Unemployment Duration and the Interactions Between Unemployment Insurance and Social Assistance∗ Michele Pellizzari† March, 2005 Abstract Existing studies of unemployment benefits and unemployment duration suggest that reforms that lower either the level or the duration of benefits should reduce unemployment. Despite the large number of such reforms implemented in Europe in the past decades, this paper presents evidence that shows no correlation between the reforms and the evolution of unemployment. This paper also suggests an explanation for this fact by exploring the interactions between unemployment benefits and social assistance programmes. Unemployed workers who are also eligible for some social assistance programmes should be less concerned about their benefits being reduced or terminated. Data from the European Community Household Panel are used to provide evidence to support this argument by exploiting variation in a particular feature of family cash benefits, which are universal in some European countries and means-tested in others. Comparing similar persons subject to different family assistance schemes shows significant differences in the elasticity of the probability of finding employment to both the generosity and the duration of the unemployment benefit. Keywords: Unemployment duration, unemployment insurance, social assistance, duration models. JEL Codes: J64, J65 1 Introduction The effect of unemployment insurance (UI) on unemployment duration is the object of many studies in a rather large literature. Two empirical findings are now widely accepted. First, ∗ I would like to thank Tito Boeri, Marco Leonardi, Alan Manning, Steve Pischke, Federico Perali and Bar- bara Petrongolo for useful comments and suggestions. This paper has received useful comments from seminar participants at the IZA Summer School, CEP-London School of Economics and University of Verona. Financial support from the ESRC, Bocconi University, the Centre for Economic Performance and the University of Verona is gratefully acknowledged. All errors are my own responsibility. † IGIER-Bocconi University, IZA, CEP and fRDB. Contact address: michele.pellizzari@unibocconi.it 1 as initially showed by Nickell [1979] and Lancaster [1979], higher benefits are associated with longer unemployment spells. Later, Moffit [1985] and Meyer [1990], having access to information about both the level and the duration of benefit entitlement at the individual level, were able to show a second important empirical finding, that the probability of exiting unemployment increases around the time of benefit exhaustion. The literature also provides a comprehensive theoretical framework for interpreting these results. Mortensen [1977] develops a simple search model that easily delivers negative correlation between exit rates and unemployment benefits via search effort and reservation wages being respectively negatively and positively affected by income out of work. When UI entitlement expires, income out of work suddenly drops, inducing an instantaneous increase in search effort and a decrease in the reservation wage, thus providing an explanation for the observed higher exits rates around the time of exhaustion. Cahuc et al. [2000] recently extended the model by endogenising wages and allowing the unemployment benefit to gradually decline over time. On the basis of these findings, one would expect reforms that reduce either the level or the duration of unemployment benefits to have a positive impact on the unemployment rate. However, this prediction does not seem to conform with the recent experience of many European countries. Figure 1 plots the time series of the unemployment rate for selected European countries. The vertical lines indicate the implementation years of reforms that have modified either the level or the duration of the unemployment benefits. The solid bars refer to changes in the amount of the benefits and the dashed lines to changes in their duration. The thickness of the lines indicate the direction of the change: thick for reductions (either in the amount or duration of benefits) and thin for increases. A first simple fact is evident from Figure 1: the past 20 years have been constellated by labour market reforms in virtually all European countries. Moreover, despite the coexistence in many countries of reforms of opposite sign, often implemented close to each other (in Finland and France, for example), most of the changes (19 out of 29) modified the system towards less generous benefits paid for a shorter time. However, already a simple visual inspection of Figure 1 suggests that the correlation between these reforms and the evolution of unemployment is rather weak. 2 More convincing evidence can be produced for those countries where reforms took place during the years covered by the European Community Household Panel (ECHP)1 . This is possible for seven countries: Austria, Belgium, Finland, Germany, Greece, Ireland and the United Kingdom. Table 1 shows the conditional difference in the probability of finding employment between individuals who entered unemployment before and after the reform. The estimates are produced with a standard hazard model controlling for gender, age, health status, education, marital status, family size, presence of children, household income and regional unemployment2 . Results confirm the visual impression from Figure 1: reforms that reduced the level or the duration of unemployment benefits did not have a significant effect on the probability of finding a job. There are marginally significant effects only in Austria (where the estimate is actually negative) and Ireland. The scarce success of labour market reforms in Europe has been acknowledged by other authors as well, for example Coe et al. [1997] and Orszag et al. [1999]. This papers suggests an explanation for the failure of so many reforms of the unemployment compensation system. European countries all have complex welfare states and unemployment compensation is only one element of the system that necessarily interacts in various ways with all the other programmes. In particular, many unemployed persons receive other social assistance benefits together with their unemployment insurance. Most of these other benefits are means-tested, therefore a reduction or an anticipated withdrawal of unemployment insurance is often compensated, at least partly, by higher transfers from other programmes. Moreover, even those unemployed who only receive unemployment insurance may still expect to become eligible for some social assistance programmes when their benefits expire. For these workers, too, reductions or exhaustion of unemployment insurance are less of a concern and do not affect much their search effort nor their reservation wages. These arguments will be tested empirically using data from the European Community Household Panel, which allow to reconstruct monthly labour market histories for samples of individuals from all EU countries. Contrary to most studies in this literature that use data from administrative sources, this paper exploits survey data which have two main 1 2 The data are described in details in Section 4. A fuller description of the econometric model is provided in Section 6. 3 advantages. First, the ECHP contains information on numerous types of social transfers and thus permits to identify UI recipients who are also entitled to other social assistance programmes. Second, by relying on self-reported information about one’s labour market status it is possible to reconstruct unemployment spells that end into employment and into inactivity separately. Hence, I will be able to estimate the probability of finding a job rather than that of leaving unemployment or the UI registry. This is an important innovation: in the largest sample used in this study exits into inactivity represent about 15% of total exits from unemployment. However, using survey rather than administrative sources necessarily lowers the quality of the data on UI payments and durations. In particular, the total amount of UI benefits received by each individual in the ECHP is only recorded annually (not monthly) and the duration of payments is not known. This is solved by imputing benefit entitlements on the basis of individual characteristics available from the ECHP and institutional information about the functioning of the welfare system in each country and year. Moreover, the ECHP, by providing data that are highly comparable across countries, allows to use variation in the administrative rules of the welfare systems to identify causal effects. In particular, the institutional features of family cash benefits offer an interesting source of variation. In 10 out of the 15 pre-enlargement EU countries eligibility for family benefits is determined only by the number and the age of the children in the household, regardless of income. Only in the remaining 5 countries - Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain - family benefits are subject to means testing. This paper exploits this variation to identify the differential effect of unemployment benefits on the job finding probabilities of potential recipients of family benefits. Intuitively, in countries where family benefits are means tested, UI recipients who are potentially eligible for child assistance will be less worried about reductions or withdrawal of their benefits, as these could be compensated by higher social assistance payments. In countries were family benefits are ”universal”, i.e. not means tested, there should be no such interaction effect. Results indicate significant differences in the elasticity of the job finding probability to the unemployment benefit and to the time of benefit exhaustion between male heads of households with children subject to means tested versus universal family benefits. 4 The importance of interactions between welfare programmes has lately been recognised by both academicians and policy makers. Belot and van Ours [2000] provide evidence from macro data showing that countries where unemployment has fallen often owe their success to comprehensive rather than piecewise reforms of labour market policies. A theoretical justification for the importance of these interactions is discussed in Coe et al. [1997] within a search and matching framework. Despite the acknowledged importance of potential overlappings between welfare programmes, specific evidence from micro data is still lacking. This paper aims at filling this gap by providing detailed evidence on one specific interaction. The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 briefly describes the institutional details of unemployment benefits and other social assistance programmes in Europe. Section 3 shows how interactions between welfare programmes can be analysed in a standard search model. Section 4 describes the data while Section 5 discusses the empirical strategy. The results of the empirical analysis of re-employment probabilities are presented in Section 6. Section 7 concludes. 2 Unemployment Compensation and Social Assistance in Europe 2.1 Institutional Framework All European countries have large and well developed welfare states, nevertheless there still exist important differences in the institutional details across countries. The comparison of different types of welfare states in Europe has been the object of a large number of studies in both the economic and the political literature3 . This section simply aims at providing a very general overview of the welfare programmes available in the European countries during the period covered by the empirical analysis that follows. Excluding old age pensions (which are still the major component of social expenditure in many countries), welfare benefits are generally grouped into 5 large categories: unemployment related benefits, family cash benefits, invalidity benefits/pensions, housing benefits and 3 Bertola et. al [2000], Esping-Andersen [1990], Ferrera [1998]. 5 general social assistance. In kind benefits are not considered here, even if they might play an important role for some groups of beneficiaries (disabled persons, large families, et.). Unemployment benefits are generally distinguished into unemployment insurance and unemployment assistance. Unemployment insurance is a rather standard insurance scheme by which workers who have paid sufficient contributions out of their salaries are allowed to receive a compensation if they become unemployed. Unemployment insurance is usually rather generous but benefits are typically paid only for a limited period of time (with Belgium, where the duration of payments is unlimited, being a notable exception) and various reeligibility conditions apply for repeated spells of unemployment. Clearly then, unemployment insurance does not cover the whole population of jobseekers: young workers - and anybody who has not paid enough contributions - and the long term unemployed - who have exhausted their benefits - cannot claim the benefit. For this reason many countries have introduced a parallel unemployment assistance programme that pays a (typically lower) benefit to those who, for any reason, are not entitled to unemployment insurance. Along with these general characteristics, the details of the unemployment benefit schemes vary widely across European countries. Invalidity benefits are another important component of the welfare system and often take the form of pensions. The typical scheme pays a benefit to individuals whose capacity to work and earn is substantially reduced by some sort of invalidity. Almost all countries also require some kind of contribution conditions. There are few exceptions to this general rule: in the Netherlands there is no qualifying conditions while in Finland and Sweden the main conditions relate to residence in the country rather than to contribution records. The level of the benefit is usually determined on the basis of a measure of ”normalised” earnings, i.e. earnings of a similar person who does not suffer from the invalidity. In some countries invalidity benefits also vary with age but payments are always carried over to retirement, at which point an invalidity pension is typically converted into an old age pension. Family cash benefits are the most important welfare programme that is not related to employment. In the majority of countries (10 out of 15) family benefits are actually paid to any household with children, regardless of their income. These benefits are paid until the child reaches a certain age and the amount varies according to the child’s age and to 6 the number of children in the household. Some countries also offer supplements for single parents. Children who undertake higher education or training are often allowed to receive benefits for some additional years above the age limit. The provision of housing benefits is more varied. Some countries offer a generalised housing benefit available to everyone whose income is sufficiently low (Germany, France, Netherlands, Finland) while others simply provide specific housing supplements for those on low-income benefits (Ireland, Luxembourg, Austria and Portugal). Denmark and Sweden have both. Some countries do not offer any housing benefit but often social housing is available for low income families. Finally, all countries, with the exception of Greece and Italy4 , also provide a general social assistance scheme that aims at preventing poverty for those individuals or families who do not qualify for any of the other ”categorical” benefit or who still remain under a variously defined income threshold. Qualifying conditions for this type of assistance are usually related to nationality, residence and age. All countries also require those who are able to work to prove that they are actually willing to take up job offers and beneficiaries are often required to participate in training or other active labour market programmes. Synthetic tables that summarise the details of welfare programmes in the European countries can be found in Appendix B. 2.2 Welfare Reforms in Europe Table 2 presents a more complete description of the reforms indicated in Figure 1, including additional details on changes in social assistance programmes as well. In the past two decades policy makers have apparently been listening to economists as many reforms have actually changed the unemployment compensation system in the direction of lower benefits paid for shorter periods. Much less effort has been put in reforming other welfare programmes and one of the main claims of this paper will be that the scarce success of UI reforms is partly due to the lack of coordination with other parts of the welfare system. 4 A minimum income scheme was experimented in Italy between 1998 and 2002 (Reddito Minimo d’Inserimento) but was never introduced on a universal basis. 7 Looking at Table 2 some notable facts emerge. First, in the effort to reduce unemployment in the recession of the early 90s, there has been a clustering of reforms between 1992 and 1996. Secondly, the large majority of reforms clearly focused on unemployment insurance and have typically taken the form of reduction of either the duration or the level of the benefits. Many countries have also tightened eligibility conditions or strengthened work requirements for the unemployed. Only few reforms addressed other welfare programmes and even fewer tried to comprehensively change several programmes at the same time (Germany in 1998, Ireland in 1993, the United Kingdom in 1996). 3 A simple theoretical framework The interaction between unemployment benefits and social assistance can be analysed in the framework of a very standard search model. The theory in this section is a mere revised and simplified version of that in Mortensen [1977]. In each period t, an unemployed worker needs to invest leisure time (st ) to search for job offers. These arrive with per-period probability αst , where α is a constant, from an exogenous wage distribution F (·) with support (0, w]. In each period utility is a non-decreasing function of income (yt ) and leisure (lt ), u(yt , lt )5 . For simplicity, assume that working time is constant and equal to h in all jobs and that the total endowment of leisure is normalised to 1. Then, per-period utility while unemployed with benefit bt and searching for a job is u(bt , 1 − st ), while a job that pays wt generates a utility flow equal to u(wt , 1 − h). Unemployed workers also need to choose a reservation wage wt∗ : only wage offers above wt∗ are accepted, all the others are turned down. Under these assumptions the value of unemployment U at time t can be written as: (1 + r)Ut = u(bt , 1 − st ) + αst [Pr {w < wt∗ } Ut+1 + Pr {w ≥ wt∗ } E {V (w)|w ≥ wt∗ }] (1) where V (w) is the value of employment at wage w. For simplicity assume that there is 5 The per-period utility satisfies the standard assumptions, i.e. twice differentiable with: ∂u(y,l) ∂l > 0 and ∂u(y,l) ∂y∂y ≤ 0, ∂u(y,l) ∂l∂l ≤ 0. 8 ∂u(y,l) ∂y > 0, no job destruction: once workers enter employment they stay in the job forever at constant wage6 . Equation (1) can be rewritten as: (1 + r)Ut = u(bt , 1 − st ) + [1 − αst (1 − F (wt∗ ))] Ut+1 + αst Zw V (w)dF (w) (2) wt∗ The optimal levels of wt∗ and st are then chosen in order to maximise equation (2), according to the following first order conditions: V (wt∗ ) = Ut+1 ⎤ ⎡ Zw ∂u(bt , 1 − st ) ⎥ ⎢ = α ⎣ V (w)dF (w) − (1 − F (wt∗ ))Ut+1 ⎦ ∂st (3) (4) wt∗ The interpretation of these two conditions is very intuitive. Equation (3) shows that the optimal reservation wage is set at a level that equalises the value of employment and unemployment. An unemployed worker can allocate time to two different activities, search and leisure, hence optimal search time equalises the marginal utilities of search and leisure, as shown in equation (4). Note that both st and wt∗ are time-varying: equations (3) and (4) hold for all t and, for any known sequence of benefits, {bt }∞ 0 , identify a series of reserva- ∞ tion wages, {wt∗ }∞ 0 , and optimal search times, {st }0 . The per-period probability of exiting unemployment - the hazard rate - is then calculated as: qt = αst · [1 − F (wt∗ )] (5) These results are useful to analyse the implications of different assumptions about the sequence of benefits for the exit rate. Equation (5) shows that the exit rate is higher when job search is more intense and when the reservation wage is lower, i.e. when unemployed workers are less choosy about wage offers. 6 In this case: V (w, h) = ∞ X u(w, h) (1 + r)j j=t Introducing exogenous job destruction does not modify the empirical implications of the model. 9 Let us now analyse how search time, reservation wages and exit rates look like for different time profiles of the benefit. Unemployment benefit without social assistance Consider the standard case of an unemployed worker who receives a constant unemployment benefit (b) for a given number of periods, T , and nothing after that (this is the specific case discussed in Mortensen [1977]). For such worker the value of unemployment decreases over time as periods of positive benefit payments run out and expected future income out of work decreases, i.e. Ut+1 < Ut . Equation (3) implies that the reservation wage also decreases over time. Similarly, the right hand side of equation (4) increases with time (the value of unemployment enters with a negative sign and the derivative with respect to wt∗ , given equation (3), is zero7 ), therefore in order for the equality to hold the left hand side must increase as well and this can only be achieved with higher st , i.e. search time also increases with time. At time T , when unemployment benefit entitlement expires, bt discontinuously drops to zero. This requires the reservation wage to jump down and optimal search time to jump up. Note incidentally that for these effects to be non-ambiguous leisure and income must be complements (i.e. u21 (bt , 1 − st ) ≤ 0). These results are represented in Figure 2. Unemployment Benefit and Social Assistance The previous analysis can be easily extended to a worker who receives social assistance together with his/her unemployment benefit, or, similarly, to somebody who expects to become eligible for some social assistance programmes once his/her unemployment insurance expires. Eventually all changes from one scheme to another simply generate jumps in the time profile of the benefit and can be analysed within the same framework used for understanding exhaustion of unemployment benefits in the previous paragraph. It may for example be the case that, given the particular rules and household composition of applicants, family cash benefits top up household income once unemployment insurance 7 The derivative with respect to wt∗ of the right hand side of equation (4) is: ∂RHS = α [V (wt∗ ) − Ut+1 ] ∂wt which is zero at the optimum. 10 expires, leaving the time profile of benefit payments flat. In this case the model predicts no discontinuous jumps in reservation wage, search effort and exit rate, which will all remain constant throughout the entire unemployment spell. In other instances it might happen that payments under social assistance are actually higher than under unemployment insurance. This possibility, although rare, can occur in some countries where social assistance is particularly generous (see OECD [2002]). In such an extreme case the value of unemployment increases with time and all the effects derived previously are reversed, as shown in Figure 3. 4 The data: the European Community Household Panel Most of the existing studies of unemployment insurance and unemployment duration make use of administrative data8 . The advantage of these data usually consists in having detailed information about the amount and the sequence of payments as well as about individual eligibility and entitlement conditions. However, for the purpose of this paper the use of administrative data would be problematic for at least two reasons. First, in many countries unemployment insurance and social assistance programmes are administered by different governmental bodies and data available from one body rarely include information about benefits paid by others. Therefore, using administrative data would make it very difficult to look at interactions between different programmes. Secondly, and probably more importantly, even if comprehensive administrative data were available, in order to explore the interactions between different programmes one would need to compare similar individuals facing different unemployment benefits and social transfers: in other words one would need enough variation in the rules and regulations of both unemployment insurance and social assistance. However, there is typically little variation in such rules within one country9 and for identification purposes it would be helpful to 8 Boeri and Steiner [1998], Katz and Meyer [1990], Lancaster [1979], Meyer [1990], Moffit [1985], Naren- dranathan and Stewart [1993b]. 9 This is especially true for unemployment benefit while social assistance is more varied, being often administered at the local level (but this also makes it more difficult to obtain information about the system as well as about the beneficiaries). 11 use some cross-country variation as well. Unfortunately, cross-country comparable administrative microdata are simply not available. Alternatively one could use some exogenous time variation induced, for example, by a reform but, as already mentioned in Section 2, there hasn’t been much reforming in social assistance programmes over the past years. In order to overcome these problems, comparable cross-country survey data are utilized in this paper. Data come from the European Community Household Panel (ECHP), a panel of households and individuals from EU countries produced by Eurostat in cooperation with the member states statistical offices. The main advantage of this data source is the high level of cross-country comparability. This is guaranteed by standardised sampling procedures, defined by Eurostat and implemented by each country’s national statistical office. Moreover, identical questions are asked to households sampled in each country, merely translated into the local language. Sample sizes differ from country to country, with the highest sample-topopulation ratios for the largest and the poorest countries10 . The ECHP started in 1994 and 8 waves of data have been released so far, covering the period from 1994 to 2001. Not all countries entered the survey at the same time and for three of them - Germany, Luxembourg and the United Kingdom - the original sample has been replaced after the first three waves with harmonised versions of household panels already been produced nationally: the German Socio-Economic Panel (GSOEP), the Luxembourg’s Socio-Economic Panel (PSELL) and the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS). When possible data from the existing panels have been provided for the first three years too. For the purpose of this paper it is important to note that the ECHP includes information about unemployment benefit payments and social assistance transfers received both at the individual and at the household level. Moreover, it also contains retrospective information which allow to reconstruct employment/unemployment/inactivity monthly spells. In fact, individuals are interviewed once per year and at that time they are asked to report their monthly labour market status over the previous calendar year. One drawback of these data is the fact that all the variables are recorded annually and, as we will see later on, this will make it difficult to attach the correct numbers to each unemployment spell. 10 see Peracchi [2002] for a detailed description of the ECHP. 12 5 The empirical strategy The theory of Section 3 suggests that unemployment insurance recipients who also receive some social assistance should be less sensitive to both the level and the duration of their benefits. However, simply comparing UI recipients who receive some social assistance to those who do not receive any additional benefits might not identify any causal effect. The selection into social assistance is, in fact, likely to be highly non-random. Ideally, one would like to rely on a natural experiment where UI recipients are randomly assigned to a treatment group of persons eligible for means-tested social assistance and a control group of persons who are either not-eligible for social assistance or eligible for universal, non-means tested, benefits. UI recipients in the treatment group will be less concerned about their benefits being reduced or withdrawn, as they could be compensated by higher social assistance payments. Such interaction effect should not affect the control group. The ECHP allows to exploit variation in the institutional details of family cash benefits across European countries that mimic this ideal experiment. Specifically, in 5 countries Germany, Greece, Italy, Portugal and Spain - family cash benefits are means tested while in all the other EU-15 countries family assistance is universally assigned according to the number and the age of the children but regardless of household income. This paper focuses on the subsample of UI recipients who are male heads of households with children and assigns them to a treatment group of those who are eligible for means-tested family benefits and a control group of those who are either eligible for universal family assistance or not eligible altogether because the children are above the age limit. As long as the generosity of family benefits does not affect the decision about one’s country of residence11 and about when to have children, the selection into these treatment and control groups can be considered fairly exogenous. Table 3 reports the eligibility rules of family cash benefits in all EU-15 countries and the distribution of the sample by treatment and control groups. Eventually, the sample 11 An attraction effect of welfare generosity could be present for migrants, which are a minority in this sample, but is likely to be negligible for Europeans, who are highly immobile in general and especially when they have children. 13 includes 2,703 unemployment spells experienced between January 1994 and December 2001 by male heads of households who received unemployment benefits at some point during their unemployment spells. The sample is divided into a treatment group of 1,042 persons who are entitled to means-tested family assistance and 1,661 persons who are either entitled to universal assistance (because they live in countries where family benefits are not conditional on income) or are not eligible at all (because the children are above the age limit). In order to avoid further issues related to recipiency of other benefits, the sample is also restricted according to age, health status and home ownership. In particular, the persons in the sample are aged between 25 and 50 and are thus very unlikely to receive any type of old age benefits. They are also in good health conditions and they report owing their houses for the entire duration of their unemployment spell, thus making them ineligible for both sickness and housing benefits. Some of the households in the sample might still be entitled to some minimum income schemes, so the estimates reported below should be interpreted as lower bounds because potential actual or expected entitlement to minimum income programmes could affect the sensitivity to the level and the duration of unemployment benefits in the control group as well. Furthermore, left-censored spells have been dropped from the sample to avoid stocksampling bias. Unemployment spells, thus, end into either employment or inactivity or are right-censored. Spells experienced by new entrants in the labour market are also excluded because these workers are rarely entitled to unemployment insurance. Greece, Luxembourg, the Netherlands and Sweden have been excluded because information on retrospective employment status is lacking for these countries. The ECHP is a collection of country samples drawn from the total population following common procedures but independently. This means that the sample-to-population ratios differ from country to country and the observations need to be weighted accordingly when pooled together across countries. The 2,703 observations represent 685,888 unemployment spells which are distributed across countries as shown in Figure 4. This distribution is obviously influenced by both the relative size of each country and the level of the unemployment rate experienced in each area (plotted in Figure 4 along the dashed line and scaled on the right hand side vertical axis). 14 As already mentioned, this paper uses cross-country variation in the administrative rules of the welfare system (unemployment insurance and family cash benefits, in particular) to identify causal effects. This approach, however, requires controlling for all other possible institutional differences across countries. A lot of effort has been put in recent years, especially by the OECD, in producing quantitative measures of labour market institutions and a rather complete set of indicators is now available for statistical analysis. This paper fully exploits these indicators and the set of explanatory variables used for the estimation always include the following yearly measures: the regional rate of unemployment, the regional rate of longterm unemployment, expenditure in active labour market programmes (as a % of GDP), the share of part-time dependent employment, the share of temporary dependent employment, the legal minimum wage (normalised by the median wage)12 , the average effective tax rate13 , union density and the index of the strictness of employment protection legislation14 . Before proceeding with the empirical analysis two issues need to be discussed. First, although the ECHP allows the identification of monthly unemployment spells, it reports all other variables, included the amount received in ”unemployment related benefits”, only annually. Hence, it has been necessary to compute a monthly measure of unemployment benefit entitlement. Second, the pre-unemployment wage is a crucial variable for the analysis of the duration of unemployment but in the ECHP only workers who are employed at the time of the interview report their current wages. Thus, this variable is missing for many observations. These two issues are discussed in the following sub sections. 5.1 The imputation of monthly unemployment benefit payments The most obvious solution to compute a monthly unemployment benefit consists in simply dividing the annual amount by the number of months spent in unemployment during a particular year. However, this approach would generate zero variation in individual unemployment benefits over time, unless a spell spans over more than one year. Moreover, unless 12 13 This variable is set ot zero for those countries where there is no legal minimum wage. This is computed as the total tax wedge (income taxes plus all social security contributions) over total gross labour costs for a single production worker who earns the average wage in the manufacturing sector (the Average Production Worker, in the OECD terminology). 14 See OECD[2004a] and OECD [2004b] for more details about these indicators. 15 both the amount of the benefit and the number of months of unemployment are exactly measured, this approach is likely to generate some spurious covariance between monthly benefits and unemployment durations. In fact, the duration of a spell is very highly correlated with the number of months spent in unemployment in one year (it is actually exactly equal to that number if the unemployment spell begins and ends in the same year). In order to solve this problem, monthly unemployment benefits have been imputed on the basis of country specific rules and regulations. In fact, in all countries the amounts and the duration of unemployment benefits are calculated on the basis of individual characteristics, most of which are easily available from the ECHP: previous employment records, previous wage, age, family composition, et.. Combining these data with the rules of each country’s unemployment benefit system, a rather precise imputation of both the levels and the duration of payments can be obtained. In econometric terms, this procedure is equivalent to instrumenting the benefits with the country’s unemployment insurance regulations. This means that, beyond providing a monthly measure of benefits, using these imputed values makes the estimates robust to potential endogeneity of unemployment benefit receipt. The imputation routine requires two basic ingredients: a detailed description of the unemployment compensation system in all countries and years, and all relevant personal characteristics. The institutional features of all welfare programmes in the member countries of the European Union are systematically collected in the MISSOC15 , a yearly publication of the European Commission that contains comparative descriptions of rules and regulations of welfare programmes in the member states. Additional complementary information can be extracted from institutional databases created by other research institutions, like the Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti and the CESIfo centre. As for the relevant personal characteristics, most of them are directly available from the ECHP. Combining these two sources - institutional details from the Missoc and other sources and personal characteristics from the ECHP - it is possible to write imputation procedures for each country and year. The outcome of these procedures is a vector of imputed variables including the duration of benefit entitlement in months and the monthly sequence of 15 Mutual Information System on Social Protection in the Member States of the European Union. 16 payments16 for every individual in the sample. Evaluating the goodness of this imputation is not an easy task. One possibility is to compare the cumulated annual amount of imputed benefits with annual income from ”unemployment related benefits”, as recorded in the ECHP. This is done in Figure 5 where imputed annual benefits are shown on the vertical axis against reported annual benefits on the horizontal axis. Although the two measures appear to be strongly correlated, there still is a large dispersion around the 45-degree line. For two countries - Greece and Italy - the figures are particularly odd and require some explanations. Unemployment benefits in Greece, like in many other countries, are subject to a minimum and a maximum level. Here, however, the distribution of annual benefits is highly concentrated around the minimum. It seems like the large majority of the unemployed in Greece report receiving only the minimum benefit, even when the imputation suggests they should be entitled to higher transfers. Italy is another anomalous case: in this country there are many individuals who appear to be entitled but receive no benefits. This result is likely to be due to the high degree of discretionality of the Italian system. In fact, in this country unemployment benefits are highly differentiated by sector of industrial activity and firm size. Moreover, access to the most generous programmes (Cassa Integrazione Guadagni Ordinaria and Straordinaria) is often subject to government approval. This particular institutional setting, characterised by a high degree of discretionality, necessarily leads to a poor imputation. It is unclear, however, whether one would actually expect the points in Figure 5 to lie on the 45-degree line. The imputed measure of benefits is more an indicator of entitlement than receipt. It is a known fact that the degree of benefit take-up (i.e. the fraction of persons entitled to a benefit who actually claim it) varies largely across countries and can be very low. The recent survey of Hernanz et al. [2004] reports estimates of take-up of unemployment benefits that range between 65% and 76% in the United States and between 62% and 71% in the United Kingdom. Moreover, insurance-based programmes, like most unemployment benefits, are typically the least affected by low take-ups. Social assistance schemes, like some unemployment assistance programmes that are considered in this analysis, can reach 16 The programmes are written in Stata8.2 and are available from the author. 17 take-up rates as low as 37%. These estimates are only available for few countries (United Kingdom, Germany, Netherlands and a few others) which are likely to be the most efficient in the administration of social security programmes in Europe. Moreover, even if imputed and reported benefits were actually measures of the same underlying quantities, measurement error issues affect both of them and it is unclear which one of the two is preferable. Survey respondents will tend to underreport the amounts they receive from public transfers, typically because of social stigma, one of the most popular explanations put forward for the observed low take-up rates. Moreover, the ECHP only asks the annual amount received in ”unemployment related benefits”, thus, it is potentially subject to recall bias and, possibly, misunderstanding about what should fall into this group of transfers. The imputation, on the other hand, does not take into account various elements of the system for which no information is easily available. For example, in many countries benefits might be reduced or withdrawn in case the recipient does not fulfill various job search requirements. These sanctions are normally applied with some discretion and it is extremely hard to identify those persons in the ECHP who might have been subject to them. Another potential problem concerns the timing of the reforms. Changes in the unemployment compensation system could in principle be applied to the newly unemployed only, i.e. those who lost their jobs after the reform, or to all recipients. Information about these details of the reforms is very difficult to obtain. For simplicity, the imputation procedures used here assume that all changes always affect all recipients, regardless of when they entered unemployment. Finally, in the ECHP employment histories are perfectly known since the time the individual joined the survey but little is known about previous periods and some assumptions need to be made. Specifically, it has been assumed that individuals have always worked and paid contributions since the start of their first job, a piece of information available from the data17 . For the purpose of this paper, however, what matters most is that imputed benefits work well as instruments for actual benefits. The results in Figure 5 indicate that imputed benefits 17 This assumption is particularly problematic for the United Kingdom, where contribution conditions are particularly complex. 18 are generally strongly correlated with reported benefits, which, although imperfect, are the best available measure of actual benefits. Moreover, conditional on individual characteristics, the variation in imputed benefits across individuals is only due to differences, across countries and over time, in the administrative rules of the benefit systems, a type of variation which is hardly correlated with unobserved individual effects. 5.2 Measuring the earning potential of the unemployed One of the crucial controls that needs to be included in the estimation is a measure of the previous wage, as an indicator of the earning potential. In fact, the same benefit amount affects differently people who can earn different wages. What really counts in determining the incentives/disincentives to work is the actual difference between income in work and income out of work. This is why in the empirical analysis that follows, the replacement rate (the ratio between the unemployment benefit and the previous wage) will be used instead of the level of the benefit itself. However, in the ECHP unemployed workers do not report their previous wages. Only individuals who are working at the time of the interview are asked about their current monthly wage. In the estimation, the most recent observed current wage from previous interviews has been used as previous wage. Obviously there are many individuals who happen to be unemployed at all interviews, even if they report some employment spells between subsequent interviews. For these individuals no previous wage is observed. Discarding them would reduce the sample size dramatically and, even more worrisome, it would introduce a potentially large sample bias: the probability of having been unemployed at all interviews is obviously higher for individuals at high risk of long and/or repeated unemployment. Alternatively, one can use the average wage earned by individuals with similar characteristics. This is the approach taken here: missing previous wages are replaced by the average wage of full-time workers with the same level of education, age, experience, gender and region of residence18 . 18 This is computed by running a series of year-by-year, country-by-country OLS wage regressions including education, age, experience and regional dummies and run separately for males and females. 19 6 The empirical analysis Table 4 shows the descriptive statistics for the entire sample and for the treatment and the control group separately. Encouragingly, the differences between the two groups are not particularly marked. Education and income are significantly higher in the control group, while age and experience are slightly lower. Interestingly, household composition (household size and number of children) is not particularly different between the two groups, suggesting that the selection into treatment and control is mostly due to cross-country differences in the means-testing procedures. As expected, the fraction of families that report receiving family assistance is higher in the treatment group while UI replacement rates and durations are similar. Important differences emerge for unemployment assistance. In some countries, once unemployment insurance expires, one can receive a non-insurance based benefit, conventionally named unemployment assistance, which is normally unlimited (although subject to job search requirements). Most of the countries that offer unlimited unemployment assistance happen to also have universal family benefits, hence, 72% of the persons in the control group are potentially entitled to unlimited unemployment assistance versus only 16% among the treated. Finally, the average duration of the unemployment spells is only marginally different, with the treated experiencing on average spells longer by 1.5 months. The differences in the regional and country variables are more marked, but this is not surprising, being the treatment and the control group selected mostly on the basis of the features of the countries’ welfare systems. This brief inspection of the descriptive statistics already suggests that there should be no systematic differences in the individual characteristics of the treated and the controls. In order to clear any further doubt, Table 5 reports the results of a simple probit regression where the dependent variable is equal to 1 if the individual is in the treatment group and zero otherwise. Most of the individual characteristics turn out to be not significant, apart from the number of children and the size of the household. A test of the joint significance of all the personal and family variables does not reject the null hypothesis of the coefficients being all zero. On the other hand, all the regional and country characteristics (apart from the regional long term unemployment rate) are strongly significant. Once again this result is not 20 surprising. The crucial identification assumption here is that, after controlling for a large set of controls of national institutional differences, cross-country variation in the administrative rules of the welfare system can safely be used to identify causal effects. Obviously, there still remain a possibility that the treated and the control might significantly differ according to some unobserved characteristics (culture, attitudes towards family and work, etc.). However, since the variables of interest - UI replacement rate and duration of UI entitlement - have been imputed only on the basis of the country regulations, endogeneity could only arise if these unobserved characteristics influence the design of the welfare programmes considered here. Let us now move on to the analysis of the exit rates from unemployment for the two groups. Figures 6 and 7 show the empirical hazards19 for the entire sample and for the treatment and control group separately. The distribution of imputed duration of unemployment benefit is also reported in the figures, scaled on the right hand side vertical axis. The figure for the entire sample (Figure 6) shows the expected peak in the hazard around the time of UI exhaustion. In fact, the almost monotonic declining trend in the hazard rate is interrupted between the 12th and the 18th month, in correspondence with a series of important mass point in the distribution of UI duration at 12, 15, 16 and 18 months. The later mass point at 24 months, however, is not associated with any peak, but at this duration the size of the sample is already dramatically reduced and the hazard rate is estimated rather imprecisely. By looking at the same picture for the two groups (Figure 7) it is already evident that these peaks are mostly due to the control group. The hazard rate for the treated, in fact, is a lot flatter, especially between the 12th and the 18th month. Moreover, the control group shows an earlier peak at the 6th month of unemployment, in correspondence with mass points in the distribution of UI duration at 6 and 7 months. The hazard rate of the treated is a much more fluctuating at the same duration. Evidence from the empirical hazards, although already suggestive, is obviously not fully convincing because the extent to which these graphs are influenced by personal characteristics 19 The empirical hazard at time t is computed as the ratio of individuals who actually exit unemployment at time t over the number of all individuals who have been unemployed at least until t, i.e. all individuals who could have exited at time t. 21 and duration dependence is not taken into account. Table 6 reports the results from a proportional hazard model estimated for various samples. The econometric model is rather standard, with one minor difficulty arising because in the ECHP unemployment durations are recorded in months - i.e. in discrete intervals of time - whereas the underlying process of job search occurs essentially in continuous time (workers can find a job at any moment within a month). Following the custom in the literature, let us assume that the hazard rate ϑ(t|Xi , β) - of the underlying continuous process for individual i, i.e. the instant probability that the spell ends at time t, can be written as the product of two parts: a baseline hazard that depends on duration only, h0 (t), and a ”proportional shifter”, eXi β , that, according to each individual’s characteristics Xi , shifts the baseline up or down: ϑ(t|Xi , β) = h0 (t) · eXi β (6) The discrete time analog of ϑ(t|Xi , β) for spell i that ends between month Ti and Ti + 1, is usually written as: h(Ti | Xi , β) = Pr {Ti < t < Ti + 1 | t > Ti , Xi , β} = ¤ £ S(Ti |Xi , β) − S(Ti + 1| Xi , β) = 1 − exp eXi β (Hi − Hi+1 ) = S(Ti | Xi , β) where Hi = ZTi (7) h0 (u)du. It is useful to apply to equation (7) the following transformation: 0 log(− log [1 − h(Ti | Xi , β)]) = Xi β + τ i (8) Equation (8) allows to recover for (a transformation of) the discrete time hazard h(Ti | Xi , β) the separability property of its continuos-time analog. In fact, this transformation of h(Ti | Xi , β), just like ϑ(t|Xi , β), can now be separated into two parts: one, τ i = log [H(Ti ) − H(Ti + 1)] , that depends on the shape of the baseline hazard only, and another one, Xi β, which depends only on individual’s characteristics (possibly time-varying). According to equation (8), the discrete time hazard can then be rewritten as: ¢ ¡ h(Ti | Xi , β) = 1 − exp −eXi β+τ i 22 (9) Then, it is possible to express the likelihood contributions of completed and uncompleted spells in terms of the discrete-time hazard and apply the transformation of equation (8) for the estimation: completed spells : Pr {Ti < t < Ti + 1 | Xi , β} = h(Ti | Xj , β) uncompleted spells: Pr {t > Ti | Xi , β} = Ti Y k=0 TY i −1 k=0 [1 − h(k | Xi , β)] [1 − h(k | Xi , β)] In our data, a spell can end either into employment or into inactivity. Assuming that the probabilities of ending in any of these two states are independent, Narendrenathan and Stewart [1993] showed that, by making the additional, harmless but greatly simplifying assumption, that exits can only occur at the boundaries of the interval (i.e. either at the beginning or at the end of each month), the correct hazard for exits into employment can be estimated by considering as censored all those spells that end into inactivity. This is also the approach taken here and the investigation of the determinants of exits into inactivity is left for future research. The set of controls included in the model contains all the relevant observable personal characteristics, country and region specific controls and year dummies. Table 6, however, only reports the estimated coefficients on the variables of main interest - the UI replacement rate and the ”time to exhaustion” dummies - while the full set of results can be found in Table A.1 in Appendix A. The estimates in Table 6 are obtained by imposing a third order polynomial form for the baseline hazard, τ i = Ti + Ti2 + Ti3 . The first column in Table 6 shows the estimates obtained for the large sample all UI recipients, i.e. including males and females, all persons aged between 16 and 64 and all households with and without children. The purpose of this first set of results is to show that, using cross-country variation in the administrative rules of the unemployment insurance system, it is possible to replicate the usual results in the literature. In fact, higher UI replacement rates (UIρ) reduce the probability of finding a job, but only after the 6th month of unemployment, while there is no statistically significant effect during the earlier months. This non-monotonic effect of the generosity of unemployment benefit is an already known result. Once UI expires, some of the individuals in the sample are still eligible for 23 unemployment assistance but its generosity (UAρ) does not have a significant impact on the hazard rate. To capture the presence of peaks in the hazard rate around the time of benefit exhaustion, a set of ”months to exhaustion” dummies has been included in the model for both unemployment insurance and unemployment assistance. The coefficients on these dummies indicate a significant increase in the hazard rate between 4 to 6 months from exhaustion of UI and a similar but opposite effect for UA. The following column in Table 6, repeats the same estimation for the sample of 2,703 UI recipients who are male heads of households with children. Results are generally confirmed, apart form the peak in the hazard at 4 to 6 months from UI exhaustion, which has now disappeared. The most interesting part of Table 6, however, is the comparison between column 3 and 4, where the estimation is repeated for the control and the treatment group separately. The results are now dramatically different: while the negative impact of high UI replacement rates is confirmed for the control group, this disappears for the treated, who instead show significantly higher exit rates associated with more generous UI in the first 6 months of unemployment and no effect afterwards. Moreover, the estimates for the control group show peaks in the hazard between 2 and 4 months to UI exhaustion while the same coefficient is actually negative for the treated who, instead, show a jump in the probability of finding a job around the time of UA exhaustion. As indicated by the summary statistics in Table 4, there are actually few individuals who are eligible for UA among the treated, so this last result could be due these few observations all exiting around the time of UA exhaustion. The dip in the hazard between 4 to 6 months from UI exhaustion for the treated could be explained by a sort of ”wait unemployment” effect: if family benefits guarantee a similar income to UI for a longer period and without the hassle of the job search requirements, there could actually be an incentive to wait for the unemployment benefit to expire and receive more family benefits. The last column of Table 6 reports the significance level of the difference between the estimated coefficients for the treated and the control. The results of Table 6 are obtained without controlling for unobserved heterogeneity. Although the identification strategy is robust to correlation between unobservable heterogeneity 24 and the variables of interest (UI replacement rate and exhaustion dummies), unobservable effects could increase the variance of the model. This is likely to be particularly important in the sample used here, where about 60% of the individuals experience more than one unemployment spell during the period of observation. As it is customary in this literature, unobserved heterogeneity could be controlled for by making an arbitrary assumption about the distribution of the unobservables. The likelihood of the model is then estimated by integrating it out. In Table A.2 the model of Table 6 is estimated using this approach and assuming normally distributed heterogeneity. The results are only marginally different from those in the main text and, if anything, they are more precisely estimated. 7 Conclusions This paper investigates how interactions between unemployment insurance and social assistance affect the job search behaviour of the unemployed. The theoretical framework presented in Section 3 formalizes the idea that people are eventually interested in total payments (i.e. unemployment benefit and social assistance) and their time profile. Unemployed workers will react differently to changes in the rules of the UI system depending on what alternative or complementary welfare programmes are available. These theoretical predictions are tested using monthly labour market histories of European unemployed persons and exploiting variation in a particular feature of family cash benefits across Europe. While family benefits are universal in most countries, i.e. allocated according only to the number and the age of children but regardless of income, in 5 countries they are actually means tested. Comparing similar unemployed male heads of households with children who are subject to different family assistance schemes, shows significant differences in the elasticity of the probability of finding employment to both the generosity and the duration of the unemployment benefit. These results suggests that interactions between welfare programmes are, indeed, important. From a more general policy perspective, this paper highlights the need to design welfare reforms with very careful consideration for the interactions between different programmes in the system: reducing the level or the duration of unemployment benefit may not be very 25 effective in inducing unemployed workers to search harder if they can easily shift into other social assistance programmes. This result is consistent with some recent studies that have shown how wide and comprehensive reforms of labour market policies, even if politically harder to implement, are often more effective than piecewise reforms. References [1] A.B., Gomulka J., Micklewright J., Rau N., (1984) ”Unemployment benefits, duration and incentives in Britain: how robust is the evidence?”, Journal of Public Economics, 1984, vol. 23, 3-26. [2] Atkinson A., Micklewright J., (1991) ”Unemployment compensation and labour market transitions: a critical review”, Journal of Economic Literature, 1991, vol. 29, 1679-1727. [3] Belot M., Van Ours J. C., (2000) ”Does the recent success of some OECD countries in lowering their unemployment rates lie in the clever design of their labour market reforms?”, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper: 2429, June 2000. [4] Bertola G., Jimeno J.F., Marimon R., Pissarides C., (2000) ”EU Welfare Systems and Labour Markets: Diverse in the Past, Integrated in the Future?”, in Bertola G., Boeri T., Nicoletti G., Welfare and Employment in a United Europe”, MIT Press. [5] Blundell R., Fry V., Walker I., (1988) ”Modelling the take-up of means-tested benefits: the case of housing benefits in the United Kingdom”, Economic Journal, vol. 98 (390 Supplement), 1988, 58-74. [6] Boeri T., Steiner V., (1998) ””Wait unemployment” in economies in transition: the case of Poland”, Konjunkturpolitik; 44(3), 1998, 287-311. [7] Cahuc P., Lehemann E., (2000) ”Should unemployment benefit decrease with the unemployment spell?”, Journal of Public Economics, 2000, vol. 77, 135-153. [8] CESIfo (2004), Ifo’s Database for Institutional Comparisons in Europe (DICE), www.cesifo.de 26 [9] Coe D. T., Snower D. J., (1997) ”Policy Complementarities: The Case for Fundamental Labour Market Reform”, Centre for Economic Policy Research Discussion Paper: 1585, February 1997. [10] Craig P., (1991) ”Costs and Benefits: a review of research on take-up of income related benefits”, Journal of Social Policy, 1991, vol. 20(4), 537-565. [11] Daveri F., Tabellini G., (1998) ”Unemployment, growth and taxation in industrial countries”, Labour Economics, 1998, vol. 5, 47-88. [12] Dormont B., Fougere D., Prieto A., ”The effects of time profiles of unemployment insurance benefits on reemployment rate”, mimeo. [13] Elmeskov J., Martin J. P., Scarpetta S., (1998) ”Key lessons for labour market reforms: evidence from OECD countries’ experiences”, Swedish Economic Policy Review, 1998, vol. 5, 205-252. [14] Esping-Andersen G., (1990) ”The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism”, Cambridge, UK, Policy Press. [15] Ferrera M., (1998) ”The Four Social Europes: Between Universalism and Selectivity”, in Rhodes M., Meny Y., ”The Future of European Welfare: A New Social Contract?”, Basingstoke, Macmillan. [16] Fondazione Rodolfo Debenedetti (2004), fRDB Social Reforms Database, www.frdb.org [17] Heckman J., Singer B., (1984) ”A method for minimizing the impact of distributional assumptions in econometric models of duration data”, Econometrica, vol. 52, 1984, 271-320. [18] Hernanz V., Malherbet F., Pellizzari M. (2004), ”Take-up of welfare benefits in OECD countries: a review of the evidence”, OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers n. 17. [19] Holmlund B., (1998) ”Unemployment insurance in theory and practice”, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 1998, vol. 100(1), 113-141. 27 [20] Katz L. F., Meyer B. D., (1990) ”Unemployment insurance, recall expectations and unemployment outcomes”, Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1990, vol. 105(4), 973-1002. [21] Lancaster T., (1979) ”Econometric models for the duration of unemployment”, Econometrica, 1979, vol. 47, 939-956. [22] Meyer B.D., (1990) ”Unemployment insurance and unemployment spells”, Econometrica, July 1990, vol. 58(4), 757-782. [23] MISSOC, ”Social Protection in the Member States of the European Union”, 1994 to 1997 editions, European Commission, Directorate-General for Employment Industrial Relations and Social Affairs, 1994. [24] Moffitt R., (1983) ”An economic model of welfare stigma”, American Economic Review, 1983, vol. 75(5), 1023-1035. [25] Moffitt R., (1985) ”Unemployment insurance and the distribution of unemployment spells”, Journal of Econometrics, April 1985, vol. 28, 85-101. [26] Mortensen D., (1977) ”Unemployment Insurance and Job Search Decisions”, Industrial and Labor Relations Review, July 1977, vol. 30, 505-517 [27] Narendranathan W., Stewart M. B., (1993a) ”Modelling the probability of leaving unemployment: competing risks models with flexible base-line hazards”, Applied Statistics, 1993, vol. 42(1), 63-83. [28] Narendranathan W., Stewart M. B., (1993b) ”How does the benefit effect vary as unemployment spells lengthen?”, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 1993, vol. 8(4), 361-381. [29] Nickell S., (1979) ”Estimating the probability of leaving unemployment”, Econometrica, September 1979, vol. 47(5), 1249-1266. [30] Nickell S., Van Ours J. C., (2000) ”The Netherlands and the United Kingdom: A European Unemployment Miracle?”, Economic Policy, April 2000, vol. 0(30), 135-175. 28 [31] OECD (1998), ”Benefit Systems and Work Incentives - 1998 Edition”, Paris. [32] OECD (1999), ”Benefit System and Work Incentive - 1999 Edition”, Paris. [33] OECD (2002), ”Benefit System and Work Incentive - 2002 Edition”, Paris. [34] OECD (2004a), OECD Employment Outlook, Paris. [35] OECD (2004b), Taxing Wages 2003/2004, Paris [36] Orszag J. M., Snower D. J. (1999), ”Anatomy of Policy Complementarities”, IZA Discussion Paper No.41. [37] Peracchi F. (2002), ”The European Community Household Panel: A review”, Empirical Economics, vol. 27, 63-90. 29 Figures and Tables 1984 1984 1996 1996 2000 2000 2004 2004 1980 1984 1992 year 1996 Denmark 1988 1992 year 1996 Germany 1988 2000 Type of reform: — UI benefit – – – UI duration 2004 2004 20 2000 unemployment rate 15 10 1984 5 1980 0 11 unemployment rate 10 9 1992 year France 1992 year 12 8 Belgium 1988 1988 unemployment rate 10 8 1980 1980 1984 1984 1988 1988 Finland 1992 year Greece 1992 year 1996 1996 2000 2000 2004 2004 Direction of the reform: thick: less generous (i.e. lower and/or shorter payments) thin: more generous 7 12 Figure 1: Unemployment and social reforms in Europe 1980 1980 6 12 4 10 unemployment rate 8 6 4 2 unemployment rate 10 8 6 12 unemployment rate 10 8 6 1984 1988 Ireland 1992 year 1996 2000 2004 1984 1992 year 1996 Portugal 1988 2000 2004 1980 1980 1984 1984 1988 Italy 1992 year 1996 1996 2000 2000 Type of reform: — UI benefit – – – UI duration 1992 year Sweden 1988 Figure 1: Unemployment and social reforms in Europe (continued...) 1980 1980 2004 2004 15 unemployment rate 10 5 0 12 1980 1980 1984 1984 1992 year 1996 Netherlands 1988 1992 year 1996 United Kingdom 1988 2000 2000 2004 2004 Direction of the reform: thick: less generous (i.e. lower and/or shorter payments) thin: more generous 4 6 unemployment rate 10 8 unemployment rate 11 10 9 12 8 10 2 unemployment rate 8 6 4 unemployment rate 15 10 20 5 9 8 unemployment rate 7 6 5 4 Figure 2: Time profiles of benefit, reservation wage, search time and hazard rate — Case 1 reservation wage benefit wt* bt T unemployment duration T unemployment duration hazard rate search time qt st T unemployment duration T unemployment duration Figure 3: Time profiles of benefit, reservation wage, search time and hazard rate — Case 2 reservation wage benefit bt wt T T unemployment duration search time unemployment duration hazard rate st* w t* T unemployment duration T unemployment duration 46058 Austria 19606 Belgium 24877 Finland 95612 France 84908 Germany Ireland 14847 50496 Italy Portugal 9023 Figure 4: Distribution of spells by country 15460 Denmark 282122 SpainUnited Kingdom 42879 20 16 8 12 Average un. rate 4 0 300000 200000 100000 0 Frequency Figure 5: Comparison between imputed and reported annual unemployment benefit (national currencies) Figure 6: Empirical Hazard for unemployment-to-job transitions 30 0.08 0.07 25 20 hazard 0.05 15 0.04 0.03 10 frequency of UI duration (%) 0.06 0.02 5 0.01 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 month of unemployment Males heads of households with children [95% Conf. Int.] Figure 7: Empirical Hazard for unemployment-to-job transtions by groups 0.1 30 0.09 25 0.08 20 hazard 0.06 0.05 15 0.04 10 0.03 0.02 5 0.01 0 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24 26 month of unemployment CONTROL GROUP TREATMENT GROUP 28 30 32 34 36 frequency of UI duration (%) 0.07 Table 1: The effect of UI reforms on the probability of leaving unemployment Country Reform Austria reduced duration - 2000 Belgium reduced benefit — 1999 reduced benefit — 1997 Finland reduced benefit — 2000 Germany reduced duration — 1995 Greece reduced benefit - 1996 Ireland reduced benefit — 1995 United Kingdom reduced duration and benefit — 1995 effect1 -0.459* (0.252) -0.292 (0.361) 0.156 (0.142) 0.258 (0.253) -0.031 (0.169) 0.035 (0.184) 0.486* (0.279) 0.291 (0.334) 1. Coefficient of a dummy for unemployment spells that started after the implementation of the reform. The estimates are obtained from a proportional hazard model with a fully non-parametric baseline and the following explanatory variables: sex, age (linear and squared), health status, education, marital status, family size, dummy for children in the household, household income, regional unemployment rate and rate of long term unemployment, year dummies. Source: ECHP 1994-2001 Table 2: Welfare reforms in Europe COUNTRY Austria REFORMS • • • • • • • Belgium • • • • • • Denmark • • • Finland • • • • • • • France Germany Greece Ireland • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 1995: Unemployment benefits are cut (particularly for those with high incomes) 1999-2000: Family Benefits are made more generous 2000: Unemployment benefits’ duration is increased for persons with at least 15 years of contributions. 2002: Unemployment benefits made more generous. 2002: Child-care support made more generous. 1988: Replacement rates for unemployment benefits are reduced 1992: Reform of unemployment benefit: access for those on temporary or part-time jobs; redefinition of “suitable offer”; new rules for early retirement. 1998: Improved incentive for those on Income Support (Minimex) to take up jobs. 1999: Unemployment benefits made more generous for single persons 2001: Introduction of tax deductibility for child-care costs. 2001: Social assistance made more generous for old people. 1987: Unemployment benefits are increased. 1994: Labour Market Reform: unemployment benefits’ duration is reduced and eligibility conditions are tightened. 1996: Follow-up of Labour Market Reform: unemployment benefits’ duration is shortened and eligibility conditions are tightened. 1993: Reform of (flat-rate) Unemployment Assistance: duration is limited and eligibility requirements brought in line with those for the earnings-related supplementary benefit. 1995: Reform of the unemployment benefits system: stricter conditions for the unemployed to re-qualify for unemployment benefits, shortened duration for older workers 1997: Reform of the unemployment benefits system: stricter access conditions and lower payments. 1998: Unemployment benefits are increased. 1998: Stricter access conditions for minimum income benefits. 2000: Unemployment benefits are decreased. 1992: Reform of unemployment benefits that introduces a downward sliding scale for payments. 1993: Unemployment benefits’ duration is reduced. 1993: Increased generosity of general social assistance: housing benefits, family benefits, employment accidents and occupational illness benefits are increased and made easier to access. 1997: Minimum unemployment benefit is increased and duration of benefits is also extended. 1998: Minimum income benefit increased. 1999: Unemployment benefits increased. 2000: Generalised increases in both unemployment and minimum income benefits. 2001: Generalised increases in both unemployment and minimum income benefits. 1994: Unemployment benefits are reduced. 1995: Unemployment benefit duration is reduced. 1998: Several changes: stricter rules for access to the minimum income scheme (RMI); lower payments for sickness benefits; better incentives for unemployment benefit recipients to take up jobs (redefinition of suitable offer; incentive to take part-time jobs, et.). 1999: Increased sickness benefits. 1990: Unemployment benefits’ duration is increased. 1996: Unemployment benefits are reduced. 1987: Unemployment benefits are reduced. 1993: Labour Market Reform: eligibility for unemployment benefits is made stricter; child benefits are increased, family benefits are increased; income support is increased. 1995: Unemployment benefits are reduced. • • 1988: Ordinary unemployment benefits are increased. 1991: New unemployment benefit scheme for long-term unemployment is introduced (only for certain categories) Italy • 1994: Unemployment benefits are increased and coverage is extended. • 1998: Minimum income scheme introduced on an experimental basis. • 1999: introduced new means-tested family cash benefits. • 1987: Revision of the Social Security System Act: duration of unemployment benefits is reduced; stricter rules for invalidity benefits/pensions; conditions for accessing all benefits are tightened. • 1991: Social Insurance Organisational Act: administration of all benefits delegated to a single governmental body. Netherlands • 1996: General Social Assistance Act: improved incentives for those on income support to take up jobs; privatisation of sickness benefits. • 1997: A new housing benefit is introduced. • 2001: Employment bonus paid to people on unemployment benefit who find job. • 1997: Reform of family benefits (completely different structure, cannot say if more/less generous overall); easier access to employment injuries/occupational disease benefits; a new minimum income scheme is introduced. Portugal • 1998: Introduction of a “partial” unemployment benefit for part-timers. • 1998: Longer contribution record required for eligibility of unemployment benefits. • 1999: Extended duration of unemployment benefits. • 1992: Reform of the unemployment benefits (reduced duration and payments). • 1993: Unemployment benefits are reduced. Spain • 1994: Unemployment benefits are subject to taxation. • 2000: Extended unemployment benefits for older workers with children. • 1986: Participation in training programmes is considered equivalent to work for the purpose of eligibility for unemployment benefits • 1987: Subsidised jobs are offered to those whose unemployment benefit expires (and the job must, by law, last at least enough to make the worker eligible for unemployment benefits again). • 1993: Unemployment benefits are reduced. Sweden • 1997: Reform of unemployment benefits: benefits are reduced and re-qualification through subsidised jobs no longer available. • 1998: Increased sickness benefits. • 1999: Housing benefits made stricter and lower. • 2002: Child-care made more generous. • 1988: Unemployment benefits are reduced. • 1989: Unemployment benefits are reduced. • 1996: Job Seekers Allowance (JSA) replaces the old unemployment benefit: both payments and duration of benefits are reduced, income support is replaced by a means-tested component of the JSA. United Kingdom • 1997: Introduction of an employment bonus for older workers. • 1998: Welfare-to-Work Programme: training for long-term unemployed, hiring subsidies for employers, sanctions for refusing job offers, etc. • 1999: Introduction of new means-tested child-care tax credit. Sources: European Commission Missoc (1992-2001), Missoc-info (1985-2001); Fondazione RDB “Social Policy Reforms Database”; CESifo “DICE Database”. Table 3. Family Cash Benefits in Europe and Composition of the sample Country Income Test Age Limit Austria No 19 to 26 All male heads of households with kids 291 Belgium No 18 to 25 Denmark No Finland 1 Control Treatment 291 (100.0) 0 (0.0) 111 111 (100.0) 0 (0.0) 18 149 149 (100.0) 0 (0.0) No 16 275 275 (100.0) 0 (0.0) France No 18 to 20 187 187 (100.0) 0 (0.0) Germany Yes 18 199 36 (18.1) 163 (81.9) Greece Yes 18 to 22 - - - Ireland No 16 to 19 277 277 (100.0) 0 (0.0) Italy Yes 18 149 35 (23.5) 114 (76.5) Luxembourg No 18 to 27 - - - Netherlands No 17 to 24 - - - Portugal Yes 15 to 24 80 5 (6.3) 75 (93.8) Spain Yes 18 890 200 (22.5) 690 (77.5) Sweden No 16 - - - United Kingdom No 16 to 19 95 95 (100.0) 0 (0.0) 2703 1661 (61.5) 1042 (38.5) Total 1. Benefits are paid until the child reaches this age limit, which is extended for children in training or higher education. Source: European Commission Missoc Table 4: Descriptive Statistics All male heads of households with kids Mean Std. Dev. Variable Individual and spells: Age Experience1 1=primary education 1=secondary education 1=tertiary education Household size Number of chilren (<15yo) Log Household income (PPP) 2 Control group Treatment group Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. 37.22 (7.41) 36.33 (7.68) 38.66 (6.70) 20.08 0.49 0.37 0.14 4.35 1.31 (8.93) (1.32) (1.08) 18.67 0.38 0.45 0.17 4.34 1.19 (8.94) (1.41) (1.18) 22.30 0.66 0.25 0.09 4.37 1.51 8.15 (3.02) 9.02 (1.86) 6.76 (3.88) 0.21 - 0.20 - 0.24 - 0.64 (0.23) 0.64 (0.25) 0.64 (0.21) 20.89 (18.18) 20.40 (18.63) 21.66 (17.42) 0.50 - 0.72 - 0.16 - Duration of all unemployment spells Duration of completed unemployment spells 11.13 10.61 (11.53) (9.65) 10.67 10.05 (11.73) (8.69) 11.85 (11.17) 11.43 (10.88) Fraction of completed spells ending into employment ending into inactivity 81.98 0.95 0.05 - 79.77 0.94 0.06 1=Family cash benefit recipients 3 UI replacement rate Maximum entitlement of UI (in months) 1=unlimited UA 4 4 Number of spells 2703 Countries and regions: 5 Regional unemployment rate Regional long-term unemployment rate Expenditure in ALMP (%GDP) Share of part-time employment 6 6 Share of temporary employment Share of public employment 6 Minimum wage / median wage Average effective tax rate Uniuon density 7 6 Employment protection index 6 6 6 5 (8.46) (1.17) (0.87) 85.51 0.98 0.02 1661 1042 14.09 (7.49) 11.15 (5.76) 18.77 (7.54) 0.39 (0.14) 0.42 (0.15) 0.36 (0.10) 0.95 (0.47) 1.10 (0.50) 0.72 (0.30) 11.86 (4.58) 13.49 (4.44) 9.27 (3.49) 18.19 (11.13) 13.41 (8.35) 25.82 (10.77) 0.21 (0.06) 0.22 (0.06) 0.18 (0.03) 0.19 (0.21) 0.15 (0.23) 0.24 (0.15) 38.00 (5.73) 38.34 (6.42) 37.46 (4.37) 34.88 (22.22) 44.02 (23.53) 20.30 (7.27) 2.45 (0.81) 2.09 (0.82) 3.03 (0.32) 1. Years since first entrance in the labour market 2. Income of all other household members 3. Monthly UI amount / previous wage. UI amounts imputed on the basis of country regulations and personal characteristics (MISSOC, 1993-2001). 4. Imputed on the basis of country regulations and personal characteristics (MISSOC, 1994-2001). 5. Source: ECHP 6. Source OECD 7. Income taxes plus social security contributions (employer and employee) over total gross labour costs. Source: OECD Table 5: Selection into treatment and control group Dependent variable=1 if treated Personal and family characteristics: Age Experience1 1=secondary education 1=tertiary education Household size Number of kids (<15yo) (log) hh income2 1= zero hh income Country/Region characteristics: Regional unemployment rate3 Regional long-term unemployment rate3 Expenditure in ALMP (%GDP)4 Share of part-time employment4 Share of temporary employment4 Share of public employment4 Minimum wage (/median wage)4 Average tax rate5 Union density4 Employment protection index4 Year dummies: 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 Constant Observations Log-likelihood UI recipients, male heads of households with kids 0.013 (0.024) 0.025 (0.020) -0.206 (0.149) -0.063 (0.191) -0.142* (0.064) 1.774** (0.129) -0.054 (0.059) 0.616 (0.600) 0.028* (0.012) 0.925 (0.779) 1.266* (0.544) 0.268* (0.117) 0.143** (0.038) 36.324** (8.342) -30.114** (3.895) -0.329** (0.052) -0.319** (0.069) 6.434** (0.577) -0.666** (0.237) -0.751** (0.282) 0.045 (0.259) 0.400 (0.316) -0.636 (0.375) -0.494 (0.387) -0.814 (0.445) -7.706 (4.006) 2703 -319.58 1. Years since first entrance in the labour market 2. Income of all other household members. 3. Source: ECHP 4. Source: OECD 5. Income taxes plus social security contributions (employer and employee) over total gross labour costs. Source: OECD Robust standard errors (clustered by individual and year) in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% (2>time<=6) 106268 16813 -36832.70 yes yes yes (time, time2, time3) -0.112 (0.250) -0.159 (0.225) -1.235** (0.275) -0.235 (0.136) 0.072 (0.146) 0.302** (0.121) -0.035 (0.111) 0.066 (0.065) -0.468** (0.132) -0.014 (0.156) [1] 24080 2703 -9146.90 yes yes yes (time, time2, time3) 0.892 (0.601) -0.745 (0.500) -1.049* (0.479) -0.533 (0.434) 0.256 (0.258) 0.308 (0.256) 0.318 (0.322) 0.150 (0.294) -0.987* (0.458) -0.409 (0.469) UI recipients, male heads of households with kids [2] 13757 1661 -4465.21 yes yes yes (time, time2, time3) -0.476 (0.511) -0.851 (0.754) -0.978 (0.643) -0.090 (0.337) 0.597* (0.293) 0.475 (0.305) 0.204 (0.380) -0.248 (0.336) -1.368* (0.559) -0.924 (1.004) [3] Control 10323 1042 -4523.81 yes yes yes (time, time2, time3) 2.554** (0.883) 1.236 (0.773) -0.624 (0.726) -1.417 (0.950) -1.406* (0.671) 0.050 (0.420) 2.222* (0.887) 1.950* (0.778) 0.613 (0.833) 0.843 (0.707) [4] Treatment All UI recipients Table 6: Proportional Hazard Model for unemployment duration — Exits into Jobs UIρ ⋅ (time>6) Replacement rates: UIρ1 ⋅ (time<=2) UIρ ⋅ UAρ1 “Months to UI exhaustion” dummies: 1=less than 2 months 1=2 to 4 months 1=4 to 6 months “Months to UA exhaustion” dummies: 1=less than 2 months 1=2 to 4 months 1=4 to 6 months Personal and family characteristics2 Country/region characteristics3 Year dummies Baseline hazard Observations Subjects Log-likelihood Difference [3]-[4] ** ** * ** ** 1. Monthly UI or UA amount / previous wage. UI and UA amounts imputed on the basis of country regulations and personal characteristics (MISSOC, 1993-2001). 2. Age, experience, education, health status, house ownership, household size, number of kids (<15yo), (log) household income. See table A1 3. Regional unemployment rate, regional long-term unemployment rate, expenditure in ALMP (%GDP), share of part-time employment, share of temporary employment, share of public employment, minimum wage (/median wage), average tax rate. See table A1. Robust standard errors (clustered by individual and year) in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% Appendix A: Additional estimation results Table A1: Proportional Hazard Model for unemployment duration — Exits into Jobs All UI recipients [1] Replacement rates: UIρ1 ⋅ (time<=2) UI recipients, male heads of households with kids [2] Control Treatment [3] [4] -0.035 (0.111) 0.066 UIρ ⋅ (2>time<=6) (0.065) -0.468** UIρ ⋅ (time>6) (0.132) -0.014 UAρ1 (0.156) “Months to UI exhaustion” dummies: 1=less than 2 months -0.235 (0.136) 1=2 to 4 months 0.072 (0.146) 1=4 to 6 months 0.302* (0.121) “Months to UA exhaustion” dummies: 0.318 (0.322) 0.150 (0.294) -0.987* (0.458) -0.409 (0.469) 0.204 (0.380) -0.248 (0.336) -1.368* (0.559) -0.924 (1.004) 2.222* (0.887) 1.950* (0.778) 0.613 (0.833) 0.843 (0.707) -0.533 (0.434) 0.256 (0.258) 0.308 (0.256) -0.090 (0.337) 0.597* (0.293) 0.475 (0.305) -1.417 (0.950) -1.406* (0.671) 0.050 (0.420) 1=less than 2 months 0.892 (0.601) -0.745 (0.500) -1.049* (0.479) -0.476 (0.511) -0.851 (0.754) -0.978 (0.643) 2.554** (0.883) 1.236 (0.773) -0.624 (0.726) - - - 0.014 (0.015) -0.019 (0.012) -0.066 (0.113) -0.197 (0.177) - 0.015 (0.018) -0.020 (0.015) -0.057 (0.140) -0.275 (0.203) - -0.008 (0.028) -0.005 (0.022) -0.091 (0.183) -0.097 (0.293) - - - - -0.016 (0.042) 0.100 (0.063) -0.036 (0.052) -0.169 (0.464) -0.093 (0.062) 0.206* (0.091) 0.047 (0.084) 0.538 (0.795) 0.100 (0.065) -0.071 (0.088) -0.139* (0.063) -0.861 (0.548) -0.022* (0.009) 0.072 (0.397) -0.219 (0.183) -0.480 (0.037) -0.005 (0.593) 0.364 (1.846) 0.006 (0.014) 0.261 (0.416) -0.116 (0.241) -0.014 (0.038) -0.606 (0.018) 2.441 (2.172) -0.034** (0.011) -0.663 (0.933) 0.632 (1.837) -0.037 (0.318) -0.046 (16.338) 20.758 (39.683) -0.112 (0.250) 1=2 to 4 months -0.159 (0.225) 1=4 to 6 months -1.235** (0.275) Personal and Family characteristics: 1=female -0.290** (0.054) Age -0.002 (0.008) Experience2 -0.002 (0.007) 1=secondary education 0.074 (0.061) 1=tertiary education 0.286** (0.081) 1= bad health -0.391** (0.126) 1=house owner 0.245** (0.057) Household size 0.083** (0.032) Number of kids (<15yo) -0.012 (0.039) (log) hh income3 -0.067* (0.033) 1= zero hh income -0.667* (0.298) Country/Region characteristics: Regional unemployment -0.011* rate4 (0.005) Regional long-term 0.201 (0.236) unemployment rate4 Expenditure in ALMP -0.175 (%GDP)5 (0.101) Share of part-time -0.054** employment5 (0.019) Share of temporary -0.014* employment5 (0.007) Share of public 3.468** employment5 (0.833) Minimum wage (/median wage)5 Average tax rate6 Union density5 Employment protection index5 Year dummies Baseline hazard Observations Subjects Log-likelihood -0.996** (0.214) 0.022** (0.008) -0.014** (0.003) -0.158 (0.102) -0.072 (0.014) 0.039* (0.022) -0.011 (0.007) -0.452 (0.239) -0.088* (0.762) 0.005 (0.032) -0.012* (0.007) -0.256 (0.336) 4.824 (0.140) 0.232 (0.171) -0.054 (0.339) -2.236* (0.879) yes (time, time2, time3) yes (time, time2, time3) yes (time, time2, time3) yes (time, time2, time3) 106268 16813 -36832.70 24080 2703 -9146.90 13757 1661 -4465.21 10323 1042 -4523.81 1. Monthly UI or UA amount / previous wage. UI and UA amounts imputed on the basis of country regulations and personal characteristics (MISSOC, 1993-2001). 2. Years since first entrance in the labour market 3. Income of all other household members. 4. Source: ECHP 5. Source: OECD 6. Income taxes plus social security contributions (employer and employee) over total gross labour costs. Source: OECD Robust standard errors (clustered by individual and year) in parentheses * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1% Table A.2: Proportional Hazard Model for unemployment duration with unobserved heterogeneity— Exits into Jobs All UI recipients [1] Replacement rates: UIρ1 ⋅ (time<=2) -0.288* (0.121) 0.378** UIρ ⋅ (2>time<=6) (0.108) -0.384** UIρ ⋅ (time>6) (0.109) 0.044 UAρ1 (0.000) “Months to UI exhaustion” dummies: 1=less than 2 months -0.003 (0.091) 1=2 to 4 months 0.272** (0.070) 1=4 to 6 months 0.110 (0.061) “Months to UA exhaustion” dummies: 1=less than 2 months 0.205 (0.156) 1=2 to 4 months -0.590** (0.187) 1=4 to 6 months -0.751** (0.197) Personal and Family characteristics: 1=female -0.290** (0.054) Age -0.032** (0.006) Experience2 0.005 (0.005) 1=secondary education 0.244** (0.050) 1=tertiary education 0.245** (0.076) 1= bad health -0.367** (0.090) 1=house owner 0.341** (0.052) Household size -0.071** (0.017) Number of kids (<15yo) 0.163** (0.023) (log) hh income3 -0.104** (0.021) 1= zero hh income -0.811** (0.173) Country/Region characteristics: Regional unemployment -0.035** rate4 (0.005) Regional long-term -0.904** unemployment rate4 (0.171) Expenditure in ALMP -0.245** (%GDP)5 (0.080) Share of part-time 0.020 employment5 (0.014) Share of temporary 0.003 employment5 (0.006) Share of public -1.277 UI recipients, male heads of households with kids [2] Control Treatment [3] [4] 0.193 (0.189) 0.351* (0.169) -0.678** (0.193) -0.074 (0.236) 0.564** (0.208) 0.286 (0.186) -0.954** (0.222) -0.229 (0.359) 0.713 (0.583) 1.376* (0.561) 0.734 (0.576) 0.831 (0.472) -0.010 (0.154) 0.332** (0.120) 0.437** (0.100) 0.618** (0.164) 1.082** (0.125) 0.479** (0.104) -1.205** (0.434) -1.027* (0.420) 0.240 (0.214) 0.079 (0.246) -0.915** (0.256) -1.026** (0.250) -1.935** (0.336) -2.276** (0.316) -1.199** (0.329) 1.503** (0.452) 0.487 (0.486) -0.940* (0.395) - - - -0.053** (0.009) 0.064** (0.009) 0.261* (0.107) 0.831** (0.106) - -0.012 (0.011) -0.020* (0.008) -0.596** (0.088) -0.910** (0.119) - -0.090** (0.016) 0.051** (0.013) 0.078 (0.000) 1.859** (0.169) - - - - -0.201** (0.025) 0.124** (0.029) -0.125** (0.032) -1.067** (0.268) 0.138** (0.040) 0.013 (0.039) -0.270** (0.041) -1.418** (0.394) 0.148** (0.035) -0.200** (0.053) -0.154** (0.043) -0.898* (0.354) -0.030** (0.007) -1.587** (0.317) -1.060** (0.124) -0.061** (0.000) 0.218 (0.007) -2.591** -0.034** (0.010) -0.368 (0.339) -1.116** (0.143) 0.032 (0.010) 0.396 (0.325) 5.604** -0.070** (0.009) -4.154** (0.763) -1.993 (1.031) -0.199* (0.095) -0.346 (0.196) 1.269 employment5 Minimum wage (/median wage)5 Average tax rate6 Union density5 Employment protection index5 Year dummies Baseline hazard Distrbution of heterogeneity (ν) variance of ν Observations Subjects Log-likelihood (0.914) -0.092 (0.270) 0.026** (0.007) 0.004 (0.004) 0.028 (0.076) (0.929) -0.031** (0.020) 0.055** (0.013) 0.004 (0.004) -0.595** (0.133) (1.422) 0.016 (0.025) -0.022 (0.015) 0.020** (0.005) 0.532** (0.178) (23.688) -10.536 (9.861) 0.012 (0.095) -0.267 (0.223) -2.627** (0.523) Yes (time, time2, time3) Yes (time, time2, time3) Yes (time, time2, time3) Yes (time, time2, time3) normal normal normal Normal 1.689** (0.029) 1.935** (0.039) 2.067** (0.051) 2.115** (0.077) 106268 16813 -18275.38 24080 2703 -8419.14 13757 1661 -4826.16 10323 1042 -3401.37 1. Monthly UI or UA amount / previous wage. UI and UA amounts imputed on the basis of country regulations and personal characteristics (MISSOC, 1993-2001). 2. Years since first entrance in the labour market 3. Income of all other household members. 4. Source: ECHP 5. Source: OECD 6. Income taxes plus social security contributions (employer and employee) over total gross labour costs. Source: OECD Robust standard errors (clustered by individual and year) in parentheses * significant at 10%; ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% Appendix B: Descriptive tables of Welfare programmes in European countries Existing schemes Qualifying period1 Duration of payment2 TABLE B1. UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFIT IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (situation on January 2001) Country Rate3 Insurance Variable according to age No limit 60% to 55% initially declining to 44%Belgium 35% as unemployment continues Insurance 52 weeks in the preceding 3 years 1+3 years 90% of reference earnings Denmark (optional) Insurance 12 months in the preceding 3 years Depending on age and contribution Insurance: 60%-67% of net earnings Germany Assistance history (between 12 and 64 months) Assistance: 57%-53% of net earnings Depending on contribution history 40%-50% of earnings Insurance 125 days of work during the 14 Greece (between 5 and 12 months) months preceding job loss or, at least, 200 days of work during the 2 years preceding job loss. Insurance 12 months in the previous 6 years Depending on contribution history Insurance: 70%-60% of reference Spain Assistance earnings Assistance: 75% of minimum wage Insurance least 4 months insurance in last 18 Depending on age and contribution Insurance: 40.4%-57.4% of earnings, France Assistance months. history (between 4 and 60 months) declining. Assistance: lump sum Insurance 39 weeks’ contributions paid 390 days Insurance: 98€ per week Ireland Assistance Assistance: 97-98€ per week Insurance Varies according to the industry Depending on the industry (180 days 30%-80% of earnings Italy or 90 days or 36 months) Insurance 26 weeks of employment during the 365+182 days 80% of earnings Luxembourg last year Insurance: 70% of earnings Insurance 26 weeks of employment during the 6 months+ 9 months to 5 years Netherlands Assistance: 70% of minimum wage Assistance last 39 months depending on age and employment history. Insurance 52 weeks during the last 24 months Depending on age and contribution Insurance: 55% of earnings + lump Austria Assistance history (between 20 to 78 weeks) sum Assistance: 92-95% of unemployment insurance Insurance 540 days during the last 24 months Depending on age (between 12 and 30 Insurance: 65% of earnings Portugal Assistance months) Assistance: 70%-100% of minimum wage Insurance 43 weeks of employment during the 500 days Insurance: lump sum (21€ per day) + Finland Assistance last 24 months earning related supplement Assistance: lump sum (21€ per day) Insurance 6 months of employment Depending on age (between 300 and Insurance: 80% of earnings Sweden 450 days) 182 days Insurance Contributions paid in one of the 2 tax Insurance: lump sum (65-83€ per United Kingdom Assistance years on which the claim is based week) amounting to at least 25 times the Assistance: lump sum (99-130€ per minimum contribution for that year week for a couple) (1) Qualifying periods refer to working periods during which contributions are paid unless otherwise specified. (2) When duration is expressed in days these usually refer to a 5 or 6 day weekly payments. Duration usually refers only to insurance schemes, unemployment assistance is typically unlimited. (3) When different rates are specified for the same scheme, the actual rate depends on family characteristics, age, contribution history or duration of unemployment. Only basic rates are reported, excluding any supplement (family, old age, etc.) Source: European Commission Missoc 2001. Spain Greece Germany Denmark Belgium Invalidity pension Invalidity pension Invalidity pension Invalidity benefit Invalidity pension Invalidity benefit Type of benefit Eligible only after 12 months of sickness benefit 66.66% 33% 50% 50% 50% 66.66% minimum level of incapacity1 5 years of contributions 260 contributions’ weeks 12 months of work with sufficient contributions paid Worked 1/2 of the time between age 20 and the claim Between 5 and 15 years of work with 300 to 1500 contributions’ days (depending on age) 60 months of work with 36 months of contributions in the previous 5 years Until retirement Until retirement Until retirement Until retirement Until retirement Until retirement Until retirement Depends on incapacity Depends on contribution records Depends on income and contribution records Depends on age (103-128€ per week) 30%-50% of annual earnings 50%-100% of reference earnings Depends on incapacity Amount of benefit2 France Invalidity pension •66% •100% 12 months in the previous 3 years Until retirement Depends on income Duration Ireland •Invalidity pension •Incapacity benefit Eligible if invalidity prevents the beneficiary form doing his last job (or a similar one) None Until retirement Depends on contribution records Qualifying conditions Italy Invalidity pension 25% 60 contributions’ months in the previous 120 months Until retirement Depends on age Country Luxembourg Invalidity pension 50% 5 years Until retirement 25%-100% of basic pension TABLE B2. INVALIDITY BENEFITS IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (situation on January 2001) Netherlands Invalidity pension 66.66% 3 years of residence Until retirement 40-65% of last earnings Austria Invalidity pension 40% Residence in Sweden Until retirement Portugal Invalidity pension 25% Until retirement Finland Invalidity pension Lump sum Depends on age. 6 months of contributions with 120 days worked 3 years of residence Sweden •364 days •Until retirement Depends on incapacity (from 6.855€ to 18.012€ per year) Depends on incapacity United Kingdom 100% •Short-term invalidity •Enough contributions paid •Long-term invalidity •Having exhausted short-term invalidity benefit (1) Reduced capacity of earning or work unless otherwise specified. (2) When a range is specified this usually varies with age and contribution records. Source: European Commission Missoc 2001. Portugal Austria Netherlands Luxembourg Italy Ireland France Spain Greece Germany Denmark Belgium No Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes Yes No No Income Test 16 16 15 to 24 19 to 26 17 to 24 18 to 27 18 16 to 19 18 to 20 18 18 to 22 18 18 18 to 25 Age Limit1 Depends on the number of children Depends on the number of children Depends on the number of children Depends on the number of children Depends on the number of children Depends on the number and age of the children Depends on the number and age of the children Depends on family and number of children Depends on the number and age of the children Depends on the number of children Depends on the age of the child Depends on the number of children Depends on the number of children Depends on the age of the child Depends on the age of the child Calculation of benefit Yes Yes Yes No No No No Yes Yes Yes No Only for widows No Yes No Supplement for single parents Finland No 16 to 19 Country Sweden No TABLE B3. FAMILY CASH BENEFITS IN EUROPEAN COUNTRIES (situation on January 2001) United Kingdom (1) Benefits are paid until the child reaches this age limit, which is extended for children in training or higher education. Source: European Commission Missoc 2001. Luxembourg Italy Ireland France Spain Greece Denmark Belgium Housing benefit Housing Supplement for those under RMI No direct benefit but social housing is available Housing Supplement for those under Social Welfare Allowance Housing benefit No general housing benefit but some regions have introduced one. No direct benefit but a tax allowance for house rents is available. • General housing benefit (open to everybody) • Special housing benefit (for those receiving income support) Housing benefit No direct benefit but social housing is available Means tested Varies across regions • Means test • Receiving RMI Means tested • Means test • Receiving Social Welfare Allowance - • Means test • Children in the household • Married for less than 5 years - • Means test • Occurrence of a negative “ social event” that affects housing. Means test - Depending on income Varies across regions Depending on income and rent Depending on Income Depending on income, rent and family composition - Income related - Calculation of benefit Netherlands Housing Supplement for those under Social Assistance (but it varies across regions) Depending on income, family composition and town of residence Qualifying conditions Austria Housing Supplement for those under RMI Means tested Depending on income, rent and family composition Type of Benefit Portugal • Housing benefit for low income households • Housing benefit for pensioners • Housing benefit for students Means tested Country TABLE B4. HOUSING BENEFITS IN EUROPE (situation in 1999) Finland • Housing benefit for low income households • Housing supplement for social assistance recipients • Housing benefit for pensioners Means tested Depending on Income - Depending on income, family composition and rent Sweden Housing benefit Germany United Kingdom Depending on income and rent. Special supplements for those under Income Support, young and old households. Source: OECD, Benefit System ad Work Incentives (2002). Denomination TABLE B5. LOW-INCOME BENEFITS IN EUROPE (situation on January 2001) Qualifying conditions Country Willingness to work requirement1 Yes Duration Unlimited Yes - 3 to 12 months 12 months - Yes Yes Yes - Minimum de Moyens d’Existence (MIMEX) Unlimited Greece Renta Minima Unlimited Varies across towns Belgium • Nationals and refugees • Resident in the country • Aged 18y.o. and above All persons Spain Revenu Minimum d’Insertion (RMI) Varies across towns Yes Sozial Bistand France Supplementary Welfare Allowance Unlimited Yes Denmark Ireland Minimo Vitale/Reddito Minimo • Resident in the country • Aged 18y.o. and above Unlimited Yes Unlimited Italy2 Revenu Minimum Garanti Unlimited Yes Sozialhilfe Luxembourg Algemene Bijstand • • • • 12 months, extendible Yes Germany Netherlands Sozialhilfe • Resident in the country • Aged 18y.o. and above Unlimited Yes • National and refugees • Resident in the country Austria Rendimento Minimo Garantido None Unlimited - Portugal3 Toimeentulotuki None Nationals and refugees Resident in the country Aged 18y.o. and above Resident in the country • Nationals and refugees • Resident in the country • Aged 18y.o. and above Vary across towns Resident in the country Aged between 25 and 65y.o. Resident in the country Aged 25y.o. and above Finland Social Bidrag • • • • Sweden United Kingdom Income Support Unlimited Yes • Nationals • Resident in the country • Aged 18y.o. and above (1) For those who are able to work. (2) There is no national legal framework for income support. Many towns, however, have introduced a minimum income scheme but rules vary widely across the nation. In 1998 an experiment was run in 39 towns with the objective of introducing a national minimum income scheme by the year 2000. The experiment has been extended to 2002 and then abandoned. (3) Introduced in 1997. Source: European Commission Missoc 2001.