility just as the conditional idiosyncratic volatility does. Second, idiosyncratic skewness in the country-level index data is essentially zero. Therefore, it does not play a role in determining the index returns and can be ignored in the pricing of international portfolios. Finally, return reversals are not present in the country-level index data and, instead, a momentum effect is found. This momentum effect, however, does not alter our conclusions on the higher moments of the idiosyncratic shocks. The next section discusses the time-series properties of the country-specific idiosyncratic volatility and its relationship with the expected returns. Section 3 investigates the role of idiosyncratic skewness in international asset pricing. Section 4 elaborates on the economic meaning of our statistical findings and concludes the paper. 2. Returns and idiosyncratic volatilities We start with a brief review of the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle. Let ri , d ,t denote the daily idiosyncratic return of stock i on date d in month t. The idiosyncratic volatility in month t is defined as the realized monthly standard deviation of the daily idiosyncratic shocks: IVOLi ,t = Var ( ri , d ,t ) . Let Ri ,t denote the monthly return of stock i in month t. In deriving the idiosyncratic shocks from the Fama-French (1993) three-factor model, Ang et al. (2006), using 5 U.S. firm-level data, and Ang et al. (2009), using firm-level data for several international markets, run a cross-sectional regression for the following econometric specification in each month t: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t IVOLi ,t −1 + Γ t X i,t −1 + ε i ,t , (1) where X i,t is a vector of other risk measures and firm characteristics. They find that the timeseries average of the estimated γ 1,t is negative and statistically significant, indicating that investors accept a lower return on stocks with higher lagged idiosyncratic volatilities. This is the empirical evidence known as "the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle" because, according to Merton's (1987) theory, rational investors should require higher average returns to compensate for their holding imperfectly diversified portfolios. They demand a premium for holding stocks with high idiosyncratic volatilities, and therefore idiosyncratic risk should be priced to compensate rational investors holding under-diversified portfolios (Malkiel and Xu 2006). Fu (2009) argues that a valid test for the risk-return relationship should instead be examined by the following regression: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t Eˆ t −1[ IVOLi ,t ] + Γ t Eˆ t −1[ X i,t ] + ε i ,t . (1') That is, if idiosyncratic volatility is priced, we expect there to be a positive empirical relationship between expected returns and expected idiosyncratic volatility. Running (1) instead of (1') would implicitly assume that IVOLi ,t −1 is a good predictor of Et −1[ IVOLi ,t ] . To test whether this assumption is valid, Fu analyzes the persistence of the realized idiosyncratic volatilities of U.S. stocks for the period 1963-2006. Using the Fama-French (1993) three6 factor model to obtain idiosyncratic returns, he shows that the first-order autocorrelation of IVOLi ,t is small (the average across stocks is 0.330). In addition, he claims that if IVOLi ,t −1 is a good predictor of Et −1[ IVOLi ,t ] , then IVOLi ,t should be modeled as a random walk process. He uses the Augmented Dickey-Fuller t-test and shows that for almost 90% of the stocks in his sample, the random walk hypothesis for the realized idiosyncratic volatility is rejected at the 1% significance level. Therefore, he claims that equation (1) run by Ang et al. (2006) is not a valid test of the expected idiosyncratic risk-return relationship. Rather, a proper measure of conditional volatility should be used instead of the lagged volatility. To obtain an estimate of Et −1[ IVOLi ,t ] , Fu uses EGARCH models to obtain the monthly conditional idiosyncratic variance (denoted as hi ,t ). idiosyncratic volatility ( IVOLi ,t −1 ) in (1) with By replacing the lagged realized hi ,t , he finds that the time-series average of the estimated γ 1,t is positive and significant. That is, there is a positive relationship between the expected return and expected idiosyncratic volatility, and therefore, the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle is explained.1 In a study of an international CAPM, Bali and Cakici (2010) test whether the countryspecific idiosyncratic risk is priced by using country-level aggregate market index data from 37 countries and a world market portfolio index. The daily idiosyncratic shocks in month t are defined as the residuals from a regression of country i's daily market portfolio index returns ( Ri ,d ,t ) on the daily world market portfolio returns ( Rw ,d ,t ): 1 Spiegel and Wang (2005), who focus on the out-of-sample predictive power of idiosyncratic volatility and liquidity using monthly data and EGARCH models, also find that stock returns are increasing with the level of idiosyncratic volatility. 7 Ri , d ,t = µ i ,t + Betai ,t ⋅ Rw, d ,t + ri , d ,t , for d = 1, 2, . . ., Dt , (2) where Dt is the number of trading days in month t and Betai ,t is the conditional world market beta of country i in month t. They define the country-specific idiosyncratic volatility in month t as the realized monthly standard deviation of the daily idiosyncratic shocks: IVOLi ,t = Dt ∑ (r d =1 i , d ,t 2 − ri ,d ,t ) . They run a monthly cross-sectional regression of the returns to 2 country i’s market portfolio ( Ri ,t ) on lagged idiosyncratic volatility ( IVOLi ,t −1 ) and a vector of other risk measures: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t IVOLi ,t −1 + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t , (3) where Betai ,t is the conditional world market beta from (2), EPi ,t is the natural logarithm of the earnings-to-price ratio, and DYi ,t is the natural logarithm of the dividends-to-price ratio in month t. They find that the time-series average of the estimated effect of IVOLi ,t −1 on Ri ,t (i.e., γˆ1,t ) is positive and statistically significant. This indicates that international investors hold under-diversified international equity-index portfolios because the country-specific risk is priced, and that the country-specific idiosyncratic volatility predicts a positive index return in the next month. Therefore, the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle does not appear in the crosscountry market index data. 2 Since we use OLS regressions in (2) including a constant term, ri ,d ,t = 0 . Note that Bali and Cakici (2010) ignore the scaling and do not divide the sum of squared residuals by the number of days. We use this specification throughout the paper so that we can compare our results with theirs. 8 According to Fu's argument, Bali and Cakici's (2010) test would be invalid unless the lagged idiosyncratic volatility were a good predictor of the expected idiosyncratic volatility. Therefore, our first step is to analyze the time-series property of the idiosyncratic volatility of the country-level market index returns. We use the same data as those in Bali and Cakici (2010), whose data end in September 2006, but update their data to November 2010. The data are obtained from Datastream Global indices, and include U.S. dollar-denominated returns on stock market indices for 37 countries plus the world market portfolio. There are 23 developed markets and 14 developing or emerging markets.3 Table 1 shows the summary statistics of the monthly market index returns for each country and the world market, including the means, standard deviations, and correlations with the world market index returns. The next two columns show the time-series averages of EPi ,t and DYi ,t for each country. We use all available data to calculate the summary statistics.4 The starting month for each country is shown in the second column. The sample ends in November 2010 for all countries. Even with the updated data added, the summary statistics are in general very similar to those in Bali and Cakici (2010): the emerging markets exhibit higher average returns and higher standard deviations of returns, compared to the developed markets. 3 Based on Bali and Cakici's (2010) categorization, the 23 developed markets are Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hong Kong, Ireland, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Portugal, Singapore, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, and United States. The 14 developing or emerging markets are Argentina, Brazil, Chile, China, India, Korea, Malaysia, Mexico, the Philippines, Poland, South Africa, Taiwan, Thailand, and Turkey. 4 Data for the earnings-to-price ratio ( EPi ,t ) and the dividends-to-price ratio ( DYi ,t ) are in general shorter than the returns data. 9 To obtain the monthly data of the conditional world market beta ( Betai ,t ) and idiosyncratic volatility ( IVOLi ,t ), we use daily data within each month to run time-series regression (2). This generates the monthly Betai ,t and the daily idiosyncratic returns ( ri , d ,t ) . The daily idiosyncratic returns are then used to calculate the realized monthly idiosyncratic volatility ( IVOLi ,t ). The last two columns of Table 1 show the time series averages of Betai ,t and IVOLi ,t for each country. Again, the results are in general consistent with those reported in Bali and Cakici (2010): the country-specific idiosyncratic volatility is much higher in the emerging markets than in the developed markets, while the cross-sectional differences in the systematic risk for developed and emerging markets are not as significant as those in the idiosyncratic risk. To confirm Bali and Cakici's (2010) results on the idiosyncratic risk-return relationship using the updated data, we run several versions of equation (3) like they do in their paper. Table 2 reports the time-series averages of the estimated coefficients, their P-values based on the Newey and West (1987) heteroscedasticity- and autocorrelation-adjusted t-statistics, and the time-series averages of the R-squared.5 Consistent with the findings in Bali and Cakici (2010), we find that, first of all, in all specifications, almost all the risk measures have a positive effect on the returns. Secondly, the world systematic risk factor (i.e., the world market beta) does not affect returns, indicating that country-specific factors provide more of an 5 The data availabilities are different either across variables within a country or across countries. We require a minimum of ten observations in each cross-sectional regression. 10 explanation for the variation in index returns.6 Thirdly, the earnings-to-price ratio is the most significant risk factor, and the effect of the dividends-to-price ratio disappears when the earnings-to-price ratio is included in the regression. More importantly, the time-series average of the estimated effect of IVOLi ,t −1 on Ri ,t , i.e., γˆ1,t , is positive and statistically significant at the 5% level in all cases. This confirms Bali and Cakici's (2010) finding that the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle does not exist in the cross-country market index data. However, is the above test valid? That is, according to Fu's argument, is IVOLi ,t −1 a good estimate of expected idiosyncratic volatility Et −1[ IVOLi ,t ] ? The first column of Table 3 reports the first-order autocorrelation coefficients of IVOLi ,t for each country. The average of the first-order autocorrelation coefficients of IVOLi ,t across these 37 countries is 0.552, which is higher than that in Fu's U.S. firm-level data (0.330). That is, the idiosyncratic volatility is more persistent in the country-level market index returns than in the U.S. firm-level data. The second column of Table 3 reports the test statistics of the Augmented Dickey-Fuller unit-root ttest on IVOLi ,t . The results show that the test fails to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root in 13 of the 37 countries at the 1% significance level, compared to 90% rejection rate in Fu's firm-level data. These two pieces of evidence in Table 3, of course, are not strong enough for us to claim that the lagged idiosyncratic volatility ( IVOLi ,t −1 ) is a good proxy for the expected idiosyncratic volatility ( Et −1 IVOLi ,t ) in the country-level data. However, it is a better proxy in the country-level data than in the firm-level data. These observations may explain why the 6 Bekaert, Hodrick, and Zhang (2009) also show that local factors explain index returns through a multiple-factor model. 11 idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in equation (3) exists in the firm-level data but not in the country-level data. Using the realized idiosyncratic volatility in month t-1 ( IVOLi ,t −1 ) as the forecast of the idiosyncratic volatility in month t ( Et −1 IVOLi ,t ) implicitly assumes that the idiosyncratic volatility follows a martingale process. The unit-root test results above show that this may not be a proper assumption for all the countries in our sample. To relax this restrictive assumption, we follow Huang et al. (2010) and use the best-fit autoregressive integrated moving average (ARIMA) process to model the monthly conditional idiosyncratic volatility over a rolling window. Specifically, we use the realized idiosyncratic volatility over the previous twentyfour months to find the best-fit ARIMA model using the Schwarz criterion (BIC). Then the model is employed to predict the idiosyncratic volatility in the next month. We replace IVOLi ,t −1 in (3) with this estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatility ( Eˆ t −1 IVOLi ,t ) from the best-fit ARIMA model and re-evaluate the relationship between the country-index returns and the expected idiosyncratic volatilities: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t Eˆt −1 IVOLi ,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t . (3') The results are reported in Table 4. The positive relationship between conditional expected idiosyncratic volatilities and returns is again confirmed. Interestingly, the results are very similar to those in Table 2: the effects of idiosyncratic volatilities on index returns are all significantly positive and very similar in magnitudes; the world market beta is the least significant risk factor; the earnings-to-price ratio is the most significant risk factor; and the effect of the dividends-to-price ratio disappears when the earnings-to-price ratio is included in 12 the regression. Judging from the average R-squared, using the conditional idiosyncratic volatility estimated from the best-fit ARIMA model to replace the lagged idiosyncratic volatility does not improve the in-sample forecast of the cross-country market index returns. Bali and Cakici (2008), using firm-level data, show that, compared to the realized monthly idiosyncratic volatility calculated from daily data, the conditional idiosyncratic volatility estimated from a GARCH (1,1) model or an EGARCH(1,1) model using monthly data is a more accurate proxy for expected future idiosyncratic volatility. 7 As mentioned earlier, this is the strategy used by Fu (2009) to obtain the monthly conditional idiosyncratic variance. Therefore, to confirm the positive idiosyncratic risk-return relationship in the country-level data, our next step is to follow their strategy and estimate the conditional idiosyncratic volatility from an EGARCH (1,1) model by using monthly data. Specifically, we first regress the monthly country index returns on the world returns, Ri ,t = µ i + ρ i Rw ,t + ri ,t , to obtain the monthly country-specific idiosyncratic returns, and then model the idiosyncratic returns as an AR-EGARCH(1,1) process: ri ,t = α 0i + ∑ α ij ri ,t − j + ε i ,t , (4) j ln hi ,t = κ i + α i ⋅ ln hi ,t −1 + β i ⋅ 7 ε i ,t −1 hi ,t −1 +γi ⋅ ε i ,t −1 hi ,t −1 ⋅ I i+,t −1 , (5) Foster and Nelson (1996) show that the conditional volatility estimated from the GARCH models amounts to the conditional volatility estimated from a weighted rolling regression using data from the preceding months. 13 where the autoregressive (AR) lag length j is chosen by the Ljung-Box Q tests as the minimum lag that renders the serially uncorrelated ε i ,t (at the 5% significance level) up to 24 lags from an OLS autoregression; hi ,t is the conditional variance of ε i ,t , ε i ,t = hi ,t vi ,t , + + vi ,t ~ N (0,1) , and I i ,t = 1 if ε i ,t >0 and Ii ,t = 0 otherwise. Table 5 reports the estimates of the EGARCH process, along with the means of the estimated conditional idiosyncratic volatility hi ,t for each country. In general, the estimated coefficients in the EGARCH process are statistically significant at the traditional significance level. For most countries the conditional idiosyncratic volatility is highly persistent. The relative conditional idiosyncratic volatilities ( hi ,t ) across countries are consistent with the relative realized idiosyncratic volatilities ( IVOLi ,t ) across countries as reported in Table 1: the country-specific idiosyncratic volatility is much higher in the emerging markets than in the developed markets. We replace IVOLi ,t −1 in (3) with hi ,t and re-evaluate the relationship between the country-index returns and expected idiosyncratic volatilities: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t hi ,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t . (3'') The results are reported in Table 6. The positive relationship between conditional expected idiosyncratic volatilities and index returns is again confirmed.8 By comparing the results in 8 Similar conclusions can also be found in Brockman et al. (2009), who apply Fu’s (2009) EGARCH model to another set of international index data and find supporting evidence for a positive and significant relationship between expected returns and idiosyncratic volatility. 14 Table 6 with those in Table 2 and Table 4, we can see that regressions (3), (3'), and (3'') generate very similar results. Although (3'') yields a slightly higher R-squared than (3) and (3'), the similarities in these results show that the lagged realized idiosyncratic volatility is a good proxy for the conditional idiosyncratic volatility in the international market index data. It provides as useful information as the conditional volatility does in forecasting international index returns. As argued by Huang et al. (2010), if return reversals exist and the lagged return is omitted from the regressions, the effect of idiosyncratic volatility on expected returns would be under-estimated. Even if this is the case, however, our conclusion above would not change because we have found a positive and significant effect. To see the role of return reversals in our analysis, we add the lagged returns to regressions (3), (3'), and (3'') and report the results in Panels (A)-(C) of Table 7, respectively. Interestingly, return reversals do not exist in the country-level index data. Rather, we find a statistically significant momentum effect. Therefore, omitting the lagged returns actually over-estimates the effect of conditional idiosyncratic volatility on the expected returns. The magnitude of the momentum effect is, however, relatively small. After controlling for the momentum effect, the size and the level of significance of the effect of idiosyncratic volatility on the expected returns are slightly reduced. However, the effect is still positive and marginally significant at the 10% level in almost all cases. In sum, our results are consistent with Fu's argument. As long as lagged realized idiosyncratic volatilities proxy well for expected idiosyncratic volatilities, investors will expect higher returns on portfolios that have experienced high idiosyncratic volatilities. The lagged realized idiosyncratic volatility is as good a predictor of the expected idiosyncratic volatilities 15 as the conditional idiosyncratic volatility is for the international market index data. Our analysis serves to validate Bali and Cakici's (2010) use of lagged idiosyncratic volatility to test the risk-return relationship in the international market index data. These conclusions remain robust after controlling for the momentum effect. 3. Returns, idiosyncratic volatilities, and idiosyncratic skewness By incorporating the idea that investors prefer positive skewness, Boyer et al. (2010) consider the role of idiosyncratic skewness in explaining the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle. Using firm-level data in the U.S. stock market, they find that first, past idiosyncratic volatility is, compared to the past idiosyncratic skewness, a strong predictor of future idiosyncratic skewness; and second, expected idiosyncratic skewness and expected returns are negatively correlated. Therefore, investors may accept lower expected returns on stocks that have high lagged idiosyncratic volatilities because these stocks have higher expected idiosyncratic skewness. The absence of the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle in the global equity index data implies that Boyer et al.'s arguments may not hold in the international index market. If international investors prefer positively skewed index securities in their under-diversified international portfolios, then past idiosyncratic volatility should not positively predict future idiosyncratic skewness in the international index market; otherwise, the positive relationship between lagged idiosyncratic volatility and index returns found in Bali and Cakici (2010) implies that portfolios with higher idiosyncratic skewness earn higher returns. To verify Boyer et al.'s first argument (i.e., past idiosyncratic volatility is a strong predictor of future idiosyncratic skewness) in the country-level index market, we follow their steps and estimate the cross-sectional regression separately for each month t: 16 ISK i ,t = β 0,t + β1,t ISK i ,t −T + β 2,t IVOLi ,t −T + υ i ,t , (6) where T is the forecast horizon. We use our country-level index data and equation (2) to obtain the idiosyncratic shocks ( ri , d ,t ). By denoting S(t) as the set of trading days from the first day of month t-T+1 through the end of month t, Boyer et al. define the historical estimate of idiosyncratic volatility at time t as the standard deviation of the daily idiosyncratic shocks in S(t): IVOLi ,t = ∑ (r d ∈S ( t ) i , d ,t 9 − ri ,d ,t ) . Therefore, the definition of IVOLi ,t is different from that in 2 our earlier analyses unless the forecast horizon T = 1. The set of trading days S(t-T) would cover the first day of month t-2T+1 through the end of month t-T. The historical estimate of idiosyncratic skewness at time t is then defined as: ISK i ,t = ∑ (r d ∈S (t ) i , d ,t − ri , d ,t ) 3 IVOL3i ,t . Using U.S. firm-level data, Boyer et al. find that if IVOLi ,t −T is included, the time series average of βˆ1,t is insignificant and the time series average of βˆ2,t is significant. That is, past idiosyncratic volatility is, compared to the past idiosyncratic skewness, a stronger predictor of future idiosyncratic skewness. Using the country-level index data, Table 8 reports, for horizons T = 1, 6, 12, 24, and 60, the time-series averages of the estimated coefficients, their P-values based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics, and the time-series averages of the R-squared. Apparently, all the estimates are not only small in magnitudes but also highly insignificant. Neither lagged 9 Boyer et al. (2010) divide the sum of squared residuals by the number of trading days. We do not do this scaling because the current expression is consistent with our analyses earlier in the paper when the forecast horizon is one month (i.e. T=1). See Footnote 3. 17 idiosyncratic skewness nor lagged idiosyncratic volatility predicts future idiosyncratic skewness. Therefore, Boyer et al.'s observation that past idiosyncratic volatility predicts future idiosyncratic skewness is not present in the country-level data. Next, using the country-level data, we verify the second argument by Boyer et al. that the expected idiosyncratic skewness and expected returns are negatively correlated. Their cross-sectional regression is specified as: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + Λt −1Zi ,t −1 + γ t −1Eˆt −1[ ISKi ,t +T −1 ] + ε i ,t , (7) where Zi,t is a vector of risk measures and Et [ ISKi ,t +T ] is the expected idiosyncratic skewness.10 Boyer et al. construct the measure of Et [ ISKi ,t +T ] from the conditional regression (6). However, as shown in Table 8, the model fits badly, and one therefore cannot expect the conditional idiosyncratic skewness from (6) to be a good measure of the expected idiosyncratic skewness. To find a better measure of the expected idiosyncratic skewness, we adopt Fu's (2009) timeseries strategy and estimate the conditional idiosyncratic skewness from an EGARCH model. For comparisons with our earlier results and for the sake of simplicity, we only focus on estimating conditional idiosyncratic skewness with the horizon T = 1 in the following analyses. Recall that in the previous section, we follow Fu and assume that vi ,t = standard normal distribution. ε i ,t follows the hi ,t Although the EGARCH specification accommodates the asymmetric property of volatility (whereby negative shocks increase volatility more than 10 Boyer et al. (2010) actually run this regression with portfolio returns and skewness formed by sorting stock based on expected skewness. Here we instead use individual index returns and skewness because we only have 37 indices. 18 positive shocks), that model is unable to explicitly estimate the skewness of the idiosyncratic shocks. To model the skewness of the distribution, we relax the assumption of normality and adopt a more flexible distribution, namely, the skewed student-t (ST) distribution proposed by Hansen (1994). The ST distribution is a parsimonious two-parameter distribution, but also a flexible one. It is able to model not only leptokurtosis but also asymmetry. The density function of the ST distribution is: η +1 2 − 2 1 σ ⋅ vi , t + µ σ ⋅ c ⋅ 1 + η − 2 1 + λ g ST (vi , t | η , λ ) = η +1 2 − 1 σ ⋅ vi ,t + µ 2 σ ⋅ c ⋅ 1 + η − 2 1 − λ for vi , t ≥ − µ , σ for vi ,t < − µ , σ η−2 where 2 < η < ∞ , − 1 < λ < 1 , µ = 4 ⋅ λ ⋅ c ⋅ , σ = 1 + 3 ⋅ λ2 − µ 2 , and c = η −1 η +1 Γ 2 η π (η − 2)Γ 2 . The skewness sk = M 3 − 3µσ 2 − µ 3 σ 3 , where the third raw moment M 3 = 16cλ (1 + λ 2 )(η − 2) 2 . The (η − 1)(η − 3) parameter η controls the tails and the peak of the density and λ controls the rate of descent of the density around vi,t = 0. For details on the ST density, see the appendix in Hansen (1994). To incorporate the conditional idiosyncratic skewness in our time-series model, we specify the idiosyncratic shock in an autoregressive conditional density (ARCD) model suggested by Hansen (1994). Hansen’s ARCD modeling strategy is to model the parameters in the conditional density function as functions of the elements of the information set so that the higher moments also depend on the conditioning information. He conjectures that since 19 GARCH models make the conditional second moment a function of the lagged errors, it is reasonable to believe that this strategy could also work well for the other moments. Therefore, we follow his suggestion and model the skewness parameter λ in the density function of the ST distribution as: λi ,t = −.99 + .99 − ( −.99) , 1 + exp( −ωi ,t ) ωi ,t = a + b ⋅ ε i ,t −1 + c ⋅ ε i2,t −1 , (8) where the logistic transformation is used to set constraints that λi,t lies between .99 and -.99, even though ωi ,t is allowed to vary over the entire real line. We call this extension of the model in Section 2 the AR-EGARCH-ARCD model. The resulting conditional skewness is denoted by ski ,t .11 The estimated conditional idiosyncratic skewness is then used as an additional regressor in (3'') to test whether expected idiosyncratic skewness and expected returns are negatively correlated in the country-level index market: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t hi′,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + γ 5,t ski ,t −1 + ε i ,t , (3''') where hi′,t is the conditional variance estimated from the new (AR-EGARCH-ARCD) model. Panel (A) of Table 9 presents the results from (3'''). In Panel (B), we add the lagged returns as an additional regressor to control for the momentum effect. The results in both panels show that the relation between the returns and the expected idiosyncratic skewness is highly insignificant. The other estimated coefficients are very similar to those reported in Table 6 and 11 The estimation results are not reported to save space but are available from the authors upon request. 20 Panel (C) of Table 7. Therefore, idiosyncratic skewness does not play a significant role in the country-level index market. One possible explanation of the above results is that international investors do not exhibit a pro-lottery preference in their under-diversified international portfolios. However, by further investigating the idiosyncratic skewness, we find that the above results are more likely to be due to the symmetry of the country-specific idiosyncratic shocks. In Table 10, we show the means of the realized idiosyncratic skewness for T=1, 6, 12, 24, and 60. It can be seen that the averages of ISK i ,t across these 37 countries are very small in magnitude. It is only 0.011 for T=1 in our country-level data, which is relatively small compared to that in the firm-level data reported in Boyer et al., which is about 0.181.12 For the other horizons, the magnitudes are even smaller. In our estimations of the AR-EGARCH-ARCD model, although not reported here to save space, many of the estimated coefficients ( â , b̂ , and ĉ ) in the conditional density function (8) are statistically insignificant. This observation also casts doubt on the role of idiosyncratic skewness in the international index pricing. To see how appropriate this modeling strategy is, we further experiment with two alternative specifications. The first one removes the time-varying property of the skewness and imposes a constant skewness parameter by setting b=c=0 in (8), which we denote as the AR-EGARCH-ST model.13 The 12 Boyer et al. (2010) reports a mean of 0.851 for the idiosyncratic skewness in the U.S. firm- level data. However, their measure is ours multiplied by a scale of Dt . Assuming that there are 22 trading days (Dt =22) yields a mean of 0.181. 13 We find that only 9 out of the 37 indices have a statistically significant (at the 5% level) skewed distribution. The results are available from the authors upon request. 21 second alternative specification assumes a symmetric distribution by setting a=b=c=0 in (8), denoted as the AR-EGARCH-t model, which is essentially an AR-EGARCH model with a symmetric t-distribution. 14 Table 11 shows the estimation results from the cross-sectional regression (3'') with the conditional idiosyncratic volatilities estimated from these three alternative models (AR-EGARCH-ARCD, AR-EGARCH-ST, and AR-EGARCH-t). The results are very similar across these models. Therefore, whether we ignore the idiosyncratic skewness or not, the cross-sectional evidence from Bali and Cakici's (2010) is not affected. We conclude that the distribution of the idiosyncratic shocks in the international index market is mostly symmetric and the idiosyncratic skewness is not significant enough to affect the index returns. 4. Discussions and Conclusions Theories show that under-diversified investors should be compensated for assuming idiosyncratic risks. Empirical studies testing this hypothesis often use a cross-sectional regression of returns on realized idiosyncratic volatilities in the previous month and check for a positive coefficient. The empirical evidence that stocks with higher past idiosyncratic volatilities earn lower future returns has evoked a series of studies trying to explain this empirical puzzle. Studies researching the time series properties of the idiosyncratic returns for answers claim that the puzzle can be explained by the fact that, firstly, past idiosyncratic volatility is not a good predictor of expected idiosyncratic volatility; secondly, the estimate is 14 Not reported here but available upon request, the mean log-likelihoods from these three specifications are so similar that the null of a symmetric distribution cannot be rejected by the likelihood ratio test. 22 biased downward because of an omitted variable (past returns); and finally, investors' aversion to idiosyncratic risk is outweighed by the preference for idiosyncratic skewness. This paper finds that these time series properties of the idiosyncratic returns in the firm-level data are different from those in the country-level index data, which explains why the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle found in the former does not exist in the latter. First of all, in the market for global equity indices, past idiosyncratic volatility is a good predictor of expected idiosyncratic volatility. It provides just as useful information as the conditional idiosyncratic volatility in predicting future returns. That is, country-specific volatilities are persistent. The literature on international equity pricing suggests that the undiversifiable country-specific risk may be due to factors such as purchasing power parity deviations, i.e., exchange rate and inflation risk (Adler and Dumas, 1983), government restrictions on capital movements in emerging markets (Henry, 2000), and asymmetric information across markets (Brennan and Cao, 1997). Since these country-specific risk factors are most likely related to policies adopted by individual countries, it is reasonable for uncertainty to be more persistent in these data, especially in the emerging markets (Lewis, 2011). For example, before an emerging economy announces that it is liberalizing its capital market, uncertainty regarding capital mobility and exchange rate policies is persistently high. After the announcement, this type of uncertainty should remain at a lower level. In addition, as information flows more slowly across borders than across firms within a country, it is not surprising that the country-specific risk possesses a higher degree of clustering, compared to the firm-specific risk relative to the individual country's aggregate market risk. Therefore, past idiosyncratic volatility serves as a better predictor of the expected idiosyncratic volatility in the global index market than in the stock market within a country. 23 Secondly, in contrast to the finding of return reversals in the firm-level data, we report that the international index returns exhibit return momentum. Positive autocorrelations of index returns and short-term profits of momentum strategies in the international index market have been well documented in the literature (e.g., Ahn et al., 2002; Bhojraj and Swaminathan, 2006). Antoniou et al. (2005) attribute this index return momentum to the introduction of index futures, which has increased positive feedback trading in the spot markets. As positive feedback traders respond to past index changes, positive autocorrelations of index returns are shown over short horizons. This momentum effect indicates that the estimate of the expected idiosyncratic risk-return relationship is actually biased upward in a standard international CAPM model like equation (2) (Bali and Cakici, 2010) if the past return is omitted from the regression. After adjusting the bias, however, our conclusions on the higher moments of the country-specific idiosyncratic shocks remain robust. Finally, we find that country-specific idiosyncratic skewness is not significant enough to affect the country-level index returns. Unlike individual stock returns, the country-specific idiosyncratic returns are mostly symmetrically distributed. Considering the globalization of the financial markets, it is not reasonable to expect that an international equity index would earn an abnormal extreme return. Therefore, under-diversified international portfolio investors have no incentive to search for lottery-like equity indices. As a result, insignificant differences in country-specific idiosyncratic skewness do not create significant differences in equity index pricing. Index investors' preferences for idiosyncratic skewness do not outweigh their aversion to idiosyncratic risk. Along with the findings of the momentum effects and more persistent idiosyncratic volatilities, our results suggest that different investment strategies should be adopted in forming global and domestic equity portfolios. 24 References Adler, M. & Dumas, D. (1983). International portfolio choice and corporate finance: A synthesis. Journal of Finance, 38, 925-984. Ahn, D., Boudoukh, J., Richardson, M., & Whitelaw, R. F. (2002). Partial adjustment or stale prices? Implications from stock index and futures return autocorrelations. Review of Financial Studies 15, 655-689. Ang, A., Hodrick, R. J., Xing, Y., & Zhang, X. (2006). The cross-section of volatility and expected returns. Journal of Finance 61, 259-299. Ang, A., Hodrick, R. J., Xing, Y., & Zhang, X. (2009). High idiosyncratic volatility and low returns: International and further U. S. evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 91, 1-23. Antoniou, A., Koutmos, G., & Pericli, A. (2005). Index futures and positive feedback trading: Evidence from major stock exchanges. Journal of Empirical Finance 12, 219- 238. Bali, T. G. & Cakici, N. (2008). Idiosyncratic volatility and the cross-section of expected returns. Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 43, 29-58. Bali, T.G. & Cakici, N. (2010). World market risk, country-specific risk and expected returns in international stock markets. Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 1152-1165. Barberis, N. & Huang, M. (2008). Stocks as lotteries: The implications of probability weighting for security prices. American Economic Review 98(5), 2066-2100. 25 Bekaert, G., R. J. Hodrick, and X. Zhang. 2009. International Stock Return Comovements. Journal of Finance 64, 2591-2626. Bhojraj, S. & Swaminathan, B. (2006). Macromomentum: Returns predictability in international equity indices. Journal of Business 79, 429-451. Boyer, B., Mitton, T., & Vorkink, K. (2010). Expected idiosyncratic skewness. Review of Financial Studies 23, 169-202. Brennan, M. & Cao, H. (1997). International portfolio investment flows. Journal of Finance 52, 1851-1880. Brockman, P., M.G. Schutte, and W. Yu. 2009. Is idiosyncratic risk priced? The international evidence. Working paper. Campbell, J.Y., Lettau, M., Malkiel, B.G., & Xu, Y. (2001). Have individual stocks become more volatile? An empirical exploration of idiosyncratic risk. Journal of Finance 56, 1-43. Driessen, J. & Laeven, L. (2007). International portfolio diversification benefits: Cross- country evidence from a local perspective. Journal of Banking and Finance 31, 1693-1712. Fama, E. & French, K. (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56. Foster, D. P., and D. B. Nelson. 1996. Continuous Record Asymptotics for Rolling Sample Variance Estimators. Econometrica 64:139–74. 26 Fu, F. (2009). Idiosyncratic risk and the cross-section of expected stock returns. Journal of Financial Economics 91, 24-37. Goetzmann, W.N. & Kumar, A. (2008). Equity portfolio diversification. Review of Finance 12, 433-463. Hansen, B. (1994). Autoregressive conditional density estimation. International Economic Review 35, 705-730. Henry, P. B. (2000). Stock market liberalization, economic reform, and emerging market equity prices. Journal of Finance 55, 529-564. Huang, W., Liu, Q., Rhee, S.G., & Zhang, L. (2010). Return reversals, idiosyncratic risk, and expected returns. Review of Financial Studies 23, 147-168. Hueng, C. J. & McDonald, J. B. (2005). Forecasting Asymmetries in Aggregate Stock Returns: Evidence from Conditional Skewness. Journal of Empirical Finance 12, 666-685. Hueng, C. J. & R. Yau. (2006). Investor’s Preference and Portfolio Selection: Is Diversification an Appropriate Strategy? Quantitative Finance 6 (3), 255-271. Levy, H. (1978). Equilibrium in an imperfect market: A constraint on the number of securities in the portfolio. American Economic Review 68, 643-658. Lewis, K. (2011). Global Asset Pricing. NBER Working Paper, No. 17261. Li, K., Sarkar, A., & Wang, Z. (2003). Diversification benefits of emerging markets subject to portfolio constraints. Journal of Empirical Finance 10, 57-80. 27 Lintner, J. (1965). Security prices, risk, and maximal gains from diversification. Journal of Finance 20, 587-615. Malkiel, B. G. G. & Xu, Y. (2006). Idiosyncratic Risk and Security Returns. Working paper. University of Texas at Dallas. Merton, R.C. (1987). A simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information. Journal of Finance 42, 483-510. Mitton T. & Vorkink, K. (2007). Equilibrium underdiversification and the preference for skewness. Review of Financial Studies 20, 1255-88. Newey, W. K. & West, K. D. (1987). A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 703-708. Sharpe, W. F. (1964). Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. Journal of Finance 19, 425-442. Spiegel, M. I. and X. Wang, 2005. Cross-sectional Variation in Stock Returns: Liquidity and Idiosyncratic Risk. Yale ICF Working Paper No. 05-13; EFA 2005 Moscow Meetings Paper. You, L. & Daigler, R. T. (2010). Is international diversification really beneficial? Journal of Banking and Finance 34, 163-173. 28 Table 1: Summary Statistics of International Market Indices (Monthly Data) The sample ends in November 2010 for all countries. The variable EP is the natural logarithm of the earnings-to-price ratio, and DY is the natural logarithm of the dividends-to-price ratio. The idiosyncratic volatility IVOLi ,t = Dt ∑ (r d =1 i , d ,t − ri ,d ,t ) , where the idiosyncratic shocks are estimated by 2 equation (2): Ri , d ,t = µi ,t + Betai ,t ⋅ Rw, d ,t + ri , d ,t . Country Data start Argentina Aug-93 Australia Jan-73 Austria Jan-73 Belgium Jan-73 Brazil Jul-94 Canada Jan-73 Chile Jul-89 China Jul-93 Denmark Jan-73 Finland Mar-88 France Jan-73 Germany Jan-73 Greece Jan-90 Hong Kong Jan-73 India Jan-90 Ireland Jan-73 Italy Jan-73 Japan Jan-73 Korea Sep-87 Malaysia Jan-86 Mexico May-89 Netherlands Jan-73 New Zealand Jan-88 Norway Jan-80 Philippines Nov-88 Poland Mar-94 Portugal Jan-90 Singapore Jan-73 South Africa Jan-73 Spain Mar-87 Sweden Jan-82 Switzerland Jan-73 Taiwan May-88 Thailand Jan-87 Turkey Jun-89 UK Jan-73 US Jan-73 WORLD Jan-73 Market Index Returns Correlation Mean Std with WORLD 0.817 9.213 0.531 1.145 7.215 0.643 1.044 6.705 0.502 1.027 5.897 0.677 1.751 10.914 0.674 0.994 5.526 0.757 1.721 6.610 0.442 1.752 11.246 0.397 1.160 5.888 0.607 1.152 8.630 0.661 1.165 6.743 0.719 0.984 5.939 0.705 1.035 10.141 0.463 1.473 9.999 0.525 1.520 10.703 0.342 1.075 7.269 0.666 0.944 7.588 0.561 0.797 6.234 0.708 1.055 11.189 0.552 1.314 8.789 0.431 1.724 8.733 0.594 1.123 5.521 0.820 0.912 6.478 0.619 1.223 7.953 0.659 1.222 9.217 0.473 1.003 10.906 0.594 0.658 6.093 0.653 1.076 8.483 0.634 1.362 8.282 0.558 0.978 6.496 0.774 1.407 7.301 0.738 1.060 5.137 0.717 0.964 10.994 0.439 1.564 10.814 0.520 2.567 16.935 0.380 1.115 6.524 0.732 0.936 4.477 0.816 0.901 4.481 1.000 29 DY EP Beta IVOL 0.872 1.371 0.612 1.264 0.948 1.052 1.191 1.022 0.615 0.882 1.262 0.909 0.946 1.247 0.345 1.251 0.968 0.120 0.588 0.967 0.615 1.383 1.545 0.888 0.251 0.463 1.056 0.912 1.306 1.107 0.907 0.720 0.545 1.012 1.069 1.414 1.069 --- -2.571 -2.804 -2.798 -2.539 -2.284 -2.657 -2.733 -3.269 -2.754 -2.775 -2.634 -2.600 -2.705 -2.764 -3.064 -2.753 -2.830 -3.480 -2.666 -2.902 -2.487 -2.441 -2.639 -2.365 -2.732 -3.085 -2.989 -2.754 -2.738 -2.643 -2.845 -2.532 -3.073 -2.518 -2.779 -3.169 -2.730 --- 0.792 0.532 0.571 0.669 1.277 0.776 0.543 0.714 0.579 1.109 0.875 0.858 0.684 0.650 0.381 0.700 0.719 0.981 0.666 0.458 0.998 0.865 0.458 0.886 0.397 0.931 0.624 0.532 0.704 0.949 0.996 0.724 0.510 0.569 0.844 0.915 0.958 1.000 6.244 4.866 3.702 3.707 6.464 2.904 4.204 7.366 4.221 5.797 4.094 3.618 6.496 6.358 6.685 4.454 4.985 3.976 8.165 5.176 5.363 3.437 4.756 5.382 6.156 7.070 3.808 4.998 5.845 3.945 4.904 3.503 7.575 7.268 11.515 3.832 2.468 --- Table 2: Cross-Sectional Regressions This table reports the cross-sectional regression results for (3): Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t IVOLi ,t −1 + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t . The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Constant IVOLi ,t −1 0.761 0.106 (0.004) (0.034) Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 Avg. R2 0.113 0.696 0.109 0.087 (0.025) (0.024) (0.596) 0.188 2.440 0.125 0.645 (0.000) (0.022) (0.000) 0.194 0.336 0.098 0.404 (0.309) (0.042) (0.010) 2.511 0.144 0.092 0.708 (0.000) (0.005) (0.553) (0.000) 0.282 0.109 0.091 (0.421) (0.025) (0.575) 2.596 0.143 0.099 0.723 -0.009 (0.001) (0.006) (0.527) (0.001) (0.967) 0.171 0.274 0.371 0.244 (0.027) 30 0.329 Table 3: First-Order Autocorrelation Coefficients and the Augmented Dickey-Fuller t-test Statistics for Monthly Realized Idiosyncratic Volatility ADF-t is the Augmented Dickey-Fuller t-statistic. The asterisk * indicates that the test fails to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root at the 1% significance level. Country Argentina Australia Austria Belgium Brazil Canada Chile China Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hong Kong India Ireland Italy Japan Korea Malaysia Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Philippines Poland Portugal Singapore South Africa Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan Thailand Turkey UK US 1st-order autocorrelation 0.525 0.510 0.617 0.464 0.594 0.528 0.504 0.618 0.410 0.689 0.532 0.427 0.621 0.580 0.426 0.429 0.609 0.670 0.722 0.668 0.619 0.579 0.444 0.528 0.403 0.577 0.495 0.604 0.454 0.487 0.525 0.473 0.670 0.620 0.555 0.660 0.600 31 ADF-t -6.293 -9.339 -4.380 -4.401 -4.305 -7.108 -6.429 -2.043* -5.088 -3.159* -5.652 -3.829* -3.280* -6.172 -6.360 -4.152 -4.525 -3.597* -5.054 -2.973* -3.679* -4.478 -5.226 -6.237 -3.839* -4.210 -3.247* -4.413 -7.788 -5.130 -3.877* -6.974 -3.171* -3.195* -3.580* -4.964 -4.648 Table 4: Cross-Sectional Regressions This table reports the cross-sectional regression results for (3'): Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t Eˆ t −1 IVOLi ,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t . The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Constant Eˆ t −1 IVOLi ,t 0.685 0.098 (0.020) (0.008) Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 Avg. R2 0.109 0.552 0.095 0.189 (0.092) (0.013) (0.308) 0.186 2.167 0.081 0.518 (0.000) (0.071) (0.000) 0.194 0.217 0.095 0.430 (0.526) (0.007) (0.004) 1.866 0.099 0.184 0.489 (0.002) (0.031) (0.301) (0.000) 0.271 0.066 0.099 0.219 0.408 (0.853) (0.009) (0.230) (0.006) 1.628 0.092 0.235 0.449 0.142 (0.053) (0.048) (0.185) (0.016) (0.396) 32 0.166 0.240 0.326 Table 5: Estimation Results from the AR-EGARCH(1,1) Model This table presents the key estimation results from the model: ri ,t = α 0i + ∑ α ij ri ,t − j + ε i ,t , j ln hi ,t = κ i + α i ⋅ ln hi ,t −1 + β i ⋅ ε i ,t −1 hi ,t −1 +γi ⋅ ε i ,t −1 hi ,t −1 + ⋅ I i+,t −1 , ε i ,t = hi ,t vi ,t , vi ,t ~ N (0,1) , and I i ,t = 1 if ε i ,t >0 and Ii+,t = 0 otherwise. The numbers in parentheses are P-values. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Country Argentina Australia Austria Belgium Brazil Canada Chile China Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hong Kong India Ireland Italy Japan κ β α γ -0.001 0.954 -0.321 0.445 (0.994) (0.000) (0.001) (0.023) -0.089 0.995 -0.170 0.263 (0.007) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) -0.045 0.932 -0.338 0.700 (0.639) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) -0.079 0.950 -0.351 0.555 (0.276) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 0.523 0.786 -0.606 0.731 (0.083) (0.000) (0.001) (0.012) 1.756 0.257 -0.096 0.363 (0.026) (0.398) (0.395) (0.054) -0.032 0.961 -0.215 0.404 (0.715) (0.000) (0.021) (0.015) -0.094 0.948 -0.327 0.796 (0.548) (0.000) (0.008) (0.001) 0.058 0.932 -0.213 0.358 (0.578) (0.000) (0.004) (0.002) -0.131 0.979 -0.271 0.521 (0.083) (0.000) (0.002) (0.000) -0.115 0.990 -0.195 0.363 (0.003) (0.000) (0.002) (0.002) -0.044 0.972 -0.131 0.317 (0.349) (0.000) (0.023) (0.004) -0.101 0.962 -0.348 0.616 (0.195) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) -0.054 0.930 -0.467 0.819 (0.518) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 0.102 0.947 -0.119 0.364 (0.574) (0.000) (0.156) (0.023) -0.105 0.976 -0.273 0.468 (0.024) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) -0.116 0.988 -0.203 0.413 (0.004) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 2.111 0.172 -0.425 0.823 (0.003) (0.466) (0.002) (0.000) 33 Mean of 7.438 5.197 5.256 4.202 7.162 3.599 5.577 9.736 4.443 6.180 4.401 4.107 7.254 6.980 9.533 5.132 5.956 4.370 hi ,t Table 5 (continued): Estimation Results for the AR-EGARCH (1,1) Model Country Korea Malaysia Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Philippines Poland Portugal Singapore South Africa Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan Thailand Turkey UK US κ β α γ -0.017 0.988 -0.243 0.158 (0.745) (0.000) (0.000) (0.125) -0.139 0.951 -0.420 0.778 (0.073) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) -0.109 1.000 -0.095 0.253 (0.133) (0.000) (0.613) (0.361) 0.025 0.925 -0.157 0.376 (0.795) (0.000) (0.016) (0.003) 2.497 0.217 0.032 -0.098 (0.315) (0.780) (0.847) (0.662) -0.057 0.980 -0.132 0.311 (0.386) (0.000) (0.024) (0.004) -0.077 0.988 -0.213 0.312 (0.340) (0.000) (0.008) (0.014) 5.513 -0.477 -0.546 1.035 (0.000) (0.007) (0.011) (0.005) 0.010 0.960 -0.123 0.283 (0.922) (0.000) (0.126) (0.038) -0.125 0.967 -0.329 0.614 (0.026) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) -0.037 0.982 -0.164 0.264 (0.585) (0.000) (0.006) (0.014) 0.021 0.959 -0.228 0.238 (0.759) (0.000) (0.000) (0.012) 0.078 0.919 -0.187 0.443 (0.745) (0.000) (0.181) (0.086) -0.077 0.950 -0.221 0.494 (0.246) (0.000) (0.002) (0.000) -0.115 1.004 -0.165 0.235 (0.007) (0.000) (0.021) (0.013) -0.045 0.986 -0.182 0.252 (0.429) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) -0.098 1.008 -0.153 0.124 (0.005) (0.000) (0.002) (0.008) -0.114 0.995 -0.248 0.318 (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.003) -0.138 0.977 -0.323 0.473 (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) 34 Mean of hi ,t 7.811 6.612 6.318 3.143 4.819 5.501 7.700 7.602 4.554 5.886 6.738 3.929 4.774 3.516 8.385 8.747 14.001 3.814 2.485 Table 6: Cross-Sectional Regressions This table reports the results for (3''): Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t hi ,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t . The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Constant hi ,t 0.440 0.144 (0.134) (0.004) Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 Avg. R2 0.120 0.379 0.130 0.206 (0.240) (0.011) (0.188) 0.196 2.299 0.127 0.659 (0.000) (0.016) (0.000) 0.210 0.083 0.117 0.427 (0.802) (0.015) (0.012) 2.133 0.136 0.246 0.670 (0.000) (0.010) (0.107) (0.000) 0.002 0.114 0.218 (0.995) (0.027) (0.166) 1.701 0.130 0.257 0.564 0.200 (0.015) (0.013) (0.108) (0.005) (0.215) 0.176 0.290 0.404 0.248 (0.018) 35 0.340 Table 7: Cross-Sectional Regressions Panel (A) reports the cross-sectional regression results for (3) with the lagged return added; Panel (B) reports the results for (3') with the lagged return added; and Panel (C) reports the results for (3'') with the lagged return added. The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) tstatistics. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Constant Panel (A) Panel (B) Panel (C) IVOLi ,t −1 Eˆ t −1 IVOLi ,t hi ,t Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 Ri ,t −1 Avg. R2 0.186 0.724 0.084 0.047 (0.005) (0.082) (0.011) 0.653 0.086 0.010 0.059 (0.025) (0.074) (0.950) (0.001) 2.796 0.104 0.780 0.056 (0.000) (0.026) (0.000) (0.002) 0.298 0.078 0.397 0.049 (0.305) (0.101) (0.001) (0.010) 2.723 0.115 0.007 0.781 0.064 (0.000) (0.017) (0.970) (0.000) (0.000) 0.287 0.086 0.019 0.319 0.059 (0.378) (0.081) (0.903) (0.027) (0.001) 3.000 0.106 0.019 0.818 -0.135 0.059 (0.000) (0.041) (0.920) (0.000) (0.516) (0.001) 0.611 0.094 0.043 (0.019) (0.005) (0.012) 0.475 0.096 0.086 0.053 (0.098) (0.009) (0.613) (0.003) 2.079 0.076 0.514 0.050 (0.000) (0.031) (0.001) (0.006) 0.129 0.093 0.440 0.047 (0.675) (0.004) (0.002) (0.011) 1.743 0.113 0.017 0.465 0.056 (0.006) (0.006) (0.930) (0.011) (0.005) -0.006 0.104 0.102 0.407 0.053 (0.985) (0.005) (0.536) (0.005) (0.004) 1.882 0.111 0.081 0.522 0.013 0.047 (0.020) (0.010) (0.693) (0.014) (0.943) (0.023) 0.443 0.116 0.038 (0.100) (0.016) (0.033) 0.330 0.109 0.166 0.046 (0.268) (0.036) (0.295) (0.007) 2.362 0.104 0.669 0.043 (0.000) (0.037) (0.000) (0.020) 0.109 0.096 0.388 0.035 (0.734) (0.052) (0.012) (0.055) 2.141 0.114 0.230 0.668 0.057 (0.000) (0.030) (0.101) (0.000) (0.001) 0.046 0.090 0.167 0.339 0.040 (0.897) (0.104) (0.253) (0.035) (0.019) 1.914 0.096 0.213 0.597 0.142 0.052 (0.006) (0.068) (0.137) (0.006) (0.277) (0.004) 36 0.253 0.280 0.241 0.348 0.305 0.395 0.187 0.255 0.285 0.240 0.352 0.305 0.399 0.194 0.260 0.293 0.246 0.357 0.309 0.401 Table 8: Forecasting Idiosyncratic Skewness This table reports, for horizons T = 1, 6, 12, 24, and 60, the time-series averages of the estimated coefficients, their P-values (in parentheses) based on Newey and West (1987) tstatistics, and the time-series averages of R2 from cross-sectional regression (6): ISK i ,t = β 0,t + β1,t ISK i ,t −T + β 2,t IVOLi ,t −T + υ i ,t . Horizons T=1 T=6 T = 12 T = 24 T = 60 Constant ISK i ,t −T IVOLi ,t −T Avg. R2 0.117 0.003 0.013 0.001 (0.391) (0.460) (0.166) -0.001 0.033 -3*10-5 (0.817) (0.309) (0.940) -0.001 0.043 -7*10-5 (0.785) (0.382) (0.773) 0.004 0.161 -3*10-4 (0.386) (0.130) (0.171) 0.006 0.201 -2*10-4 (0.096) (0.125) (0.074) 37 0.156 0.145 0.145 0.204 Table 9: Cross-Sectional Regressions This table reports the cross-sectional regression results for the following model: Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t hi′,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + γ 5,t ski ,t −1 + γ 6,t Ri ,t −1 + ε i ,t . The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics. A P-value of 0.000 indicates that the P-value is nonzero, but smaller than 0.0005. Variables Constant Panel (A) 0.524 h′ 0.128 (0.065) (0.010) 0.431 0.119 0.213 -0.038 (0.156) (0.025) (0.185) (0.825) Panel (B) Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 ski ,t −1 Ri ,t −1 0.008 Avg. R2 0.176 (0.963) 2.308 0.118 0.644 0.052 (0.000) (0.028) (0.002) (0.818) 0.100 0.085 0.522 0.197 (0.767) (0.089) (0.003) (0.275) 2.077 0.136 0.326 0.663 0.073 (0.000) (0.013) (0.049) (0.000) (0.747) -0.004 0.083 0.216 0.504 0.179 (0.990) (0.109) (0.188) (0.004) (0.303) 1.327 0.126 0.391 0.487 0.298 0.128 (0.092) (0.024) (0.023) (0.030) (0.040) (0.587) 0.247 0.274 0.227 0.348 0.295 0.396 0.381 0.102 0.168 -0.088 0.057 (0.179) (0.049) (0.259) (0.581) (0.001) 2.294 0.094 0.630 0.040 0.062 (0.000) (0.038) (0.002) (0.840) (0.001) 0.176 0.063 0.451 0.123 0.048 (0.580) (0.225) (0.009) (0.439) (0.007) 2.111 0.120 0.312 0.696 0.133 0.073 (0.000) (0.011) (0.018) (0.000) (0.535) (0.000) 0.111 0.059 0.157 0.390 0.095 0.052 (0.757) (0.317) (0.287) (0.027) (0.534) (0.004) 1.539 0.098 0.361 0.552 0.251 0.156 0.069 (0.041) (0.056) (0.015) (0.014) (0.058) (0.467) (0.000) 38 0.309 0.349 0.295 0.410 0.354 0.455 Table 10: Realized Idiosyncratic Skewness The idiosyncratic skewness ISK i ,t = ∑ (r d∈S ( t ) i , d ,t − ri , d ,t ) 3 IVOL3i ,t , where S(t) is the set of trading days from the first day of month t-T+1 through the end of month t and the idiosyncratic shocks are estimated by equation (2): Ri , d ,t = µi ,t + Betai ,t ⋅ Rw, d ,t + ri , d ,t . Horizon Argentina Australia Austria Belgium Brazil Canada Chile China Denmark Finland France Germany Greece Hong Kong India Ireland Italy Japan Korea Malaysia Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Philippines Poland Portugal Singapore South Africa Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan Thailand Turkey UK US Average T=1 T=6 T=12 T=24 T=60 0.017 -0.001 -0.003 0.012 0.013 0.000 0.020 0.036 0.007 -0.009 0.009 0.003 0.029 0.006 -0.009 0.007 0.016 0.019 0.018 0.030 -0.001 0.007 -0.002 0.016 0.017 0.011 0.021 0.028 0.007 -0.013 0.012 0.003 0.028 0.037 0.010 -0.004 0.010 0.011 0.001 -0.012 -0.008 0.003 0.012 -0.010 0.009 0.021 0.004 -0.018 0.000 -0.006 0.014 -0.016 0.000 -0.002 -0.002 0.016 0.007 0.006 0.012 0.000 -0.007 0.000 0.020 0.005 0.008 0.006 -0.011 -0.011 -0.001 0.003 0.008 0.011 0.008 -0.002 0.004 0.002 -0.005 -0.015 -0.008 0.002 0.007 -0.010 0.005 0.015 0.001 -0.016 -0.002 -0.009 0.008 -0.026 0.003 -0.002 -0.004 0.014 0.008 -0.001 0.009 -0.003 -0.009 -0.004 0.021 0.003 0.005 0.002 -0.013 -0.010 -0.003 0.000 0.005 0.004 0.008 -0.002 0.004 -0.0005 -0.013 -0.015 -0.006 0.000 0.004 -0.008 0.002 0.011 0.002 -0.014 -0.003 -0.007 0.005 -0.031 0.001 0.000 -0.004 0.014 0.010 -0.005 0.005 -0.003 -0.010 -0.005 0.025 0.002 0.002 0.000 -0.011 -0.007 -0.002 -0.001 0.003 0.000 0.006 0.000 0.005 -0.001 -0.020 -0.013 -0.002 0.001 0.005 -0.006 0.002 0.007 0.005 -0.009 -0.003 -0.005 0.003 -0.030 -0.003 -0.002 -0.003 0.012 0.013 -0.004 0.002 -0.001 -0.008 -0.004 0.025 0.001 0.000 -0.001 -0.008 -0.004 0.000 -0.001 0.002 0.004 0.004 -0.001 0.003 -0.001 39 Table 11: Cross-Sectional Regressions This table reports the regression results of (3''): Ri ,t = γ 0,t + γ 1,t hi ,t + γ 2,t Betai ,t −1 + γ 3,t EPi ,t −1 + γ 4,t DYi ,t −1 + ε i ,t , with hi ,t estimated from the following models: (i) AR-EGARCH-ARCD model - time-varying skewness parameter. (ii) AR-EGARCH-ST model - constant skewness parameter. (iii) AR-EGARCH-t model - zero skewness, i.e., AR-EGARCH model with a t-distribution. The average intercepts, average slope coefficients, and average R2 are presented. The numbers in parentheses are P-values calculated based on Newey and West (1987) t-statistics. Models (i) (ii) (iii) Constant hi ,t Betai ,t −1 EPi ,t −1 DYi ,t −1 Avg. R2 1.498 0.133 0.241 0.503 0.221 0.343 (0.029) (0.006) (0.147) (0.010) (0.203) 1.603 0.143 0.260 0.554 0.201 (0.023) (0.005) (0.125) (0.006) (0.213) 1.600 0.148 0.253 0.561 0.200 (0.023) (0.004) (0.146) (0.005) (0.235) 40 0.339 0.340