UCL Australia Presentation to the Nuclear Engineering Panel Engineers Australia (Sydney), 27 March 2013 Is the National Electricity Market impeding the effectiveness of energy-sector policies designed to mitigate climate change through long-term investment in lowcarbon technologies? ABSTRACT Prior to market liberalisation, the Australian electricity sector comprised state-based vertically-integrated monopolies, with largely capacity-driven investment, average cost pricing, and consumers (i.e. tax payers) bearing market risks. However, since market liberalisation investment and market risks have been borne by the investor, with short-run marginal cost (SRMC) pricing determined by market forces and, as a consequence, generating price uncertainty. Current government policy in the electricity sector is primarily focused on policies to support the development and deployment of non-nuclear low-carbon technologies in order to reduce their costs and thus reduce the longterm costs of decarbonising the sector. However, the design of the National Electricity Market (NEM) may make low-carbon investment riskier than continued investment in fossil fuel technologies. Thus, even with a carbon price, investment in low-carbon technologies may be discouraged. The NEM is an energy-only obligatory market for trading electricity. Generators offer price and associated quantity bids for five-minute dispatch intervals, with prices average over a thirty minute trading interval. The marginal generator (i.e. the highest accepted bid) sets the wholesale price, which then applies to all successful bids. The marginal generator is generally a fossil fuel generator. Thus, marginal bid pricing will include the carbon price, since this will be part of a fossil fuel generator’s short run costs. This should give a competitive benefit to low carbon technologies. However, the risks attached to recovery of fixed costs of new generation assets will vary considerably depending on the capital intensity of the different technologies. Wind power operates as base-load, ahead of coal and CCGT, because of its lower short run marginal cost (SRMC), and can therefore offer very low (or even negative) price bids to ensure dispatch. However, the large gap between the SRMC and the average cost of wind gives rise to a high level of risk that full cost recovery will not be achieved. Combined cycle gas turbine (CCGT) technology, however, has a much lower capital cost than wind (about 40% of the cost), plus it is partially hedged against price volatility as it is generally the marginal-bid technology. Thus price volatility for CCGT is likely to be significantly lower than for wind, and full cost recovery less of an issue. The problem is to replace, or complement, long-term market arrangements with technology-specific policies that encourage investment in long-term low-carbon technologies. The challenge is to combine public and market coordinations in order to maintain financial incentives, while simultaneously reducing the risks inherent in the market regime sufficiently so as to ease investment. There are two broad options for government intervention: 1. Feed-in tariffs Structured either as fixed payments, premium payments on top of the electricity price, or financial contracts for difference against the market price. 2. Establish a market for clean energy Imposition of quantity obligations on suppliers (such as a renewables obligation). 1 Alternatively, it may be preferable to reform the structure of the NEM to address the issue on a market-wide basis. Possible market reform may include the following: • • • • Carbon price support: the guarantee of a minimum carbon price in the electricity market; Long-term contracts for all low-carbon generators: structured as contracts-for-difference against the market price; Targeted capacity payments for flexible/peaking plants; and Emission performance standards. To conclude, liberalised electricity markets such as the NEM have raised the risks faced by investors in highcapital-cost, low-operating-cost generation, thereby discouraging investment in low-carbon-technologies. A key question for governments, therefore, is whether to use targeted measures to reduce risk and ensure capital cost recovery for low-carbon investments, or whether to reform the NEM so that market-based policies can be incorporated into its structure. Failure to act may delay investment in a low-carbon technology future, thus raising the cost of de-carbonising the electricity sector. 2