EX SU ECUT MM IV AR E Y $35.00 In bookstores April 2010 “ “ Productivity isn’t everything, but in the long run it is almost everything. —Paul Krugman Inter-American Development Bank DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 1 2/12/10 5:04 PM DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 2 2/12/10 5:04 PM Low Productivity: The Root Cause of Weak Economic Growth The economies of Latin America and the Caribbean suffer from a chronic low-growth disease caused by low productivity. Unfortunately, the region has become so accustomed to this economic ailment, that it no longer considers slow growth its most pressing problem. And yet, the countries of the region are paying dearly for not assigning economic growth the highest priority. For example, income per capita in Latin America and the Caribbean was almost one-quarter that of the United States in 1960 while today it is only one-sixth. In contrast, several East Asian countries, which in 1960 had income levels well below those of Latin America and the Caribbean, are fast approaching or have joined the ranks of high-income nations (Figure 1). If productivity in the region had grown at the same rate as in the United States, the income per capita of the region relative to the United States would have remained unchanged at one-quarter, even with the reported investments in human and physical capital. If, on the other hand, productivity had converged to the U.S. level—that is, if the physical and human resources which Latin American and Caribbean countries currently enjoy were used with the productive efficiency of those in the United States—per capita income would have doubled and the income of the region relative to that of the United States would be one-third. 1 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 1 2/12/10 5:04 PM Figure 1 Relative Productivity in Latin America, 2005 35.8 Chile 76.6 25.1 Costa Rica 75.5 20.3 Dominican Rep. 69 31.6 Argentina 63.5 28.2 Uruguay 63.1 13.3 El Salvador 60.7 22.8 Mexico 58.6 20.7 Brazil 57.3 18 Colombia 56.1 24.8 Panama 54.7 20.6 Venezuela 52 16.8 Typical country of Latin America Paraguay 51.8 13.4 49.3 9.74 Nicaragua 46.1 13 Jamaica 44.4 13 Ecuador 39.7 8.52 Bolivia 39 13 Peru 37.3 6.53 Honduras 0 10 31.1 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 TFP relative to United States (percentage) GDP per capita relative to United States (percentage) Source: Authors’ calculations based on A. Heston, R. Summers, and B. Aten (2006), Penn World Table Version 6.2, Center for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of Pennsylvania; World Bank (2008), World Development Indicators Online; R. J. Barro, J., and Lee (2000), International Data on Educational Attainment: Updates and Implications, CID Working Paper No. 42, Center for International Development at Harvard University. Note: TFP = total factor productivity. 2 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 2 2/12/10 5:04 PM The Concept of Productivity Raising productivity implies finding better ways to more efficiently use the existing labor, physical capital and human capital of the region. One standard way to measure gains in efficiency is to compute increases in total factor productivity (TFP), that is, the efficiency with which the economy transforms its accumulated factors of production into output. Reporting that TFP grew 1 percent is equivalent to saying that 1 percent more output was obtained from the same productive resources. This is the preferred measure of productivity in this study, which focuses on the drivers of the level and growth of TFP rather than on the determinants for increasing human or physical capital (Figure 2). Figure 2 Average Annual Labor Productivity Growth by Region and Period, 1950–2005 (percent) 5 4 4.60 3.90 3.80 3 2.70 2.40 2 1.50 1 0 –0.30 –1 1950–1975 Latin America 1975–1990 High-Income Countries 1990–2005 East Asia Source: Authors’ calculations based on M. P.Timmer, Marcel P., and G. J. de Vries (2007), A CrossCountry Database for Sectoral Employment and Productivity in Asia and Latin America, 1950–2005, Research Memorandum GD-98, Groningen: University of Groningen. 3 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 3 2/12/10 5:04 PM Small and Unproductive Companies The root problem of productivity in the region is too many resources allocated to too many small low-productivity companies, and a dearth of middle-level and high-productivity firms. While in the United States 54 percent of firms have fewer than 10 employees, in Argentina, for example, 84 percent have no more than 10 employees. In Mexico and Bolivia, small companies account for more than 90 percent of all firms. The least productive companies tend to be the smallest: a Latin American company with more than 100 employees can generate, on average, double the output with the same resources of a company with only 10 to 19 employees (Figure 3). 0 185.32 216.32 Chile 2006 132.12 Uruguay Colombia El Salvador Venezuela 2005 1988 2005 2001 Firm size (number of employees) 20–49 50–99 57.75 38.44 74.62 102.94 100.60 105.23 43.90 60 55.43 61.79 79.41 120 133.50 142.60 179.11 180 26.84 35.34 Percentage Increase in Productivity Figure 3 Productivity by Firm Size Relative to Firms with 10–19 Workers, Manufacturing Establishments Bolivia 2000 100–249 Sources: C. Birbuet, and C. G. Machicado (2009), Understanding Productivity Levels, Dispersion and Growth in the Leather Shoe Industry: Effects of Size and Informality, Washington, DC: IDB; M. Busso, L. Madrigal, and C. Pagés (2009), Productivity and Resource Misallocation in Latin America, Washington, DC: IDB; A. Camacho, and E. Conover (2009), Misallocation and Manufacturing TFP in Colombia, Washington, DC: IDB; J. Atal, M. Busso, and C. Cisneros (2009), Productivity and Misallocation: The Case of El Salvador, Washington, DC: IDB; C. Casacuberta, and N. Gandelman (2009), Productivity, Exit and Crisis in Uruguayan Manufacturing and Service Sectors, Washington, DC: IDB; INE (2001), Encuesta Industrial Anual de Venezuela.. 4 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 4 2/12/10 5:04 PM The Key Role of the Service Sector Raising the productivity of services is a must to boost economic growth and improve the standard of living of all Latin American and Caribbean people. Sixty-one percent of all workers in the region are employed in the non-tradable service sector, and the competitiveness of the primary and industrial sectors depends on having good transport and communications, efficient storage and distribution systems, and many other services. The productivity gap of service companies in the region compared with the United States is 85 percent. Meanwhile, the gap in productivity for the region’s manufacturing sector, which employs about 20 percent of the workforce, is 61 percent. In the agriculture sector, which employs about 18 percent of the total workforce in the region, the gap is only 20 percent (Figure 4). Figure 4 Average Annual Labor Productivity Growth in Agriculture, Industry and Services, 1951–2005 (percentage) 6 2.5 1.4 –1.8 –1 –2 –3 1.3 1.3 –0.9 0 0.1 2.4 3.5 2.2 2.0 2.6 1.8 1 3.2 3.6 2.5 1.8 2 2.8 3 3.8 4 3.5 5.0 5 1951– 1975 1975– 1990 1990– 2005 Agriculture Latin America 1951– 1975 1975– 1990 Industry East Asia 1990– 2005 1951– 1975 1975– 1990 1990– 2005 Services High-Income Countries Source: Authors’ calculations based on M. P.Timmer, Marcel P., and G. J. de Vries (2007), A CrossCountry Database for Sectoral Employment and Productivity in Asia and Latin America, 1950–2005, Research Memorandum GD-98, Groningen: University of Groningen. 5 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 5 2/12/10 5:04 PM Policies to Foster Productivity With the right economic policies, Latin American governments can go a long way toward solving the productivity problem. Many of the problems arise from market failures that have yet to be properly addressed, and others from failed economic policies that, often unintentionally, have taken a toll on productivity by increasing allocation of resources to small and inefficient firms. This study explores whether policies on trade, credit, taxes, social protection, aid to small firms, innovation and industrial promotion are at the root of the problem, or instead part of the cure for the low-productivity-growth disease of the region. This book focuses on the less studied dimensions of productivity that may be vitally important for the design of public policy in Latin America and the Caribbean. High Transportation Costs and Trade Free trade has often been touted as a boon to productivity because it exposes producers to greater competition, forcing them to cut costs and increase their efficiency while providing greater access to more and better inputs, particularly capital goods. However, high trade costs, particularly those associated with transportation, have prevented the region from reaping all the benefits from greater international trade. Moreover, economic resources are diverted to an inefficient transportation system, hurting the overall level of productivity in the economy. The region as a whole spends in freight nearly twice as much as the United States to import its goods. Most Latin American countries have higher freight rates when exporting to the United States than countries in the Far East and in Europe. This is alarming, particularly when considering countries that are very close to the United States, such as those in the Caribbean (Figure 5). 6 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 6 2/12/10 5:04 PM Figure 5 Freight Expenditures as a Share of Exports to the United States, 2006 China Oceania East Asia European Union–12 Paraguay Guyana Argentina Chile Panama Guatemala Uruguay Ecuador Brazil Costa Rica Colombia Jamaica Belize Trinidad and Tobago Honduras Peru Bolivia Barbados Nicaragua Salvador Venezuela Mexico 6.24 5.50 4.41 3.77 15.87 12.43 7.73 7.65 7.55 7.32 6.82 6.74 6.27 6.22 5.99 5.95 5.90 5.36 4.69 4.69 4.22 4.08 3.56 3.38 3.17 1.14 0 5 Percentage 10 15 Source: Authors' calculations based on U.S. Census Bureau dataset on U.S. Imports of Merchandise (various years). Note: European Union-12 countries are: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, Netherlands, Sweden and United Kingdom. Ports and airports are grossly inefficient in the region. Inadequate physical infrastructure is to blame in some countries, but more important are the support activities for the movement of cargo and the inefficiencies caused by inadequate regulation, lack of competition in services, and deficient operating procedures and information systems. 7 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 7 2/12/10 5:04 PM Too Little Credit Despite the financial deregulation of the 1990s, the depth of Latin American credit systems remains very low by international standards (Table 1). Consequently, lack of credit is one reason why there is so much dispersion in the productivity of firms. Without credit, productive firms cannot expand and less productive firms cannot make the technological changes and investments needed to raise their productivity. The credit drought has another damaging effect on productivity: it weakens the incentives for informal firms to comply with tax, legal and social security provisions. This hurts productivity by allowing unproductive firms to survive because they have lower costs than their formal counterparts. Expansion of credit to enterprises can help formalize jobs and, as a result, improve productivity. Table 1 Financial Development and Total Factor Productivity Growth by Region, 1965–2003 Number of countries Credit to the private sector (percentage of GDP) TFP growth (percentage) 7 77 1.3 Industrial Countries 22 74 0.6 Africa 16 18 –0.1 Latin America 18 31 –0.5 Region East Asia Source: Credit to the private sector: World Bank (2009), The World Business Environment Survey; TFP: C. Daude, and E. Fernández-Arias (2010), On the Role of Aggregate Productivity and Factor Accumulation in Economic Development in Latin America and the Caribbean, Washington, DC: IDB. 8 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 8 2/12/10 5:04 PM Complex Tax Systems Tax systems in the region remain very complex, segmented and ineffective. It takes an average of 320 hours per year for Latin American and Caribbean firms to file taxes compared to an average of 177 hours in high-income countries (Figure 6). Almost all countries have multiple tax regimes for firms of different sizes, and tax collection is decidedly low: 17 percent of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2005 compared to 36 percent in industrial countries) Taxes on profits are high by international standards, yet collection is very inefficient due to high evasion, particularly among small and micro firms. As a result, the region’s tax systems distort the allocation of productive resources: the sectors and firms that expand are not necessarily the most productive but rather those that enjoy higher tax breaks or can evade their tax obligations more easily. The creation of simplified tax systems for small companies has increased formalization but created incentives for these firms to remain small in order to avoid a sharp drop in their profitability. Simplifying, unifying and enforcing the tax provisions that apply to enterprises could contribute greatly to productivity; in turn, higher productivity would boost both the gross domestic product and tax receipts. Social Policies: Good Intentions, Unintended Outcomes Social policies—either through government spending or regulation— can change behavior in labor markets and hurt productivity by preventing the efficient allocation of resources in the economy. The strategy of financing social security by taxing formal labor adds to nonwage labor costs and induces workers and companies to pursue informality, misallocating the economies’ resources. Higher labor informality, then, prompts governments to increase social protection to those without a formal job. That, in turn, can 9 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 9 2/12/10 5:04 PM reduce workers’ willingness to search for jobs with social security coverage, distorting firms’ and workers’ decisions on labor allocation and scale of operations, decisions that further hurt productivity. It is estimated that increased informality causes Latin America and the Caribbean to lose annually between 0.4 and 5.2 percent of output (Table 2). The answer is not to eliminate social policies but to cut the linkage of benefits and funding of those policies with employment. Universal coverage services, such as health insurance, or even retirement pensions, can be funded with fewer distortions by general taxation instead of labor taxation. Programs for Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises Do programs for small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs) increase firms’ productivity? Unfortunately, evaluations of these programs have been few and far between and when done, the variable of focus has been employment rather than productivity. On average small firms—particularly the smallest ones—do not necessarily use additional resources more productively than medium and large firms. If anything, most of the evidence suggests the opposite: many of the smallest firms are actually too large relative to what they should be because they benefit from implicit subsidies in the form of unpaid taxes and social security contributions. Thus, they may not be able to employ additional labor or capital very productively, particularly relative to larger firms. The objective of such programs should not be to create jobs but to create productive jobs, which can appear in an enterprise of any size, including but not limited to SMEs. Estimates in this volume suggest that SME programs may indeed boost the productivity of beneficiary firms but, in the aggregate, the effects would be greater if support was open to all firms no matter their size, particularly companies in the formal sector. 10 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 10 2/12/10 5:04 PM Figure 6 Time Required to Complete Tax Payments, 2007 Europe and Central Asia Latin America Middle East and North Africa South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa East Asia and Pacific High Income 350 320 295 293 287 228 177 Brazil Bolivia Venezuela, RB Ecuador Mexico Panama Argentina Peru Guatemala Uruguay Paraguay Dominican Republic El Salvador Chile Guyana Costa Rica Nicaragua Honduras Colombia Suriname Haiti St. Kitts and Nevis Belize Grenada Dominica St. Lucia 2,600 1,080 864 600 517 482 453 380 344 336 328 324 320 316 288 282 240 224 208 199 160 155 147 140 120 92 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 Annual Hours Source: Authors’ calculations based on World Bank (2009), The World Business Environment Survey. Note: Information based in 181 countries, with data from 2007–2008. Time is recorded in hours per year, and it measures the time to prepare, file and pay (or withhold) three major types and contributions: the corporate income tax, value added or sales tax, and labor taxes, including payroll taxes and social contributions. 11 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 11 2/12/10 5:04 PM 12 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 12 2/12/10 5:04 PM Year 2002 2007 2006 2005 2006 2007 2005 2006 2002 Country Bolivia Brazil Chile Colombia Costa Rica Ecuador El Salvador Guatemala Mexico 13.6 1.7 0.6 2.1 0.2 2.4 0.9 17.8 0.9 Uncovered salaried workers (million of workers) (I) Nonwage labor cost (percentage of salary) (II) 37.9 53.6 31.7 53.5 33.0 34.8 32.4 31.8 36.4 Uncovered salaried workers (percentage of salaried workers) 75.0 31.9 20.1 31.8 18.1 66.9 49.0 63.4 50.7 Table 2 Output Loss Estimates for the Region 14.0b 21.8a 12.5 20.9 12.5 19.9 13.5 17.9 8.72a Covered/ uncovered wage gap (percentage of average salary) (III) 50.3 53.6 44.9 55.6 45.5 73.4 45.1 71.5 46.6 Continues on next page [1.4–2.1] [1.9–4.1] [1.6–2.4] [2.1–4.1] [0.6–0.8] [1.1–1.5] [0.4–0.6] [1.8–2.5] [3.6–5.1] Annual GDP loss range Difference in (percentage marginal of GDP) productivity (V) = 0.5 x (I) x (IV) (percentage x (average wage)/ of salary) (IV) = (II) + (III) GDP 13 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 13 2/12/10 5:04 PM 2005 2006 2004 Nicaragua Paraguay Venezuela 1.9 0.9 0.7 Nonwage labor cost (percentage of salary) (II) 51.1 27.8 22.9 Uncovered salaried workers (percentage of salaried workers) 67.0 83.3 41.0 14.0 15.0 19.8 Covered/ uncovered wage gap (percentage of average salary) (III) 36.9 42.9 70.9 [0.4–0.8] [2.7–5.2] [3.9–6.3] Difference in Annual GDP loss range marginal (percentage productivity of GDP) (percentage (V) = 0.5 x (I) x (IV) of salary) x (average wage)/ (IV) = (II) + (III) GDP Source: Authors’ calculations based on: IMF (2009), World Economic Outlook, and countries’ household surveys from Bolivia: INE (2002); Brazil: IBGE (2007); Chile: MIDEPLAN (2006); Colombia: DANE (2005); Costa Rica: INEC (2006); Ecuador: INEC (2007); El Salvador: DIGESTYC (2005); Guatemala: INE (2006); Mexico: INEGI (2002); Nicaragua: INIDE (2005); Paraguay: DGEEC (2006); and Venezuela: INE (2004). Notes: Column (III) shows the wage gap that remains after controlling for gender, age, education, living in the capital city, economic sector and firm size. The lower bound in Column (V) assumes that the covered–uncovered wage gap is zero. The upper bound in that column uses the result in Column (III) . a Due to data availability, not controlling for either firm size or economic sector. b Due to data availability, not controlling for firm size. Year Country Uncovered salaried workers (million of workers) (I) Table 2 Output Loss Estimates for the Region (continued) New Ideas for Innovation The capacity of a society and its firms to generate and assimilate technological change is a key component of prosperity and growth. Many Latin American firms invest in innovation. Nonetheless, their financial commitment amounts to a mere 0.5 percent of gross revenue compared to 2 percent, or four times higher, for countries in the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). Firms in the region spend most of their innovation dollars on assimilating technology in new equipment and machinery, while developed countries invest primarily in research and development. The public sector is the biggest spender on research and development, but its focus is on basic research in universities and public research centers which, with valuable exceptions, have little influence on productive innovation and low scientific performance by international standards. The main obstacles to innovation in the region are lack of finance, long return periods, small domestic markets, and a shortage of trained personnel. Consequently, deepening credit markets, lowering transportation costs, and improving education and worker training can boost the incentives for firms to innovate. Governments must solve failures in communication among the various actors in innovation systems in order to have positive outcomes in the productive system. 14 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 14 2/12/10 5:04 PM A New Era for Industrial Policy Increased productivity for the region will depend on the coordinated efforts of individuals, enterprises and institutions in the private and public sectors, paving the way for a new era for industrial policy. In a departure from the past, industrial policies today are understood as a set of instruments and institutions that facilitate coordination and generate specific public inputs required by specific sectors. Although the final product may be exports or goods tradable internationally, the goal of these new industrial policies is not to stimulate any sector. Rather, the goal is to develop and expand sectors that have potential comparative advantages or positive externalities over other areas in the economy. Successful policies promote public–private cooperation, exploit the information advantages of the private sector, create incentives for risk-taking, and above all discourage rent-seeking behavior. Outstanding examples of these policies come from the agricultural sector, such as the development of genetically improved rice varieties or soy seeds adapted to the Brazilian savannas through public–private partnerships. Implementing policies that foster productivity in the region is a challenge because it may go against measures that give immediate political benefits, such as tax exemptions for certain sectors. In addition, such policies may be difficult to implement because economic activity has been diversified, the powers of national governments have been decentralized and political systems have become more participative. Countries will need to build a politically feasible social consensus in favor of productivity. Such public support is possible. In the past 15 years, after many setbacks, Latin American societies have succeeded in building a social consensus in favor of macroeconomic stability. Thanks to this, the region has come 15 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 15 2/12/10 5:04 PM through the worst international financial crisis since the Great Depression in relatively good shape. A new consensus now is imperative to allow the region to build upon its macroeconomic stability, paving the way for Latin America and the Caribbean to achieve sustainable long-term economic growth that is stimulated by rising productivity and not the exploitation of natural resources. 16 DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 16 2/12/10 5:04 PM Order Form PLEASE PRINT 1. NAME AND ADDRESS Name Organization Mailing Address Country Telephone Fax E-mail 2. METHOD OF PAYMENT Credit card or check, in U.S. dollars, drawn on a U.S. bank and payable to PÓRTICO BOOKSTORE. Amount must cover price plus shipping costs Check American Express Visa Card no. MasterCard Expiration date Signature 3. SHIPPING ADDRESS (if different from name and address shown above) Name Organization Mailing Address Country Telephone Fax E-mail 4. SHIPPING COSTS For shipment within the United States and Canada, add $5 to your order for the first book and $1 for each additional book. Outside the United States and Canada, add $11 to your order for the first book and $5 for each additional book. 5. ORDER BOOKS Title/Unit Price # of Copies Total (in US$) The Age of Productivity / US$35.00 SHIPPING COSTS (see 4) TOTAL 6. SEND Fax: (202) 312-4188 Pórtico Bookstore 1350 New York Avenue, NW Washington, DC 20005 Tel. (202) 312-4186 portico.sales@fceusa.com DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 17 Also available at Amazon.com 2/12/10 5:04 PM DIA_booklet 2-12-10 final.indd 18 2/12/10 5:04 PM