Centre for Economic Policy Research Center for Economic Studies Maison des Sciences de l'Homme Is the Crisis Problem Growing More Severe? Author(s): Michael Bordo, Barry Eichengreen, Daniela Klingebiel, Maria Soledad MartinezPeria, Andrew K. Rose Source: Economic Policy, Vol. 16, No. 32 (Apr., 2001), pp. 53-82 Published by: Blackwell Publishing on behalf of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, and the Maison des Sciences de l'Homme Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3601034 Accessed: 16/12/2008 14:22 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Centre for Economic Policy Research, Center for Economic Studies, Maison des Sciences de l'Homme, Blackwell Publishing are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economic Policy. http://www.jstor.org SUMMARY The crisisproblemis one of the dominantmacroeconomicfeatures of our age. Its prominencesuggestsquestionslike thefollowing:Are crisesgrowingmorefrequent? Are economiestakinglongerto recover?These Are theybecomingmoredisruptive? historical questions,which can be answeredonlyby comparing arefundamentally thepresentwith thepast. To this end, this paper developsand analysesa data base spanning120years offinancial history.Wefind that crisisfrequencysince 1973 has beendoublethat of the Bretton Woods and classicalgold standard periodsand is rivalledonl by the crisis-ridden1920s and 1930s. Historythus confirmsthat thereis somethingdfferentand disturbingaboutour age. However, thereis little evidencethat criseshavegrown longeror outputlosseshave become larger.Crisesmay havegrown morefrequent,in otherwords, but theyhave not obviouslygrown more severe. Our explanationfor the growingfrequencyand chroniccosts of crisesfocuses on the combinationof capital mobiliy and the financial safety net, including the implicit insuranceagainst exchangerisk provided by an ex ante crediblepolicy of pegging the exchangerate, which encouragesbanks and corporationsto accumulateexcessiveforeign currency for restoringstability and exposures.We also providepolicy recommendations growth. - ichael Bordo,Barry Eichengreen,Daniela Klingebieland Maria SoledadMartinez-Peria Economic Policy April 2001 Printed in Great Britain ? CEPR, CES, MSH, 2001. 53 53 FINANCIAL CRISES Is the more crisis severe? problem growing MichaelBordo, BarryEichengreen,Daniela Klingebieland MariaSoledad Martinez-Peria RutgersUniversity;Universityof California,Berkeley;WorldBank;WorldBank 1. INTRODUCTION The crisisproblem was one of the dominant featuresof the 1990s. Financial historiesof the decade, when they are ultimatelywritten,will undoubtedlybe organized around the European exchange rate crisis of 1992-3, the Tequila crisis of 1994-5, the Asian crisis of 1997-8, the Braziliancrisisof 1998-9, and the Russia-LTCM affair.That so many episodes of financialturbulenceand distresswere packed into so few years points to what is new and troubling about the economic and financial environment in which we currentlylive. Or does it? The premise implicitin many accounts of the most recent decade, that the crisisproblem is growing more severe, is just that - implicit. Remarkably,policymakers and scholarscan nowhere find a systematic,quantitative,empiricalstudy on whose basis the questionposed in the title of our paper can be addressed.Even that handfulof studies which compares the 1990s with the immediately preceding decades (e.g., International Monetary Fund, 1998; Caprio and Klingebiel, 1999) should create some uneasiness on the part of those presuming that ours is a distinctive age of financial instability.Their We are gratefulto Tamim Bayoumi, Filippo Cesarano, Henri Delanghe, Caroline Fohlin, Per Hanson, LarsJonung,Jan Tore Klovland, Rolf Luders,Jaime Reis, Georg Rich, Ranil Selgado, Alan Taylor, Gail Triner, and Penti Varti for help with data. For able assistancewe thank Carlos Arteta, Sonal Dhingra, Galina Hale, Elena Goldman, Chris Meissner,Antu Murshid and Ivanna Vladkova-Hollar.We thank Richard Baldwin, Richard Portes, Andrew Rose, and Charles Wyplosz for suggestions. The World Bank Research Committee and the NBER provided financial support. None of the opinions expressed here are necessarilythose of the World Bank or of any other organizationwith which the authors are affiliated. 54 54 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. crisis chronologies suggest that currency and banking crises were chronic problems not just in the 1990s but in the precedingyears as well. Anyone old enough to rememberthe 1980s will not be surprised.Is it really true, in other words, that the crisis problem is growing more severe? A comparison of the 1980s with the 1990s is hardly an adequate basis for generalization,of course. In this paper we thereforeelaboratethe comparisonalong four dimensions. First, we compare the recent period with more than a century of financial crises, distinguishing the Bretton Woods period (1945-71), the interwar years (1919-39), and the gold standardera (1880-1913). Second, we extend the comparison from the frequencyof crises to their depth and duration. Third, we compare the output losses from crises with the output losses from recessions in which no crises occurred. Fourthand finally,we ask whether the patternswe observe in the frequency,severityand longevity of crises are best explicable in terms of international economic policies (the flexibility of the exchange rate and the openness of the capital account) or the management of the domestic financial system. It will be evident that these two sets of variables correspond to the two leading explanations for the recent Asian crisis, one which attributesits outbreak and severityto internationaleconomic policies (unsustainable currency pegs and precipitous capital-account liberalization), the other which blames it on flawed domestic financial regulation. This illustrateshow our findings can be used to shed light on the generality of popular explanations for the recent spate of crises. By placing contemporaryexperience in its historicalcontext, we hope to be able to determine what conclusionsshould be drawn from recent crises about the operation of internationalcapital markets.For some, the frequencyand severityof crisesin the 1990s point to the dangers of financial liberalizationand the inability of financial marketsto allocateresourcesefficiently.For others,the crisisproblemreflectsnot the risksof financial liberalizationand the inefficiencyof deregulated markets but rather the tendency for governments to run monetary and fiscal policies inconsistentwith exchange-rate and financial stability and for national and international authorities to weaken market disciplineby indiscriminatelyprovidingcapitaland liquiditysupportto distressedfinancial institutionsand bailing out depositors and creditorsof these institutions.An historical perspectivecan help to determinewhich of these views is more generallyapplicable.Is the crisisproblem most severe in periods when financialmarketsare liberalizedand capital accountsare open? Has it grown with the propensityof governmentsto provide domestic financialinstitutionswith liquidityand capitalsupport?Questionssuch as these can only be answeredby comparingthe 1990s with earlierperiods. We detail our crisis identificationmethodology and discuss the main features of the data in the next section. After that, we study whether crises make recessions worse (Section 3), whether capital controls affect the frequency of crises (Section 4), and how policy affectscrisisseverity(Section 5). Our conclusionsand policy recommendationsare in the final section. A 'Web Appendix', which provides more detail on our data and methods, can be found on http://www.economic-policy.org. CRISES FINANCIAL CRISES FINANCIAL 55 2. COUNTING CRISES Since any study of crises turns on how these events are identified, the first order of business is to describe how we isolate them. (For additional details, see the Web Appendix available at http://www.economic-policy.org.) 2.1. How to spot a crisis We define financial crises as episodes of financial-marketvolatilitymarked by significant problems of illiquidity and insolvency among financial-marketparticipantsand/or by officialinterventionto contain such consequences.For an episode to qualifyas a banking crisis, we must observe financial distress resulting in the erosion of most or all of aggregate banking system capital, as in Caprio and Klingebiel (1996, 1999). For an episode to qualify as a currency crisis, we must observe a forced change in parity, abandonment of a pegged exchange rate, or an international rescue. In addition, we construct the familiar index of exchange market pressure (calculated as a weighted average of exchange rate change, short-terminterest rate change, and reserve change relative to the same for the centre country, the UK before 1913 and the US after).A crisisis said to occur when this index exceeds a criticalthreshold.We score an episode as a currency crisis when it shows up according to either or both of these indicators. Sometimes, crises come in waves, with a new one breaking out before recovery from its predecessor is complete. Attempting to calculate separate recovery times or output losses in such cases is problematic (it would not be clear, for example, which part of the output loss should be attributed to which event). Successive crises that erupt before recovery from a first crisis is complete are therefore scored as one event. For the entire 120-year period, we have data for 21 countries, which we follow through time. To facilitatecomparisonswith other studieswe also consider for the post1973 period a larger sample of 56 economies. The complete list of crisescan be found in the Web Appendix mentioned above. 2.2. Severity and frequency To quantifythe depth and durationof crises,we compute the trend rate of GDP growth for the five years preceding the event. Recovery time, that is, crisisduration,is calculated as the number of years before GDP growth returnsto that trend. Crisisdepth is then the output loss, which we calculate by cumulating from the onset to the recovery - the differencebetween pre-crisistrend growth and actual growth. Plainly, there is no single - or, for that matter, best - way of measuringthese output losses. Mulder and Rocha (2000) argue that the approach used here will overstate such losses because pre-crisis growth tends to be unsustainably high, rendering it an inappropriatebasis for comparison.They also observe that truncatingthe calculationat the point where the growth rate returnsto trend will understatethe loss because the level 56 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. of output, as distinct from the growth rate, remains depressed for several subsequent years. But there is no reason to think that these biases are more severe in one period than another. Since we are concerned with intertemporal comparisons, such biases are likely to be of less moment here than in other applications. Comparing the behaviour of output around crises with its behaviour around recessions requires data for the latter. While for the US we have NBER dates, similar dates do not exist for all 21 countries we consider before 1971 or for the even larger country sample we consider subsequently. We therefore used a statistical technique called the 'band-pass filter' (see Stock and Watson, 1999) to date recessions. (Intuitively, the band-pass filter identifies dates when a country's growth rate slips below its trend; a more technical discussion can be found in the Web Appendix.) For the US there is reasonable conformance between the NBER dates and those obtained using the filter. There are reasons to worry about the consistency of the business cycle properties of GDP statistics spanning more than a century. For the United States, Romer (1989) and Balke and Gordon (1989) have attempted to adjust the historical statistics for cyclical consistency with modern data. Reassuringly, previous studies of the changing length and severity of recessions have obtained similar results using these alternative series. Figure 1 summarizes the frequency of crises (the number of crises divided by the number of country-year observations, by period), immediately suggesting that the crisis problem has grown since 1973. The bar at the far right, indicating a frequency of 12.2% 14O2 10 _ L. 0. Q" i i2 188191 1919199 19 1880-1913 1919-1939 1945-1971 191 19 199 1973-1997 19 1 1973-1997 (21 countries) (56 countries) * Banking crises O Currency crises Figure 1. Crisis frequency, 1880-1997 Source: Authors' calculations. 1 Twin crises E All crises FINANCIAL FINANCITAT, CRISES CRISES 57 57 for our 56-countrysample for the post-1972 period, means that these countrieshave had a nearly one in eight chance of sufferinga currencycrisis,banking crisis,or twin crisisin a given year. The firstthree sets of bars show that this is high by historicalstandards- for example, it is nearly 2? times the 1880-1913 rate. The pre-1913 comparison thus suggests that crises at the rate we have been experiencing them are not an inevitable corollaryof globalization. 2.3. Currency crises Figure 1 also makes clear that it is the frequencyof currencycrisesthat explainswhy the rate of incidence has been so great since 1973. Only in the Bretton Woods period (1945-71) does one see an incidence of currency crises nearly as great.1 The lesser frequency of currencycrisesbefore 1913, when capital controlswere absent and capital mobility reached high levels, challenges the notion that it is financial globalization,pure and simple, that has created instability in foreign exchange markets. Rather, there appears to be an increase in the incidence of currency crises over time, as if factors in addition to financial integration, which has a U-shaped time profile, influence their incidence. The trend is not monotonic, however; the frequency of currency crises declines after 1972 when we follow the 21-countrysample throughout.(Moreover,there are signs of a further decline in the frequency of currency crises after the mid-1980s in the larger sample as well.) But this only reinforces our point that the extent of capital mobility is not a sufficientexplanation for the frequency of currency crises. One interpretationof the rise of currencycrisesargues that democratizationhas made it more difficultfor governmentsto crediblycommit to exchange rate stabilizationand to subordinate all other goals of policy to the maintenance of a currency peg (e.g., Eichengreen, 1996 andJeanne, 1997). As a result,currencypegs lack the credibilitythey of capital mobility and possessedbefore 1913. The implicationis that it is the combination democratization not capital mobility per se that has undermined the credibilityof exchange rate commitments and made currencypegs more fragile. 2.4. Banking and twin crises The period of exceptional instabilityfor banking and twin criseswas the interwarperiod. Aficionadosof the Great Depressionwill not be surprised.Disturbingly,however, our era is close behind. In contrast, banking crises were almost non-existent in the heyday of BrettonWoods, something that was not also true of currencycrises,as we saw a moment ago. Thus, while the tight regulation of domestic and international capital markets, which characterizedthe world followingWorld War II, suppressedbanking crisesalmost 1Some may wish to dismisssome of these recent episodes as 'pseudo currencycrises'on the ground that they may not have had the same negative repercussionson the real economy as currencycrises occurringin some earlierperiods. In fact, as we show below, the averageoutput loss due to currencycriseshas been broadlysimilarsince 1973, in the BrettonWoods years, and even before 1913. Recent currency crises are not pseudo crises in terms of the associated output loss. 58 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. completely in the 1950s and 1960s, controls on capital flows were less successful in suppressing currency crises. Moreover, the contrast with 1880-1913, when the incidence of both banking and twin crises was lower, again suggeststhat blame for the frequencyof crisestoday cannot simplybe laid on the doorstepof financialliberalization - such liberalizationwas equally prevalent before 1913. The difference in results for the two post-1972 samples (for 21 and 56 countries) reveals where the greater frequency is concentrated, namely, in the additional developing countries included in the larger sample, which tend to be younger, smaller, and less developed. There is still an increase in crisis frequencywhen we stick with the 21-countrysample, but it is less pronounced. Indeed, a detailedlook at the data (see Web Appendix) suggests that crises have always tended to be predominantly an emergingmarket problem, with over 75% of pre-1913 crises occurring in emerging market nations, although the Great Depression, when financial stabilityin the industrialcentre became a casualty, is a prominent exception. (More than 75% of crises in this period were centred in industrialcountries.)In an arithmeticsense, a large part of this change stems from the fact that a number of nineteenth century emerging marketshad become industrialeconomies by the interwaryears; this led us to reclassifynine of our pre-1913 emerging nations into industrialnations post-1919. Thus, not too much should be read into these particularnumbers. But there is still an economic point. Earlierscholarshave contrastedthe stabilityof the centre with the instabilityof the peripheryunder the gold standard (Triffin, 1964; de Cecco, 1974) while observing that the crisis problem gravitatedto the centre between the wars (BernankeandJames, 1991). Our results are consistentwith this interpretation. Readers may be wonderingwhether criseshave been growingmore frequentwithinthe most recentperiod.We thereforedividedthe 1973-97 period in two, taking 1988 (the eve of large-scaleportfoliocapitalflowsto emergingmarkets)as the dividingline. Interestingly, it turns out that currency crises were actually more prevalent in 1973-87 than subsequently(frequenciesfor two periods are 8.8% and 5.6% respectively).What have been on the rise, however, are bankingcrisesand, therefore,twin crises,whose frequency increased quite noticeably between sub-periods.Specifically,the frequency of banking crisesdoubles in the 21-countrysample between the two periods,and risesby 50% in the 56-countrysample. This points clearlyto what is new and troublingabout our age. 2.5. Duration and depth of crises Table 1 shows that the story for duration differs sharply from the story for frequency. Currencycriseswere significantlylonger prior to 1913 than since 1973, a contrastthat is most dramaticfor the industrialcountries(see Web Appendix on http://www.economicpolicy.org). However, the other periods are basically indistinguishable.The opposite holds for twin crises;the number of years needed to recover from the events, ratherthan falling,has been rising,again most noticeablyin the industrialcountries.The durationof banking crises,by contrast,seems little changed over our sample. Put these cross-cutting FINANCIALCRISES 59 Table 1. Duration and depth of crises All countries 1880-1913 1919-1939 1945-1971 1973- 1997 21 nations 1973-1997 56 nations Currency crises Banking crises Twin crises All crises 2.6 2.3 2.2 2.4 Average duration of crises in years 1.9 1.8 1.9 a 2.4 3.1 2.7 1.0 3.7 2.4 1.8 2.6 2.1 2.6 3.8 2.5 Currency crises Banking crises Twin crises All crises 8.3 8.4 14.5 9.8 Average crisis depth (cumulativeGDP loss in %) 14.2 3.8 5.2 a 10.5 7.0 15.8 1.7 15.7 13.4 5.2 7.8 5.9 6.2 18.6 8.3 Notes:a indicates no crises Source: Authors'calculations. trends together and it follows that there is little sign of consistent change in crisis duration over time. The resumption rule. These findings constitute a significant challenge to the conventional wisdom, represented by Goodhart and Delargy (1999). Those authors argue that countries should have recovered from currency crises more quickly under the 2.5.1. gold standard than today owing to the so-called 'resumption rule' (countries forced off their gold standard pegs often sought to resume convertibility at the pre-crisis parity once the crisis passed). Awareness of this resumption rule should have stabilized capital flows, as foreign funds flowed back in, in anticipation of the capital gains that would accrue when the exchange rate was pushed back up. This return of flight capital, Goodhart and Delargy argue, should have fostered swift recovery. They then review the historical record for the pre-1913 period and conclude that it is consistent with their view. This, however, is not what we find. In our larger sample of pure currency crises, average recovery time was shorter after 1973 than before 1913 (2.1 versus 2.6 years), not longer as Goodhart and Delargy suggest.2 Because strong policy recommendations have been based on the conventional wisdom, this finding is noteworthy. Hanke (1998), for instance, suggests that the Asian crisis countries should have somehow restored their currencies to pre-crisis levels to stabilize expectations and regain investor confidence. McKinnon (2000a,b) cites the Goodhart-Delargy finding in arguing that East Asian countries should establish official dollar parities and commit to returning to them after any crisis. Our findings suggest that such recommendations should be taken with a grain of salt. 2The Goodhart-Delargy conclusion is based on analysisof only six episodes. Moreover, we categorize some of their currency crisesas twin crises(Italy, 1894 and 1908, Argentina, 1890) or bankingcrises(Australia,1893). The resumption-ruleargument does not obviouslylead one to expect rapid recoveryfrom banking crises,and indeed the speed of recoveryfrom pure banking crises was almost exactly the same before 1913 as after 1972. 60 60 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. 2.5.2. Crisis depth and mix. The overall impression left by this comparison of crisis durationis how little has changed. The question then becomes whether the same is true of other aspects of these events. As Table 1 shows, the figures on crisis depth, like duration, do not suggest that the crisisproblem is growing more severe. The output loss from currencycrises is only a half to two-thirdstoday what it was in the prior age of globalization.The output loss from banking crises is only 75% to 80% today what it was between 1880 and 1913. Only twin crises may have grown more severe, and the difference is slight. The differencesthat do stand out are the exceptional severityof crises (of all kinds)in the interwar years and the importance of mix. Particularlyimpressive are the large output losses as a resultof currencycrisesin the 1920s and 1930s (nearlytwice as large as in 1880-1913; nearly three times as large as under Bretton Woods and today). Twin crises, especially in emerging economies, were also more severe than in other periods. For banking crises, the pattern is muted but still there. The importanceof mix is evident in the comparisonof the BrettonWoods period with today. Consideringall crises, output loss is much larger today, but this is entirely due to the composition effect;output loss from each type of crisishas basicallybeen stable, but banking and twin crises - which are more severe than currency crises - are more prominent in today's mix. Not all of the criseswe identifyare associatedwith output losses. In fact, no recession accompaniedabout a quarterof crisessince 1973 (seethe Web Appendix).The exceptions, not surprisingly,are the twin crises,which are alwaysdisruptiveto growth.The patternis similar for earlier historicalperiods, although there are variations.For example, crises more uniformlycaused output lossesprior to 1913 than in the BrettonWoods or interwar years. Reassuringly,little changes when we limit the sample to criseswith output losses. Overall, then, crisis depth and duration tell similar stories. While crises have grown more frequent,they have not grown more severe. If anything, the durationof crises and their output losses were greater in the period of globalizationleading up to 1913. The Great Depression and Bretton Woods periods were different,the former because of the exceptionalseverityof both currencyand bankingcrises,the latterfor the virtualabsence of banking crises.But if these differencesare prominent, the similaritiesare, if anything, more prominent still. 3. DO CRISES MAKE RECESSIONS WORSE? These output losses from crises are less impressiveif they are indistinguishablefrom the output losses in recessions not accompanied by crises. While crises often occur in recessions,it could be that the occurrenceof a crisisadds nothing to the severityof those recessions,and that all we are picking up is the output effects of the latter. To find out, we measure the severity of a recession by cumulating output losses, startingfrom the firstyear following the business-cyclepeak and continuing to the year when growth returnsto its pre-crisistrend. For recessionswith crises,we again cumulate 61 61 FINANCIAL CRISES output loses from the beginning of the recession even if the crisis comes several years into the recession.3 The results, in Figure 2 (top panel), confirm that recessions with crises are more severe than recessions without them. This is true for virtually every period and type of country considered. The contrast is most pronounced in the interwar period - not surprisingly, 1 GDP loss I and without with 30.0 I ii 25.0 V) V) 20.0 - I~ Ii 0 a. 0 * crises I I iI 41 15.0- L 1. I 10.0 1 5.00.0 1E880-1913 1919-1939 Average , recovery I w PI I~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ I L-- Il I I 1945-1971 I 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 nations) (56 nations) time with l and without I crises 5.0 4.0 3.0 UL 2.0 1.0 0.0 1880-1913 Figure 2. Recessions 1919-1939 with and without 1945-1971 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 nations) (56 nations) crises Source: Authors'calculations. 3We also calculatedcumulativeloss dated from the crisisonset. The general patternis the same but the magnitudeof the loss is obviously smaller. 62 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. MICHAELBORDO ETAL. given the importanceattached to crisesin accounts of the Great Depression. Our age, in other words, is not exceptional in this regard. The output loss is about ten percentage points larger in recessions with crises than in recessionswithout them both since 1973 (when we consider all 56 countries, as is our convention)and before 1913, a result that holds even more stronglyif we consider only the 21-country sample since 1973. In the Bretton Woods period, the additional output loss is slightly smaller, but 'slightly'is the operativeword. Again, while crisesmay have been growingmore frequent,they have not obviously been growing more costly. The bottom panel of Figure 2 confirmsthat averagerecoverytimes tell the same story. Recessions with crises last longer than recessionswithout them. The difference is most dramatic in the interwar years. But even in the other periods, when it is less, the differentialin recession length is in the order of 50%. 3.1. Controlling for other characteristics of cycles There are at least two reasons to pause before concluding that crises make recessions worse. First, simple comparisons that fail to control for other factors can conceal regularitiesor suggest spurious ones. Second, correlation says nothing about causality; crisesmay fostersevere recessions,or severe recessionsmay fostercrises.We now develop a model with which to test these hypotheses. 3.1.1. Controlling for other factors. Taking the recession as the unit of observation, we relate the output loss to various characteristicsof the cycle and to a dummy variable for whether or not a crisis was observed. As characteristicsof the cycle we include the average growth rate in the five years preceding the downturn, since work on 'credit booms' suggeststhe more rapid is growth in a business cycle upswing the sharperis the contraction in the downswing (Gavin and Hausmann, 1996), and a variable that distinguishesbetween industrialand emerging market nations, following the literature that suggests that business-cycle volatility is greater in emerging markets. Using a standard statistical procedure (least squares), we look at how well our explanatory variables account for the depth of recessions. Table 2 reports the results for the entire period and for the post-1973 years. The positive coefficient on expansion-phase growth ('average growth') confirms the creditboom hypothesis,while the positive coefficienton the 'industrialnation' variablesuggests that recessions are not more severe in emerging markets - if anything the opposite is true. We also controlled for period-specificfactors by including 'fixed-effect'dummy variablesfor sub-periods.These results(not reported)suggestthat recessionswere slightly more severe under the gold standardand in the interwaryears, other things equal, and less severe under Bretton Woods, although only this last differenceis significant. The coefficienton the 'all crises'variableis of particularinterest.The point estimate of 8.67 means that the cumulative output loss is about nine percentage points greater in recessions with a crisis - a figure reassuringlysimilar to that suggested above. The 63 FINANCIAL CRISES Table 2. Depth of recessions with and without crises: regression analysis Variable Coefficient t-statistic Variable Coefficient t-statistic 1880-1997 (dependent variable % loss of output) Constant Constant -6.33 2.51 9.08 3.20 Average growth Average growth 1.83 Industrialnation Industrialnation 2.36 All crises 8.67 5.52 Banking crisis Currency crisis Twin crisis V = 351, R2 = 0.41 N = 351, R2 = 0.41 -6.86 3.19 2.74 3.22 7.79 14.84 3.65 9.25 2.12 1.72 4.16 4.87 1973-1997 (dependent variable % loss of output) -8.18 Constant Constant 2.66 3.09 5.87 Average growth Average growth 5.45 3.08 Industrialnation Industrialnation All crises 10.50 5.98 Banking crisis Currency crisis Twin crisis V = 140, R2 = 0.46 N = 140, R2 = 0.40 -7.98 3.00 5.89 4.44 8.67 15.95 2.46 6.33 3.46 2.30 4.37 5.42 Notes:t-statisticswere calculated using White heteroscedasticityconsistent standarderrors. The regressionfor the pooled sample (1880-1997) also includes period fixed effects (not reported).Entries in bold face denote coefficientsthat differ significantlyfrom zero at the 95% confidence level. Source: Authors' calculations. coefficientis statisticallysignificantat a very high confidence level (99%).In other words, even after we control for other characteristicsof the country and the cycle that make certain recessions unusually severe, there is still an association between crises and the output loss. In the right-handpart of the top panel, we separatecurrency,banking and twin crises. All three are positivelyassociatedwith the severityof recessions,currencyand twin crises significantlyso. Twin crises add an additional 15 percentage points of output loss, while currency crises are about half as disruptive,banking crises a quarter. This last result is surprising.We did not expect currency crises to be so much more disruptive than banking crises. Results for the 1973-97 period (lower panel) are startlinglysimilar. Twin crises are again twice as disruptive as currency crises, which are twice as disruptiveas banking crises. The point estimatesare slightlylarger than for the longer period but none differs significantlyfrom its full-samplevalue. Thus, formal tests cannot reject the null that the output effects of currency, banking and twin crises remain the same today as over the century that ended in 1971. 3.2. Direction of causality While we have now controlledfor other characteristicsof cycles that affectthe severityof recession, the inferences we drew from Table 2 may be based on an inappropriate 64 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. MICHAELBORDO ETAL. assumption about the direction of causality,which could run from recessions to crises rather than from crises to recessions. Those who regard business-cyclefluctuationsas fundamental and crises as ephemera (e.g., Schwartz, 1986 and Gorton, 1988) would subscribe to this view. To address this possibility, we employ a two-step statistical technique ('two stage least squares') that seeks to eliminate the possibility of reverse causality.We do so as follows. In the firststep, we estimate multinomiallogit regressions of the crisis indicators (where the crisis indicator can take on four values denoting a currency crisis, a banking crisis, a twin crisis, or no crisis, and these alternativesare mutually exclusive)on lags of inflation, the ratio of broad money (M2) to reserves,the ratio of M2 to GDP, the trade balance, the budget balance, a dummy variable for currency pegs, a dummy variable for capital controls, and a measure of crises in neighbouring countries as a proxy for crisis 'contagion'. The use of lagged values increasesthe likelihoodthat these are valid instruments.(An alternativespecificationthat drops the contagion, peg and trade-balancevariables yields the same results, as noted below.) In the second step, fitted values are used in place of the actual crisis indicators. The resultis that the effect of criseson recessionseverity,that is, the point estimateon 'all crises', is now larger than before, implying a cumulative 14 percentage points of lost growth, and the coefficientstill easily differsfrom zero at the 95% confidence level. We decisivelyrejectthe assertionthat the correlationis due only to the effect of recessionson crises. 3.2.1. The causes of crises. It is tempting to use the first stage described above to analyse the causes of crises. This is tantamount to attempting to construct a leadingindicator model of currency and banking crises - something that is, however, problematic.As emphasized by Eichengreen et al. (1995), attempts to statisticallyrelate crises to fundamentals are unlikely to have high explanatory power because fundamentalsare only part of the explanation. Models of self-fulfilling'bank runs' and multiple equilibriain foreign exchange markets (so-calledsecond generation models of speculative attacks) suggest that there is unlikely to be a simple mapping from fundamentalsto crisisincidence. Consistentwith this view, all the evidence is that crises are heterogeneous.These are theoreticaland empiricalreasons not to expect too much. In light of these caveats, we rely on simple tabulationsto identify regularities.Among the most importantregularitiesto emerge from such tabulationsis the differencein crisis incidence in countrieswith and without capital controls, that is, national restrictionson inward and/or outward movements of capital. It is to their role that we now turn. 4. CAPITAL CONTROLS AND CRISES While popular commentators often blame the increasingly free mobility of financial capital for recent crises, our data suggest that the story is more complex. As Figure 3 illustrates,currencycrises are more, not less, likely in countrieswith capital controls;this is true of every period but the first,when controls were uniformlyabsent. On the other Currency crises * nations with controls O nations without controls 16- 144 12/ 4/ _ 2 0 1880-1913 1919-1939 Twin crises 1945-1971 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 nations) (56 nations) 1880-1913 *with and O without 1919-1939 All crises 16 14 12/ >, 10/ O CT cr L) (3 a, 6 L LL 4- 2_ 1880-1913 Figure 3. Crises frequency Source:Authors' calculations. 1919-1939 1945-1971 in nations 1880-1913 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 nations) (56 nations) with and without capital controls 1919-1939 66 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. hand, banking crises have been less frequent since 1973 when controls were present, althoughthe same pattern is not evident in earlieryears. Both resultsare robustto formal statistical analysis (see the appendix below): even after controlling for their other determinants,banking crises are less frequent but currency crises are more frequent in the presence of capital controls. We also find that the determinants of crises are no different,in a formal statisticalsense, today than over the entire historicalsweep. Thus, our analysis continues to underscorethe extent of continuity. The positive association of controls with currency crises is consistentwith theoretical work suggesting that controls incline governments to riskier policies and may make market participantsdoubt the readiness of the authoritiesto defend an exchange rate (Bertoliniand Drazen, 1997a,b). The two empiricalstudies of this issue of which we are aware, Glick and Hutchison (2000) and Leblang (2000), also find that countriesimposing controls are more likely to experience currency crises. The negative correlation between controls and banking crises is also in line with theory and recent experience. In the literature on the Asian crisis, for instance, it is of controls permitted banks and corporationsto fund themselves argued that the absence offshore and thus lever up their bets, something that the entities in question were encouraged to do by the fact that they were sheltered by a financial safety net and implicit exchange rate guarantees(Goldstein, 1998). Our empiricalfindingssuggest that this pattern is not new. In short, capital controls emerge as a key determinant of crisis frequency in the twentieth century. Their presence or absence is at least part of the explanation for why banking crises have grown more frequent while currency crises have become less frequent since the late 1980s. The removal of controls, in conjunctionwith the changes in political setting emphasized above, thus helps to account for the most important feature distinguishingthe 1990s from most of the century that preceded it. 5. POLICY AND THE COST OF CRISES Having considered the determinants of crisis frequency, the next question is what determinestheir severity.Unfortunately,economists have not arrivedat a consensus on what determinesthe costs of currencyand bankingcrises.We thereforestartby checking our data for simple correlationsbetween policy regimes and the crisisseverity,takingthe cumulativeloss of output (as defined above) to be our measureof severity.4Where simple comparisons suggest regularities or important changes across regimes, we then ask whether or not that pattern is robust to more formal statisticalanalysis.Where it is, we can say that we have identified an important determinantof crisis severity. We considereda varietyof potential explanationsfor the cost of crises:currentaccount balances, budget balances, whether the currencyis floating, whether capital controlsare 4Output loss is only one cost measure. Currencycrisescan involve a loss of credibilityand bankingcrisesinvolve fiscal costs to taxpayers,which may include an inflation tax. See Honohan and Klingebiel (2000) and Gupta et al. (2000) on such issues. 67 FINANCIAL CRISES present, and financial system structure(i.e., whether different financial intermediation functionscan be carried out by a single institution - so-called 'universalbanking' - are strictlyseparated,or are in between). For bankingcrises,we also considerpolicies used to facilitate crisis resolution, constructinga measure of open-ended liquidity support (the provision of financial support to distressed,often insolvent financial institutions)and of capital support (wherepublic resourcesare used to re-capitalizeproblem banks).Finally, we enumerate instances when governments provide unlimited guaranteesto depositors and creditorsof financial institutionsin the attempt to stem a loss of confidence in the system. 5.1. Currency crises In reviewing our data, the cost of currency crises did not seem to be systematically influenced by a nation's budget balance, financial system structure, exchange rate regime, or capital account regime. The current account deficit, on the other hand, does seem to matter. For currency crises, Figure 4 shows that for the post-1972 years, but not before, the cost is greater when the current account deficit is allowed to widen significantlyin the preceding period. This result is robust to formal statisticalanalysisthat also controls for the impact of other determinants. In Table 3, this is evident in the negative and statisticallysignificantcoefficienton the currentaccount variable('lag of currentaccount to GDP') for the post-1972 years but not for the period as a whole. The same is true whether or not a twin crisisdummy is included. The latter is also consistentlysignificant 20/ 18 _ ~) 14 o 12 I 1x0 Pu? 1880-1913 1919-1939 1945-1971 1973-1997 (21 countries) | * with current account deficit Figure 4. Average currency crisis depth 1973-1997 (56 countries) 0 without current account deficit | and current account deficits 68 MICHAELBORDOETAL. Table 3. Determinants of the cost of currency crises (Dependent variable is the output loss resulting from currency crises) Variable Constant Lag of M2 over reserves Lag of current account to GDP Lag of government surplus to GDP Lag of inflation Lag of GDP per capita Lag of capital controls Twin crisis dummy Number of observations Pseudo R2 1973-1997 1880-1997 Coefficient t-statistic Coefficient t-statistic 4.82 -0.05 -0.57 0.06 -0.00 -0.00 -2.72 15.69 1.37 -0.28 -2.10 0.19 -0.24 -0.55 -0.92 5.29 6.74 -0.13 -0.15 -0.05 -0.00 -0.00 -1.68 11.53 2.47 -1.21 -0.71 -0.19 -0.20 -1.01 -0.77 4.75 95 0.06 155 0.03 Notes:MultivariateTobit analysis,with statisticallysignificantlyeffectsshown in bold. Tobit is appropriatehere due to the many zero-output-lossobservations.We also estimated these with a two-stageHeckman procedure (firststage probit for whether a crisisoccurredand including the InverseMills Ratio in the second-stageTobit for the cost of the crisis).In no case was the Mills Ratio coefficient significanceand other summarystatistics never suggestedthat selectivitywas severe. Source: Authors' calculations. at conventional confidence levels, confirming that currency crises are more costly when they are accompanied by banking-sector problems. The 'sudden stop' problem. The impact of the current account plausibly reflects the 'sudden-stop' problem, in which an abrupt cessation of capital inflows requires the current account deficit to be quickly eliminated by the compression of consumption, 5.1.1. investment and import spending, thus potentially causing a collapse of output and doing damage to the financial system. It is striking that this problem is apparent in the post-1972 period but not before. The difference is not that large current account deficits were absent in earlier years (to the contrary, as shown by, inter alia, Taylor, 1996), but rather that they did not lead to sudden stops. Of the 33 crises that were preceded by current account deficits in the period 1880-1972, deficits were transformed into surpluses in the year following the crisis in only six cases (a ratio of 15%). The same was true in 18 of the 48 crises preceded by deficits in the 1973-97 period (a ratio nearly twice as large). While the comparison is crude, it suggests that current account reversals have been faster in the recent period and these faster reversals in turn lead to costlier currency crises. Determining just why sudden stops were less frequent and severe in earlier eras is likely to require an historical investigation beyond the scope of this article. However, the historical literature offers hints about how countries could run persistent current account deficits before 1913 - often of a size unmatched in the mid-to-late twentieth century without suffering debilitating interruptions. For example, Feis (1930) and Fishlow (1986) emphasize the private-to-private nature of flows and strong complementarities between trade flows and capital flows. Creditors' willingness to finance trade deficits in difficult FINANCIAL CRISES 69 times may also have been enhanced by the knowledge that the resourcesthey provided were flowing into foreign-exchange-generatingactivities. By contrast, much post-1972 lending was public-to-public or private-to-public and less consistently export linked. Additional explanations for the earlier lack of sudden stops include the adherence to stable monetary and fiscal policies required by the gold standard and colonial/Commonwealth links which minimized political uncertainty as argued by Bordo et al. (1998). 5.2. Banking crises For banking crises, the most important regularitieswe found concern liquidity support for insolvent banks and the nature of the exchange rate regime. Both since 1972 and in the interwaryears, banking crises were more costly when open-ended liquidity support was provided (Figure5 top panel) and when the exchange rate was pegged (Figure5 bottom panel). There are of course no banking crises to analyse under Bretton Woods, and the pre-1913 period looks like a fundamentallydifferent animal. Both effects are robust when we estimate Tobit equations for the cost of banking crises, including the additional determinantsof banking crises described above, for the entire 120 years as well as the post-1972 period (see appendix below). Why open-ended liquiditysupportfor insolventbanksshould increasethe cost of crises is no mystery. Public loans to banks that are not conditioned on restructuringand recapitalizationpermit insolvent institutionsto gamble for resurrection.Such loans also facilitatethe continuedflow of financingto loss-makingborrowers,and allow owners and managers to engage in looting (Akerlofand Romer, 1993). The role of these perverse incentives is evident in the 1997-8 Asian crisis, and specificallyin Indonesia, where, accordingto governmentaudits,an estimatedUS $16 billion of liquiditysupport(24% of GDP) issued to distressedfinancial institutionsdisappeared. The Asian crisis is also a graphic reminder of how pegged rates can provide an implicit guarantee against exchange risk, thereby encouraging the accumulation of unhedged foreign exposures, which increased financial distresswhen the denouement comes (more on this below). The Asian crisis, however, is merely the latest instance of the operation of these perverse dynamics. History provides many examples. A classic case is the European banking crises of the early 1930s. There, the Austrian and German governments encouraged domestic banks to provide much-needed 'industrial policy loans' to embattled but politically powerful industrial firms, in return for which they received implicit guarantees of government support. Foreign investors, reassured by these promises of support and under the impression that they were insured against currency riskby the government'spolicy of pegging the exchange rate, were more than willing to provide the German and Austrianbanking systemswith short-termcredits.When it was revealed in the 1931 Creditanstaltcrisisthat these loans had gone bad, expectationsthat the government would be forced to intervene cast doubt over the stability of the currency. As the short-term money attempted to flee, the exchange rate came under 70 MICHAELBORDOETAL. CL a 0 40r I-z (0) m 1880-1913 1919-1939 1945-1971 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 countries) (56 countries) * with liquidity support O without liquidity support 18j 16 Q. Q (A 0 0) (D 14 2- 1880-1913 1919-1939 1945-1971 1973-1997 1973-1997 (21 countries) (56 countries) peg with without o peg Figure 5. Average cost of banking crises, liquidity support and currency pegs Source: Authors'calculations. pressureand the entire arrangementpredictablycame to grief. The need to defend the currencypeg, together with investordoubts about the credibilityof their commitment to do so, then preventedthe authoritiesfrom lowering interestrates or discountingfreelyon behalf of even solvent banks. The result was large-scale capital flight, forcing official intervention to support the banking system and the imposition of exchange controls, considerablymore draconian than recent Malaysian controls, to prevent the collapse of the currency. While this abbreviated review of interwar history suggests that there is nothing new under the sun, the top panel of Figure 5 suggests that pre-1913 crisis resolution was CRISES FINANCIAL CRISES FINANCIAL 71 different.Then, liquiditysupport,if anything,was part of the solution ratherthan part of the problem, its more limited and judicious provisionreflectingthe more limited political pressuresto provide it. Similarly,pegged exchange rates were not clearlyassociatedwith more serious banking crises; if anything, the opposite was true, reflecting the greater credibilityand durabilityof the peg and the lesser extent of short-termcapital flows. As a recent illustrationof these points, we consider now the 1997 Thai crisis. 5.3. Thailand as a case in point Thailand's crisis had both currency and banking elements and each of the key relationshipsin our data - pegged exchange rates, large current account deficits, and liquidity support for insolvent intermediaries - played important roles. By 1996 Thailand's current account deficit reached 8% of GDP. Heavy capital inflows and a credit boom channelled substantialinvestmentinto real property,creating an asset-price bubble. When the bubble burst, a number of lightly regulated finance companies that were heavily involved in real estate immediately encountered difficulties.Initially the government avoided acknowledgingthe problem by extending massive liquidityto these finance companies (in the amount of 10% of GDP). By mid-1997, however, the manifest insolvencyof these institutionscompelled authoritiesto close all but two of the intervened ones. Additional low cost, government-suppliedliquidity, which was provided without intervening in these companies' operation, only added to the supply of funds in the market with which to attack the peg. It is not surprisingthat this was the moment at which the perception that the exchange rate was misalignedbegan to take hold. Already at the beginning of 1997, total private capital flows started to taper off, before turning into massive outflowswhen the crisisbroke. The capital outflow dictated huge swings in the currentaccount. Currentaccount surpluseswere achieved primarilythrough import compression and reductions in income rather than through additional exports. The consequence was a massive recession. Thailand's crisis also illustratesthe role of a pegged exchange rate in setting the stage for the financial crisis.That the nominal value of the baht did not change for ten years surely influenced market participants'perceptions of currency risk. Meanwhile, a tight monetary policy that held interest rates above internationallevels created incentives for residentsto fund themselvesoffshore,increasingtheir exposure to currencyand liquidity risk. These unhedged foreign exposures confronted the authorities with a dilemma. Allow the currencyto float and damage the health of a bankingsector indirectlyexposed to currencyrisk,or defend the peg at all costs, includingby holding up interestrates and betting foreign currencyreservesforward.In the end, they had no choice but to allow the exchange rate to float, having depleted their foreign exchange reserves and incurred a large contingent liability as a result of their effortsto prop up the financial system. But this move to greater exchange rate flexibility came too late. A more flexible exchange rate, had it been adopted earlier, would have avoided the impression of an implicit exchange rate guarantee and encouraged Thai residentsto more carefullyassess 72 72 MICHAEL ETAL. MICHAEL BORDO BORDO ETAL. foreign currency risk. It also would have allowed the central bank to resort to lower interest rates when the economy started to slow, easing the pressure on financial institutions'balance sheets. Closely related to this problem were distortions on the financial side that created artificial incentives for short-term offshore funding. Prominent among these was the establishmentof the BangkokInternationalBankingFacility(BIBF),an offshorefinancial market that enjoyed tax and regulatoryadvantagesaimed at fosteringthe development of Bangkokas a regional financial centre. Unlike other deposit-typeinstruments,shortterm BIBF monetary instruments(under 12 months to maturity)were not subjectto the usual cash reserve requirements.This tax and reserve treatment of BIBF institutions acted like Chilean holding-period taxes in reverse, encouraging rather than deterring short-term capital inflows. In an effort to sterilize the resulting inflows and to curtail credit expansion, the government tightened monetary policy, which only encouraged further inflows by increasing the differentialbetween foreign and domestic rates and furtherencouraging offshore short-termfunding. Thus, Thailand manifestedeach of the problemshighlightedby our historicalanalysis: the threat to banking-systemstabilityposed by the fatal combination of an open capital account, the implicit insurance against exchange risk conferred by an ex antecredible currency peg and open-ended liquidity support, plus the threat to currency stability posed by the combination of a large current account deficit and policies encouraging short-term borrowing by banks and corporates. Our analysis suggests that, had they known their history better, these dangers would have been more apparent to observers before the fact. 6. SUMMARY AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS It will come as no surprisethat one conclusion of this paper is that the crisisproblem is not new. Banking crises, currency crises and twin crises are hardy perennials;over the last 100 years, criseshave been followed by downturnslasting on average 2-3 years and costing 5-10% of GDP. They are evident under a wide variety of monetary and regulatoryregimes. What, then, was differentabout the last quarterof the twentieth century?The obvious answer is the greater frequency of crises. Since 1973 crisis frequency has been double that of the Bretton Woods and classicalgold standardperiods and matched only by the crisis-ridden1920s and 1930s. History thus confirms that there is something different and disturbingabout our age. Beyond this, the dominant impressionis, to echo Goodhart and Delargy (1999),plusfa change, plus c'estla memechose.Crisis length has remained constant. Output losses have changed little. Crisesmay have grown more frequentbut they have not also grown more severe. An importantqualificationhas to do with mix. The growing prevalence of twin crises is a significantdifferencebetween the fourth-quarterof the twentieth century compared FINANCIAL CRISES 73 73 to what came before. Twin crises have always been more disruptivethan banking and currency crises, and their incidence has been greater in the last quartercentury than in any period other than the disastrousDepression years. To the extent that twin crises became more frequent in the last 25 years, the cost of a randomly selected crisis was greater,and the resumptionof growth took longer. This twin-crisisproblem has attracted considerable attention from recent investigators(e.g., Kaminsky and Reinhart, 1998); our findings suggest that their preoccupation is fullyjustified. There is by now a large literatureon the causes of crises,and we have done little more than confirmthat its main findingsextend to earlierperiods.What is new is our evidence regardingthe implicationsfor the cost of crises of the exchange rate regime, the current account and liquidity support. We find that banking crises are more costly in the presence of pegged rates. Official assurances of exchange rate stability encourage the accumulationof unhedged exposures;as noted above, this is a lesson of the 1920s as well as the 1990s. Moreover, restrictiveexchange rate commitments limit the ability of the authorities to implement a more accommodative monetary policy in the event of negative shocks, again plausiblymaking the crisisworse. 6.1. Policy implications The policy implicationsfollow directly.There is an argumentfor flexible exchange rates as an ex antemeasure to minimize the cost of banking crises. This is importantbecause the point is contested, with some authors arguing that floating rates rather than pegs heighten financial fragility by discouraging financial deepening and hindering the development of the capacity to borrow abroad at long maturitiesin one's own currency. By implication,floats ratherthan pegs should be associatedwith costly crises.This is not what we find. Another key implication is that how the authorities support the banking system is important. The historical record shows that unconditional support for unsound intermediariesmakes crises worse by facilitatinglooting and gambling for resurrection. While there are theoreticalargumentsthat cut both ways, the evidence shows that while prompt public intervention in all distressed financial institutions limits the macroeconomic costs, waiting to intervene until after the crisishas passed risksthrowing good money after bad. In terms of the severityof currencycrises,what mattersmost is how far out on a limb the authorities permit the economy to crawl in the pre-crisis period. The wider the current account deficit and the heavier the reliance on short-termborrowingto finance is, the more disruptivethe dislocationswhen inflows dry up and the more difficultthe necessaryadjustments.Before the Asian crisis,it was fashionableto deny the importance of current account deficits and their financing as sources of vulnerability.Our findings suggest that the pundits would not have been so quick to dismissthem had they known their history. 74 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. MICHAELBORDO ETAL. It followsthat emergingmarketsvulnerableto sudden shiftsin capitalflows - which in practice means all emerging markets - should formulate their monetary, fiscal and exchange rate policies with an eye towardlimitingcurrentaccount deficitsand managing their financing. They should be sure that tax policies and reserve requirementsdo not artificiallyencourage mismatches of lending and borrowing maturities. They should strengthen market discipline so that banks and corporationsare compelled to manage their exposuresprudently,and they should upgrade the prudentialsupervisionof banks and securitiesmarketsto compensate for the inadequaciesof market discipline and for the moral hazard created by the safety net. And where time is required to raise supervisionand regulationto world-classlevels, they may want to contemplate Chileanstyle holding period taxes on inward foreign investment as interim measures, to further protect against distortions leading to excessive and therefore dangerous maturity mismatches.The case for these taxes, in this context, is preciselythat they can be used to lengthen the maturitystructureof the foreign debt and to offsetthe bias towardexcessive short-termexposures stemming from a safety net and weak prudential supervision.5 At the same time, our analysis lends little support to the view that capital controls provide governments and investors with protection against currency crises. To the contrary, we find a positiveassociation of currency crises with controls, suggesting that governments enjoying their shelter often succumb to the temptation to run riskier policies and that the markets take their presence as an unfavourablesignal of official resolve. In a word, the moral hazard due to controlsis severe. However, there is a negative association between capital controls and banking crises, as if an open capital account facilitatesthe effortsof marketparticipantsshelteredby a safetynet to lever up their bets. Again, the obvious interpretationis in terms of moral hazard. There is a heated debate over whether the stresslaid by academic and officialcommentatorson moral hazard has been overdrawn.Our conclusionis that it has not. Moral hazardhas long been with us; it should be taken seriously. But nothing here supports the notion that countries should liberalize at will. The historical evidence, from the recent Asian crisis and elsewhere, underscores that countries need to be cautious about how they open their capital accounts. Too many Asian governmentsliberalizedshort-terminflows first, encouragingthe accumulationof foreign exposuresand renderingthe economy susceptibleto sudden changes in investor sentiment. Their experience underscoresthe importance of liberalizingin ways that do not encourage banks and corporates to accumulate huge maturity mismatches. More generally, capital account opening should be carefully sequenced with other policy reforms. It should be accompanied by measures to limit official safety nets, to improve 5See Eichengreen and Mussa (1998) for furtherdevelopment of this recommendation.There is an enormousdebate over the effectivenessof these taxes. While some criticsargue that they are vitiated by evasion, others point to the lack of evidence that they limit the overalllevel of foreign borrowing.The second objection can be dismissedon the groundsthat the rationaleis not to limit the overalllevel of borrowingbut to alterits maturitystructure,and on the maturityfront the evidence is compelling.As one carefulrecent study (De Gregorioetal., 2000) puts its, 'the more persistentand significanteffect is on the compositionof the inflows, tilting composition towardslonger maturity'.As for the firstobjection, it is importantto recall that such a measure, to effectivelylengthen the maturitystructureof the debt, need not be evasion free. HNANCIAL CRISES FINANCIAL 75 disclosure, and to strengthen the supervisoryand regulatory frameworkunder which financial institutions operate so that financial institutions have stronger incentives to consider the consequences of their actions. As part of this, nations should avoid tax incentives that encourage excessive reliance on short-termobligations,as in Thailand in the mid-1990s, and instead design tax policies to minimize those risks. More flexible exchange rates can also play a role by forcingfinancialand non-financialcorporationsto consider the risks of short-termforeign exposures on a daily basis. Finally, our results suggest that it is criticallyimportantfor the authoritiesto operate their lender-of-last-resortfacility so that liquidity support is only provided to solvent institutions for limited periods at penalty rates against collateral. This should help to ensure that it is not used to supportinsolvent institutionsand to delay the recognition of financial distress. Discussion AndrewK. Rose Universityof California,Berkeley Crises have important effects on the economies (especiallyof developing countries),and governmentsfall and rise because of them, so it is scarcelysurprisingthat so much work has been done in the area. Yet the huge amount of recent research has left us with remarkablyfew concrete results. The crisis crisis The crisis literature is in crisis. As a profession, we simply do not have a very good understandingof what causes crises (especiallycurrencycrises).We are thereforeunable to provide policy-makerswith good crisisprevention techniques, early warning systems, and so forth. Theory is ahead of empirics in this area of economics, but both are in terribleshape. Faced with this miserablestate of affairs,researchershave gone to lengths to broaden the data sample being examined. We started with individual country case studies of currency crises. Next came post-war panels of industrialcountries. Then we added developing countries.Bankingand twin criseswere added to the list next, allowing even more observationsto be modelled. The logical end to this broadening of the data set is deepening it by going furtherback in time, and this is preciselywhat Bordo etal. do. I applaud their efforts for two reasons. First, we should certainly try to exploit all available data to try to understand financial crises. Second, the historical data must surely be the final frontier.If we don't appreciablyadd to our stock of knowledge with this data, perhaps it would be best if we collectively took a breather. A break from statistical analysis might add the perspective necessary to figure our way out of the current morass. 76 MICHAEL ETAJ. MICHAEL,BORDO ETAL. The authorsinterprettheir findingsas saying that there is nothing new under the sun; like the poor, criseshave alwaysbeen with us, and will continue to be with us. They then claim that the frequency of crises has risen, that crises are more costly since the most damaging type, twin crises, are more prevalent. The exceptional period is the interwar period, hardly a typical experience. They do this based on a huge amount of empirical work, spanning four historicalperiods covering over 50 countriesand 120 years of data, disaggregated over three types of crises, and covering the cost (in terms of foregone output) of crises as well as their incidence. I interpret their results somewhat differently. Suppose I were to claim that the compelling lesson from Bordo et al.'s data is that there is remarkablylittle to be learned from the past about financialcrises.Would this reallybe at grossodds with the data?The crisis frequenciesin Figure 1 hardly point to a noticeable trend in crisis incidence (and this impression would be strengthened with some standard errors).Ditto the average recoverytimes and the output losses of Table 1. In fact the heterogeneityin crisesmakes any strong statements about long-term trends infeasible. There is a special reason to be cautious of the authors' conclusions of the costs of crises. When we think of the American recession of 1990-1, we think of the Gulf War and the associated shock to the price of oil, in unfortunate conjunction with tight monetary policy intended to lower inflation. Similarly,we refer to the Volcker recession of the early 1980s, the shock of German Unification and its consequences for German interestrates and its EMS partners,to the burstingof theJapanese asset price bubble in 1989 ... and so forth. In each case, we think of business cycles as having causes that we can usuallypoint to. But none of these structuraleffectsis controlledfor in the regression analysis that Bordo et al. do. That is, the econometric results from Table 2 on do not control for the standard determinants of recessions (monetary shocks, the oil price, productivity effects, and so forth). Since the latter are quite plausibly correlated with crises, one has to think of the paper's findings on the cost of crises as being preliminary. Where do we stand? Current data show us remarkablylittle about the causes of crises and therefore about crisispredictionand prevention.The same is basicallytrue ofpre-WWII data. So the first message for policy-makers from this paper is basically negative. We simply don't currently have the ability to determine what causes crises. This negative conclusion carrieswith it a host of negative corollaries.If we can't understandthe determinantsof crises,we can't predict them with mechanical early warning systems.Preventingcrisesis that much harder. One of the real contributionsof this paper is that it pushes us away from trying to explain crisesand towardsthe study of what causes crisesto be more or less costly. This is surely a worthwhilegoal, and I applaud it without reservation.Even if we can't prevent the disease, knowing how to reduce its impact is an important objective. The FINANCIAL CRISES 77 reorientationof the literaturehas only begun with this paper, and I look forwardto more work in the area. What do we know about crises?They are not all alike. They never have been. The heterogeneous nature of financial crisesis their defining characteristic.It explains why it is so hard to model them empirically,and why new theoreticalmodels seem alwaysto be needed expostto explain the latest outbreak.This may be cold comfort indeed for policy makers, but at least they can appreciate the opportunitythis representsfor researchers. Panel discussion The general discussion of the paper stressed a host of statisticalissues, many of which were incorporatedinto the final version of the paper and so are not reportedhere. Guido Tabellini questioned whether counting crises is the right approach; the magnitude of recessions has increased and this should be taken into account. J6rn-Steffen Pischke pointed out that the standarderrorson many estimatedparametersare very high. Alan Wintersaskedthe authorsto prove more carefullythat twin crisesoccur more frequently, but are qualitativelynot more serious other than just adding to the losses. He suggested that more cross-sectionanalysis is necessary to address this issue. Marc Flandreauargued that the massive interwarchanges make it difficultto look at the time trend. PatrickHonohan pointed out that the costs of crisesdo not show up only in macro data. For instance, capital losses due to bad lending are also important.Harry Huizinga further suggested a crisis's effect on neighbouring countries might also be considered part of the cost; this he felt would be an interesting avenue for future research. For instance the crisis in Brazil is known to have affected Argentina substantially. Part of the discussionfocused on the policy implicationsof the empiricalanalysis.Alan Winters pointed out that it is difficultto obtain policy conclusions. In particularfor the question whether to use fixed or flexible exchange rates and the role of capital controls. Georges de Menil added a caveat to the analysis. While capital controls may prevent crisis,the process of globalizationmay overallbe beneficialfor the country.Thus a policy recommendation to impose controls may be misleading. In his response, Michael Bordo admitted that looking at patterns in large data sets ignores the work of historians.He was also worried about the resultson capital controls and pointed out that the paper is not on globalizationin general. Capital controlsmay be harmful for a country for other reasons. APPENDIX: ECONOMETRICANALYSIS OF CRISIS DETERMINANTS Table Al presents the multinomialregressionsfor the likelihoodof various kinds of crisesreferred to in Section 4. The results confirm that the effects of capital controls are statistically significant at standardconfidence levels, i.e., that capital controlsmake banking crisesless frequentbut currency 78 MICHAELBORDOETAL. Table Al. Multinomial logit analysis of determinants of crises, 1880-1997 Twin crises Dependent variable is type Currency crises Banking crises of crisis Variable Coefficient z-statistic Coefficient z-statistic Coefficient z-statistic Constant Lag of inflation Lag of capital controls Lag of M2 to reserves Lag of GDP per capita Lag of GDP growth Lag of Government surplus -3.19 -0.01 -0.05 -0.02 -0.01 -0.01 0.03 7.89 3.02 0.14 1.03 1.24 0.36 0.81 -2.36 -0.02 -0.97 -0.02 -0.01 -0.02 0.03 5.23 1.01 2.10 0.71 2.92 0.56 0.61 -3.11 0.01 0.53 0.02 -0.01 0.01 -0.04 12.25 1.61 2.52 2.62 1.35 0.40 2.02 differentthanzero at the 95%confidencelevels.The numberof Jotes:Entriesin boldface are significantly observations is 1722and the R2 is 0.04. Source: Authors' calculations. crises more frequent. Also, a Wald test for differencesbetween the full sample and 1973-97 is unable to reject the null that the determinantsof crisesare no differenttoday than over the entire historicalsweep. The conclusion that banking crisesare less likelyin the presence of capital controlsis reinforced insofaras interactiontermsbetween crisisindicatorsand dummy variablesfor the post-1973 period again enter insignificantly,individuallyand as a group, and change none of the coefficientson the other variables when added to the specification. While the same pattern is evident when we estimate a separateequation on the data for the post-1973 sub-periodalone, the coefficienton the capital-controlsvariable does not approach statisticalsignificance at standard confidence levels. The same resulthas been reportedpreviously,for a differentcountrydata set, by Eichengreenand Arteta (2000). Note that in Table Al, we use a more limited list of explanatoryvariablesthan in the first-stage of the two-step procedure described in Section 3.1. (Specifically,we drop the lag of the peg, the contagion variable, and the current account). More elaborate specificationsyield essentiallythe same results. Specifically,it remains true that both banking and currency crises are significantly more likely in low-income countries where financial systems are underdeveloped, that currency crisesare less likelywhere lagged reservesare large (relativeto M2) and the budget surplusis large. And, importantly,our resultsregardingcapital controls remain unchanged. Econometricanalysis of bankingcrisis severity Table A2 presentsthe multivariableTobit analysis- referredto in Section 5.2 - that supportsthe assertion that when it comes to banking crisis severity, the most important regularitiesconcern liquiditysupportfor insolvent banks and the nature of the exchange rate regime. The significance of the exchange rate is sensitive to the inclusion of our measure of financial structure and to whether or not we include a dummy variable for whether the banking crisis in question was accompanied by a currency crisis (that is, whether we include a twin crisis dummy). This is not surprising,since we know that central banks whose currencies are simultaneouslyunder attack have less leeway for intervening to stabilize their banking systems. Among the policy variables intended to facilitatecrisisresolution,capital support and unlimited guarantee do not prove to be Table A2. Determinants of the cost of banking crises Dependent variable is the output loss resulting from banking crises 1973-1997 Constant Liquiditysupport Capital support Guarantee Lag of peg Lag of capital controls Twin crisis dummy Lag financial intermediationindex Number of observations Pseudo R2 1880-1997 Constant Liquiditysupport Capital support Guarantee Lag of peg Lag of capital controls Twin crisis dummy Lag financial intermediationindex Number of observations Pseudo R2 Coefficient t-statistic Coefficient t-statistic Coefficien 4.39 7.25 4.82 -4.96 2.63 -4.81 11.71 1.01 2.05 1.26 -1.44 0.65 -1.07 3.23 5.59 9.92 5.38 -3.14 4.31 -1.39 1.11 2.46 1.20 -0.79 0.92 -0.27 -8.45 11.96 10.30 -6.61 8.88 0.33 4.19 29 0.09 4.02 5.98 2.20 -0.67 -0.13 1.56 3.60 29 0.04 1.42 1.99 0.67 -0.22 -0.05 0.55 1.27 4.72 6.91 2.40 -0.70 0.29 2.44 1.68 2.34 0.72 -0.23 0.11 0.87 9.55 5.63 0.20 -0.35 0.78 2.17 -1.63 76 0.02 Multivariable Notes: Tobitanalysis,with statistically effectsshownin bold. significantly Source: Authors'calculations. 76 0.02 80 80 MICHAEL BORDO ETAL. MICHAELBORDO significant,i.e., influence the economic costs of banking crises one way or another. These results confirm those of Honohan and Klingebiel (2000) for the modern period. The financial structure variable(fullyintegrated,mixed or separate)also does not appear to have systematicallyinfluenced the costs of banking crises. REFERENCES Akerlof, G. and P. Romer (1993). 'Looting: the economic underworldof bankruptcyfor profit', Activity2. Brookings PapersonEconomic Alba, P., L. Hernandez and D. Klingebiel (1999). 'Financialliberalisationand the capital account: Thailand, 1988-97', Policy Research Working Paper No. 2188, The World Bank. Balke, N. and R. Gordon (1989). 'Estimationof prewar GNP: methodology and new evidence', 97. Journalof PoliticalEconomy M. Bordo and L. Jonung (1998). 'Historical evidence on business cycles: the U.M., Bergman, internationalexperience', in J. Fuhrer and S. Schuh (eds.), BeyondShocks:WhatCausesBusiness Cycles?Federal Reserve Bank of Boston Conference Proceedings, Conference Series no. 42, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Bernanke,B. and H.James (1991). 'The gold standard,deflation and financial crises in the Great Depression:an internationalcomparison',in R.G. Hubbard (ed.), FinancialMarketsandFinancial Crises,University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Economic Bertolini, L. and A. Drazen (1997a). 'Capital account liberalisationas a signal',American Review87. (1997b). 'When liberal policies reflect shocks, what do we learn?',Journalof International Economics 42. Bloomfield, A.I. (1968). 'Patterns of fluctuation in international finance before 1914', Princeton Financeno. 21, InternationalFinance Section, Department of Economics, Studiesin International Princeton University. Bordo, M. (2000). 'Banking crises and banking crisis management in historical perspective', unpublishedmanuscript,Rutgers University. Bordo, M. and B. Eichengreen (1998). 'The rise and fall of a barbarousrelic', NBER Working Paper no. 6436. (1999). 'Is our current international financial environment unusually crisis prone?', in D. Gruen and L. Gower (eds.), Capital Flows and the InternationalFinancial System,Reserve Bank of Australia, Sydney. Bordo, M., B. Eichengreen and D. Irwin (1999). 'Is globalisation today really different from globalisation a hundred years ago?', BrookingsTradePolicy Forum 1999. Bordo, M., B. Eichengreen andJ. Kim (1998). 'Was there really an earlier period of international financial integration comparable to today?', in The Implications of Globalisation of WorldCapital Markets,Bank of Korea, Seoul. Bordo, M. and L. Jonung (1996). 'Monetary regimes, inflation and monetary reform', in D. Vaz and Information: and K. Velupillai (eds.), Inflation,Institutions Essaysin Honorof Axel Leijonhufvud, Macmillan, London. -(2000). 'A return to the convertibilityprinciple?Monetary and fiscal regimes in historical Theoryas a Basisfor Monetary Policy,Macmillan, perspective',in A. Leijonhufvud(ed.), Monetary London (forthcoming). Bordo, M. and F. Kydland (1995). 'The gold standard as a rule: an essay in exploration', in Economic History32. Explorations Bordo, M. and A. Schwartz (1996). 'The operation of the specie standard:evidence for core and peripheral countries, 1880-1990', in J. Braga de Macedo, B. Eichengreen and J. Reis (eds.), The GoldStandard andBeyond,Routledge, London. Currency Convertibility: Calvo, G.A. and C.M. Reinhart (1999). 'When capital inflows come to a sudden stop: consequences and policy options', unpublishedmanuscript,University of Maryland. Caprio, G., Jr and D. Klingebiel (1996). 'Bank insolvencies: cross-countryexperience', Policy Research Working Paper 1620, The World Bank, Washington, DC. FINANCIALCRISES CRISES FINANCIAL 81 (1999). 'Episodesof systematicand borderlinefinancialcrises',unpublishedmanuscript,World Bank, http://worldbank.org/htm/FinancialSectorWeb.nsf7(attachmentweb)/Crisistableproduct. Claessens,S. and D. Klingebiel (2000). 'Fiscalrisksof the bankingsystem:approachesto measuring and managing contingent government liabilitiesin the banking sector', in H. PawlakovaBrixi, A. Schick and S. van Wjinbergen (eds.), Government Liabilitiesand Fiscal Vulnerability, Contingent Oxford University Press (forthcoming). De Cecco, M. (1974). MoneyandEmpire:The ClassicalGoldStandard, Blackwell,Oxford. De Gregorio,J., S. Edwardsand R.O. Valdes (2000). 'Controlson capital inflows:do they work?' NBER Working Paper No. 7645, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA. Eichengreen, B. (1994). 'Historyof the internationalmonetary system:implicationsfor researchin internationalmacroeconomicsand finance', in F. van der Ploeg (ed.), TheHandbook ofInternational Macroeconomics, Blackwell,London. Capital:A Historyof the International MonetarySystem,Princeton University (1996). Globalising Press, Princeton. Eichengreen, B. and C. Arteta (2000). 'Banking crises in emerging markets:presumptions and evidence', unpublishedmanuscript,University of California,Berkeley. Eichengreen, B. and M. Mussa (1998). 'Capital account liberalization:theoretical and practical aspects', IMF Occasional Paper No. 172, InternationalMonetary Fund, Washington DC. Eichengreen,B., A. Rose and C. Wyplosz (1995). 'Exchangemarketmayhem:the antecedentsand aftermathof speculativeattacks',Economic Policy21. (1996a). 'Speculativeattackson pegged exchange rates:an empiricalexplorationwith special reference to the European Monetary System', in M. Canzoneri, W. Ethier and V. Grilli (eds.), TheNew Transatlantic Cambridge University Press, New York. Economy, (1996b). 'Contagious currency crises: first tests', in T. Anderson and K. Moene (eds.), FinancialLiberalisation andMacroeconomic Policy,Blackwell,Oxford/EBRD, London. Feis, H. (1930). Europe,the World'sBanker,Yale University Press, New Haven. Fishlow,A. (1986). 'Lessonsfrom the past:capital marketsduringthe 19thcenturyand the interwar Debt,Cornell University Press, Ithaca. period', in M. Kahler (ed.), ThePoliticsof International Furman,J. andJ. Stiglitz (1998). 'Economic crises:evidence and insightsfrom East Asia', Brookings Paperson Economic Activity2. Gavin, M. and R. Hausmann (1996). 'The roots of banking crises:the macroeconomiccontext', in R. Hausmann and L. Rojas-Suarez (eds.), BankingCrisesin LatinAmerica,The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Girton, L. and D. Roper (1997). 'A monetary model of exchange market pressure applied to Economic Review67. postwar Canadian experience', American Glick, R. and M. Hutchinson (2000). 'Stopping 'hot money' or signaling bad policy? Capital controlsand the onset of currencycrises',unpublishedmanuscript,FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco and UC Santa Cruz. Goedde, I. (2000). 'The German twin crisis of 1931', unpublished manuscript, University of Mannheim. Crisis,Institutefor InternationalEconomics,Washington,DC. Goldstein,M. (1998). TheAsianFinancial AnEarlyWarning FinancialVulnerability: Goldstein,M., G. Kaminskyand C. Reinhart (2000).Assessing Markets,Institutefor InternationalEconomics, Washington, DC. for Emerging System Goodhart, C. and and PJ.R. DeLargy (1999). 'Financialcrises:plus ca change, plus c'est la mrme chose', LSE Financial Markets Group Special Paper No. 108. Gorton, G. (1988). 'Bankingpanics and business cycles', OxfordEconomic Papers40. Greenspan, A. (2000). 'Globalisation',speech to the 75th anniversaryconference of the Bank of Mexico, 14 November, www.bog.frb.fed.us/boarddocs/speeches/2000. Gupta, P., D. Mishra and R. Sahay (2000). 'Output response during currencycrises',unpublished manuscript,IMF. Hanke, S. (1998). 'How to establishmonetary stabilityin Asia', CatoJournal17. Hausmann, R., M. Gavin, C. Pages-Serraand E. Stein (1999). 'Financialturmoiland the choice of exchange rate regime', unpublishedmanuscript,Inter-AmericanDevelopment Bank. Honohan, P. and D. Klingebiel (2000). 'Controlling the fiscal cost of banking crises', Policy Research Working Paper No. 2441, The World Bank, Washington, DC. Outlook InternationalMonetary Fund (1998). WorldEconomic (May), IMF, Washington, DC. Slump,Clarendon Press, Oxford. James, H. (1986). TheGerman Economics 43. Jeanne, 0. (1997). 'Are currency crises self-fulfilling?A test',Journalof International 82 82 MICHAELBORDOETAL. Kaminsky, G. and C. Reinhart (1998). 'The twin crises: the causes of banking and balance-ofEconomic Review89. payments problems',American Leblang, D.A. (2000). 'To devalue or not to devalue? The political economy of exchange rate policy', unpublished manuscript,University of Colorado at Boulder (October). McKinnon, R. (1997). TheRulesof theGame,MIT Press, Cambridge, MA. (2000a). 'After the crisis, the East Asian dollar standard resurrected:an interpretationof high-frequencyexchange-ratepegging', unpublishedmanuscript,StanfordUniversity. (2000b). 'On the periphery of the international dollar standard: Canada versus Latin American versus East Asia', unpublishedmanuscript,Stanford University. Milessi-Ferretti,G.M. and A. Razin (1998). 'Current account reversals and currency crises: empirical regularities',NBER Working Paper no. 6620 (June). Mulder, C. and M. Rocha (2000). 'The soundnessof estimatesof output losses in currencycrises', unpublished manuscript,IMF. Romer, C. (1989). 'Prewarbusiness cycles reconsidered:new estimates of gross national product 97. 1869-1918', Journalof PoliticalEconomy Schwartz, AJ. (1986). 'Real and pseudo financial crises', in F. Capie and G.E. Wood (eds.), FinancialCrisesandthe WorldBankingSystem,Macmillan, London. Stock,J. and M. Watson (1999). 'Businesscycle fluctuationsin US macroeconomic time series',in North Holland, Amsterdam. J. Taylor and M. Woodford (eds.),Handbook of Macroeconomics, Taylor, A. (1996). 'Internationalcapital mobility in history: the saving-investmentrelationship', NBER Working Paper no. 5743. Triffin, R. (1964). 'The evolution of the internationalmonetary system:historicalreappraisaland future perspectives',Princeton Studiesin International Financeno. 12, InternationalFinance Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University. Zevin, R. (1992). 'Are world financialmarketmore open? If so, why and with what effects?',in T. Banuri andJ.B. Schor (eds.), FinancialOpenness andNationalAutonomy, Clarendon Press, Oxford.