Lecture 7: Globalization & international trade 1 By now, hopefully familiar with the trend in international trade over the past 200 years. That is, trade went up and by a lot with increases along two margins, the extensive and intensive. What is striking in the aggregate, though, is the apparent regularity of this growth. What forces govern this pattern? Introduction 2 Introduction 3 Remaining question for this week: What are the long-run determinants of trade? 1.) Particularly, what determines its composition? Or who trades what with whom? 2.) And what determines its dimensions? Or who trades how much with whom? Introduction 4 We have already considered one approach to explaining the composition of trade. The Heckscher-Ohlin (HO) model was used by O’Rourke and Williamson to explain the Great Specialization. Their evidence seemed to indicate that commodity price convergence Revisiting HO 5 A recap on HO: it critical assumptions 1.) Endowments of factors of production assumed to be different across countries. 2.) Factor intensities across industries assumed to be different. --------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- 3.) 4.) Revisiting HO 6 A recap on HO: it critical implications 1.) Stolper-Samuelson Theorem: an increase in the relative price of a good will increase the real return to the factor used intensively in the production of that good. 2.) Factor price equalization: free trade will tend Revisiting HO 7 A recap on HO: it historical application The 1800s saw trade costs fall and trade boom, inducing commodity price convergence. HO predicts that the UK will have exported manufacturers and NA will have exported agricultural goods and other commodities. Revisiting HO 8 And what about relative factor returns? In the UK, the formerly scarce factor (land) suffers while the formerly abundant factor (labor) benefits…w/r should increase. In NA, the formerly scarce factor (labor) suffers while the formerly abundant factor (land) benefits…w/r should decrease. Revisiting HO 9 But the success of HO in explaining trade patterns during the Great Specialization probably not all that surprising. Written at the time (indeed, a little after the fact); also, based on close empirical observation of trade patterns. Revisiting HO 10 By far, extending and testing the HO model was the predominant activity in international trade literature from 1950s into 1980s (and beyond). It all started with Leontief (1953)—the first attempt to confront the model with data. Building on work on constructing input-output Leontief’s paradox 11 Input-output coefficients combined with trade data to compute amounts of L and K used in the production of US exports and imports. Last element calculated by applying the same US input-output matrix for all of its trading partners. Assuming same matrix implies same technology (that is, same efficiency in transforming input into output). Leontief’s paradox 12 Exports Imports Capital Requirement (millions of USD) A(Kx) = 2.55 A(Km) = 3.09 Labor Requirement (person-years) A(Lx) = 182.31 A(Lm) = 170.11 By taking the ratio of the K and L requirements, we can find the amount of capital used by each worker in the production of X and M. K/Lx = kx = $2.55 million / 182.31 = $13,987 Leontief’s paradox 13 This implies that km = 1.30 kx. This gave rise to Leontief’s paradox: US imports were 30% more K-intensive than US exports. But how could this possibly be? In 1947, the US held approximately 60% of the world’s capital stock Leontief’s paradox 14 Proposed solutions for the paradox: 1.) disaggregated factors of production; Leontief only used K and L, but there are more. 2.) 1947 was unrepresentative; WWII just ended and global economy not back on its feet. 3.) US was not engaged in free trade Leontief’s paradox 15 Big assumption of common worldwide technology embedded in input-output matrix: a bad precedent which Leontief fought. Lead to many negative results, but little information on sources of HO’s failure: 1.) 2.) 3.) Leontief’s paradox 16 One of the chief criticisms of Leontief’s study was the crude classification of K and L. This, of course, followed the classic HO model of a 2x2x2 world that we have seen before. But this was obviously unrealistic, even in the world of 1947. Revising HO 17 Even with just three factors and two countries, it can become messy: K/L>K*/L* and R*/L*>R/L does not imply anything about K/R or K*/R*. Normalization matters; most convenient way of comparing across countries and factors is to normalize by GDP shares. Revising HO 18 At the same time, want to allow for corrections in the raw data used to compare endowments. For example, labor endowments could be measured by population, but what if demographics were different across countries. Likewise, land endowments could be measured by land mass, but what if soil quality differs. Revising HO 19 Revising HO 20 Allowing for more factors and differences in factors, researchers have been able to retest HO theory by using ―the sign test‖: Sign of (country’s share of effective factor minus country’s share of world GDP) Revising HO 21 Leading us to the question: what is the factor content of net exports exactly? Most directly, the factor content of exports minus the factor content of imports; anything more? Most importantly, it measures the amounts of each factor used to produce exports and imports. Revising HO 22 The example from before: the US in 1947 Exports Imports Capital Requirement (millions of USD) A(Kx) = 2.55 A(Km) = 3.09 Labor Requirement (person-years) A(Lx) = 182.31 A(Lm) = 170.11 Gross exports of 16,700 million USD and gross imports of 6,200 million USD. Revising HO 23 K content of gross exports = 16,700 * 2.55 m USD = 42,585 m USD L content of gross exports = 16,700 * 182.31 = 3,044,577 p-years K content of gross imports = 6,200 * 3.09 m USD = 19,158 m USD Revising HO 24 K content of net exports = 42,585 – 19,158 = 23,427 m USD L content of net exports = 3,044,577 – 1,054,682 = 1,989,895 p-years Because both positive, sign test would predict that US’s share of world K and L (60% and 8%) Revising HO 25 Moving towards the more recent past, Trefler is the definitive work on completely testing HO (data on endowments, trade, and technology). His data: f = 9 factors (K, 6 labor, 2 land) for c = 33 countries (high, middle, & low income). 33 countries x 9 factors = 297 sign tests versus Leontief’s 2; implies a lot more power. The missing trade puzzle 26 Looking at the sign test over all of these possible combinations, Trefler finds that the success rate is again 50/50. The underlying equation for his sign test is: Ffc= Vfc − scVfw Ffc= c’s factor content of net exports for factor f Vfc= c’s endowment of f The missing trade puzzle 27 Thus, if c effectively exports f (on net), then Ffc>0 → Vfc−scVfw>0 → Vfc>scVfw → Vfc/Vfw>sc But let’s also think about the errors generated by the predictions of HO and define the following: Errorfc = In the strict HO world, Efc should equal zero. For the weaker sign test, we would expect there to be at least a positive correlation between The missing trade puzzle 28 If Ffc = 0, then Efc = −(Vfc − scVfw)…45º line The missing trade puzzle The missing trade puzzle Suggests there is much more going on… obvious candidate is technological differences. All countries & the sign test: 50% High GDP countries: 59% Middle GDP countries: 48% Low GDP countries: 38% Once Trefler corrects for these, accuracy of sign test ranges from 59 to 66% The missing trade puzzle 31 A few other issues emerge in considering relative factor endowments as the only determinant of the composition of international trade. It is silent about role of monopolistic competition & rise of intra-industry trade from 1950s. It is silent about role of firms (especially MNCs) & rise of vertical specialization from 1970s. Moving beyond HO 32 As it turns out, many of these perspectives can be integrated by considering trade costs. Trade costs: Could potentially include: 1.) freight & time costs 2.) tariffs & non-tariff barriers 3.) costs from the use of different currencies 4.) … Moving beyond HO 33 A large literature accounting for trade costs and how they explain the volume of bilateral trade. The workhorse of empirical international trade: the gravity model. Relates bilateral volumes of trade to GDP and measures of trade costs. Moving beyond HO 34 But why ―gravity‖? M1 M 2 Fg G 2 d GDP1 GDP2 Trade12 B dn Here, B is a term which will include many trade cost elements (not related to distance). Moving beyond HO 35 Beyond agreement with common sense, gravity model is also attractive in that: 1.) it is consistent with competing models of trade; tells us how consumers allocate spending, given patterns of specialization and trade costs. 2.) it allows us to estimate trade costs over time. Moving beyond HO 36 Moving beyond HO 37 Moving beyond HO 38 Moving beyond HO 39 In trying to chart the composition and dimensions of trade, we began with HO. Its broad relevance for the 19th century and early 20th century explains its continued use. But while endowments still matter, we also need to think about other issues now related to patterns on production and specialization. Conclusion 40